Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL...

download Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.pdf

of 18

Transcript of Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL...

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    1/18

    Publicado originalmente como: J.A. BARCELO, PELFER,G., MANDOLESI,A 2002, The origins of the city. From

    social theory to archaeological description.Archeologia e Calcolatori Num. 13, pp. 41-64.

    THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY.

    FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL

    DESCRIPTION

    By Juan A. Barcel (Universitat Autnoma de Barcelona). Giuliano Pelfer (Universit di Roma-LaSapienza), Alessandro Mandolesi (Museo Archeologico di Barbarano Romano),

    ABSTRACT

    This paper will focus on the origins of the city. This subject has been studied in sociology,anthropology, history and geography, but there is not a unified approach. Our paper deals

    with the specific way social theory can be used in archaeology. We consider that a city is

    a specific form of social space produced by a series of social actions. However, thisproduction process cannot be described easily in archaeological terms. As a result, there

    is a deep gap between social theory concepts and archaeologically observable evidences.

    Today it is fashionable to speak about the unscientific nature of Archaeology and Social

    Science. This paper deals with this discussion, trying to create an observational theory to

    understand the process of city formation. We reject traditional positivist approaches of

    concept and reference, because of its simplicity. However, this fact does not mean that the

    analysis is impossible in scientific terms. We show how to use spatial statistics,probabilistic modelling and visualization technology in order to obtain a simulation of the

    spatial process, and then use the resulting model to built a representation of social theory inarchaeological terms.

    In the paper we use the Italian city of Tarquinia as a case study. It is suggested that the

    origin of the city can be represented as a spatial process beginning with preliminary

    scattered villages, which join together forming bigger spatial units, which become

    attractive for the better geographical and geomorphological conditions. The gradual

    consolidation of the main settlement in the best location is determined by the population

    growth, and the development of new productive system and new social relationships.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    2/18

    Introduction

    Today it is fashionable to speak about the unscientific nature of Archaeology and Social Science. This

    paper deals with this discussion, trying to create an observational archaeological theory to understand a

    social process.

    What is archaeology? There are still many archaeologists working in a self-limited discipline dedicated to

    the unearthing of past treasures, and the static description of past ways of live. In that sense, most

    archaeological information seems to be artifactual, because it deals with the relevance of archaeological

    finds as self-important entities, which must be studied in themselves, as muted witnesses of unknown past

    facts. Social action is here reduced to a mere description of some objects made by human agents. This is a

    positivist approach where only directly observable entities (archaeological artefacts, natural landscape)

    are taken into account. Society is here artificially restricted to the notion of Artefact, because

    artefacts are the only observable feature usually associated with the concept of social action.

    However, we can imagine a much more developed definition of archaeology, that of a discipline dealing

    with the history of our society, that is, those processes which have causedour present. In this approach,

    emphasis is not directed to empirical things, but to events and non-observable concepts -processes or

    social actions. In this sense, the goal of archaeology would not be the documentation of ancient sites and

    objects, but studying the dynamics of society. Archaeological record is the medium by which this study

    is scientifically possible. We are looking for the formation process of our own social actions, using

    ancient artefacts as their observable consequences at specific time intervals. The purpose is to discover

    what cannot be seen (social causes) in terms of what is actually seen (material effects).

    Archaeology should not be defined as the study of past things or events. We archaeologists use the past,

    but it is not the object and goal of research. We should understand our present, that is, we should analyse

    its cause, and this is only possible by defining the specific continuity between Past and Present.

    The only way to understand the origins and causes of these processes is by analysing the previous states

    of our society. We do what we are doing, because our fathers, and grand fathers made actions, reproduced

    the society of their forefathers and introduced some modifications. The Past is not like the Present, but we

    need to calculate what kind of relationship, causal or not, connected or unconnected may exist between

    what we are doing here, and what individuals did in the same spatial location, at different temporal

    locations.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    3/18

    Archaeologists usually take an inductive approach, trying to explain why the archaeological record is how

    it is. However, pure induction is impossible with archaeological material. We end creating universal

    dictionaries which are useless and even wrong!

    The only possible solution is by using deductive logic, but taking into account that archaeology is not a

    formal science. We are not trying to proof theorems, but trying to obtain the likelihood of alternative

    hypotheses. The best way is to consider archaeology as a way of problem solving, where the solution

    space has to be already known.

    The problem with this approach is the risk of just reading archaeological material in social terms. Our

    goal is not to explain archaeological material, but to find evidences of social actions performed through

    different time intervals. In this case, we have not to explain why the archaeological material found in the

    Tarquinia area is like it is, but to describe the degree of capital concentration and the emergence of cities,

    using archaeological material as data.

    If we do not know the solution of a problem, we will never solve that problem.

    To know the solution does not mean to trick. We have to build a problem space, where all possible

    alternative solutions be included, even the wrong ones, and some procedures to detect in which case, a

    particular concept is a solution to a particular problem, and in which cases it is not the solution. Heuristic

    logic allows us to distinguish between correct solutions and true ones.

    The study of the origins of cities and towns is a very good example of this way of understanding History.

    History is not a database of facts, nor a narration of past events. It is a way of thinking about the present.

    We think backwards, looking for previous states of our social system, and analysing whether they are

    causally connected or not.

    We are not interested in learning everything is possible of how people lived in prehistoric cities. We think

    that social relationships during 9-8th. Centuries in Central Italian Peninsula are causally connected with

    what we call today cities and towns in the same area. That means, a social process whose consequences

    still determine our social action, began to act in those times. We are not using modern economics

    concepts to understand past social structures. We are trying to measure the proper connection between

    the Past and the Present.

    We are not saying that market relationships are correct to characterize Early Iron Age social relationships,

    but we question whether it is or it is not the case. If we can detect evidences of capital accumulation and

    of reproductive dynamics in capital accumulation, then we will have a stronger basis for asserting the

    causal connection between our society and its state during that time interval.

    It is for this reason that we need mathematical equations. It is not to give an impression of real science,

    but a way to link theoretical terms (social concepts) with observed data. However, it is true that we cannot

    obtain proper figures for most of the parameters. Archaeological record is only a part of the material

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    4/18

    consequences of social action. Thus, not any quantification of available archaeological material is a

    correct estimation of the quantity of material effects produced by a given social cause. Instead, we have to

    study the rate of change, that is, similarities and differences between different spatial and temporal

    contexts.The Origins of the City as a Social Process

    If we do not know, what a city is and in which way it may emerge, we will never discover cities in the

    archaeological record, nor understand their historical dynamics.

    To the geographer, the city is usually described in functional terms as an urban area, which consists of a

    core administrative-government centre linked by journey to work movements to a commuting hinterland

    (Clark 1982). The city is seen as a finite entity in geographical space, which exists by exporting urban

    goods and services in exchange for those of external suppliers. In opposition to villages, which exploitthe resources of their site, cities have been conceptualised as entities which benefit from their political

    control and social dominance by exchanging and accumulating the wealth of several distant areas. This is

    possible through the various kinds of flows (materials, people, information, etc.) which connect cities to

    each other. The importance of those relationships for the functioning and the evolution of cities has led us

    to conceive urban areas, as a complex system of interdependent units (Pumain 1997).

    Obviously all those definitions are not very useful for archaeologists. A better point of departure would be

    "a unit of analysis consisting of a collection of buildings, activities and population clustered together in

    space" (Camagni 1992). The origins of cities and towns is then a social process involving two elements:the multiplication of points where people concentrates and the increase of individual concentrations

    (Carter 1972). Therefore, urban systems may be defined through a main spatial discontinuity, a dialectical

    opposition between what seems to be a city (nucleated built space) and what is not a city (dispersed

    settlement). But also inside the nucleated built space we may find discontinuities in terms of activity

    areas: the social and ritual area, a common decision-making area, an area addressed to the exchange

    activities.

    Three important factors for the existence of cities are: concentration, accessibility and spatial interaction.

    They explain the formation (concentration forces), the location (accessibility), and its shape

    (organization) (Camagni 1992).The main point for a definition of the city is then the formation of an

    institutional and nucleated space, protected, fortified, concentrated and imploded, which acts as the

    nucleous for the power, of the political, burocratical, militar activities developed from the elites, and

    controls means of production.

    Many authors suggest that the cities exist because people find more advantageous and efficient the

    management of personal, social, and economic relationships in a specially concentrated mode (Christaller

    1933, Lsch 1939, Berry and Horton 1970, Carter 1972, Clark 1982, Dicken and Lloyd 1990, Wheeler et

    al. 1998). Those approaches consider that cities are a mere spatial container of social relationships, and

    not a social relationship in itself. The wrong assumption is that human proximity is a way to obtain

    efficient methods to manage social reproduction. In this view, the spatially concentrated pattern of social

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    5/18

    and economic activities is only a function of production costs. Consequently, economic interpretation of

    urban growth lay stress upon the savings of assembly, production and distribution costs which may be

    achieved through concentration. Those authors argue that the emergence and growth of cities are the

    consequences of the search for the most economical forms of settlement.

    Nevertheless, it is a wrong assumption that human proximity be a way to get efficient methods to manage

    social reproduction. We have no empirical evidence that the emergence and growth of cities be the

    consequence of the search for the most economical forms of settlement. The search of better resource

    allocation implies always social inequalities by stressing spatial differentiation. The increasing scale of

    production and the technical benefits that accrue through economies of scale are seen both to promote and

    to require an increasing concentration of capital, largely through the process of accumulation itself.

    Spatial concentration of people and institutions tend to be accelerated by a process of centralization of

    capital in which larger groups gobbles up the smaller. We should question the usual assumption that cities

    are always generative of economic growth and an amelioration of the quality of life: the city does not

    create wealth in an effective way, but it takes over resources to a population living outside the nucleated

    settlement. An element of inequality, hierarchy, dominance and power is emerging from what seemed

    purely functional relationships (Camagni 1992). Capital is transferred from many dispersed locations to a

    central location. It is this spatial transfer of capital (people, raw products, manufactured goods, etc.) what

    we call urban system. Its main observable feature is then the apparition of a dichotomy between an

    emergent core area and the already existing settled area, which becomes a periphery. Core regions

    (cities) are defined as territorially organized subsystems of society which have a high capacity for

    generating and absorbing wealth. Rural-peripheral regions are those whose development path is

    determined chiefly by capital accumulated at core areas with respect to which they stand in a relation of

    substantial dependency. Growth in the centre tends to produce not a parallel growth in the periphery but a

    counterpoised decline, stagnation, or, at best, lower rates of growth.

    Factors contributing to that dependency may include control over manpower, tribute collection, control of

    trade, and control of elite goods. The income earned by the periphery tends to be leaked away by spent

    on goods that the periphery itself cannot provide. The production of higher-order consumer goods tends

    to be largely in hands of the core centres. The scale economies existing in the centre and the accumulated

    competitive benefits of its early start inhibit the production of such goods in the periphery. Villages in the

    periphery tend to be lower-order centres, with a restricted variety of goods to offer, where populationremains attached to domestic production or migrates to cities to access other means of production. There

    is not an evolution of social relations of production at the periphery, because it is prevented by the

    extractions from the centre.

    In fact, it is the countryside which pays for the city, and not the city which justifies its existence in terms

    of efficacy, because capital accumulation systematically drains resources and manpower from the

    periphery into core to establish the conditions for an urban take-off.

    This transfer of exchange of surplus connects all the society's economic, social, political and ideological

    organization. That is, the transfer, exchange or sharing of surplus connects the urban elite not only to theworkers from the periphery. Surplus transfer also allows the emergence of elites in the periphery

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    6/18

    reproducing the same processes of surplus management, their structures of exploitation and oppression by

    class and gender, which characterize the urban core. Through sharing sources of surplus the urban elite

    and the social classes it exploits inside the urban area are systematically interlinked to the mode of

    accumulation in rural elites in the periphery. By extension, if part of the surplus of rural elite is also

    traded for part of the surplus accumulated by rural elites in more distant peripheries, then not only coreand periphery, but also related cities and rural territories are systematically connected in the same over-

    arching system of accumulation. Core-periphery systems are in fact never isolated, but they configure a

    complex network of interlinked social units (Frank 1993, Gills and Frank 1992).

    The historical formation of the Rural-Urban (or Periphery/Center) continuum is then a progression of

    social and behavioural differentiation. It is a social process involving three main spatial factors:

    concentration, accessibility and interaction. They explain the formation (concentration forces), the

    location (accessibility), and its shape (organization). As density of population increases, so areal

    specialisation results. The competition for space becomes so great that each area in the city tends to be put

    to the uses which yield the greatest economic return. The size of the social group determines the nature of

    human relationships. Elites can mobilize enough power to control the agricultural population once the

    nucleated settlements grow large enough. The critical consideration in determining whether spatial

    aggregates of people will form unequal urban systems is whether the power of the local elites is sufficient

    to enforce rural to urban migration in excess of the natural level of population growth.

    In simple economies, one or two forces act strongly upon the system so that a single concentration is able

    to expand, by growing to dominance. As economic complexity increases, so does the range of urban

    specialization, so that there are many more stimuli to urban growth, and with the increasing size of

    intermediate and smaller centres, a rank size pattern emerges. New social groups develop with the control

    and management of the resources and production tools, administrate the economy and the surplus,

    strongly influencing the economical process, and acquire power from the products coming from the

    subordinate classes and labour force at their dependence. The consequence of replacement of old

    egalitarian relationships is an increased social differentiation, spatially mediated, with concentration of

    the economical and political power in separate sites. Spatially differentiated areas emerge (the Cities),

    where the elites will live, controlling the production but not doing the productive activities, while the

    territories, sites and regions depending from the city, are the places where production activities are

    performed and address their products to the city.

    Why the spatial effects of social differentiation seem fast always regular? Why is so usual to find core-

    periphery relationships, if spatial consequences of surplus transfer may be so diverse? The range of

    possible spatial locations for capital accumulation may be very great. Even a state of the system where

    capital is accumulated at a central place, seems rather an exception than a rule. An explanation of this fact

    comes from the analysis of social dynamics. The exploitation of the working class and the process of

    accumulation of capital requires a continuous process of urbanization, because of the search for ever

    lower costs of production and higher productivity, which favours geographic regions which allow savings

    in production. Individual economic units are obliged to embark on the process of accumulation because

    they are competing with each other and therefore have to emply their income (profit) in order to remain

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    7/18

    competitive, which means increasing labour productivity and exploitation margins and reducing the

    production costs of goods. Production has to be increased in order to retain competitiveness: profits are

    invested such a way the production cycle increases. Therefore capital concentration grows continuously

    (Miginone 1981). In general, the progressive concentration of capital leads to the exclusion of a section of

    producers from the market, since they cannot keep up with competition because their limited basic capitaldoes not allow them to produce at ever lower costs. At the same time, capital's discrimination between

    more profitable and less profitable sectors reproduce a deep economic dualism. Highly concentrated

    capital increasing exploits and discriminates against those sectors which are least able to practise capital

    concentration.

    The behaviour of individuals is influenced by the size of settlement and by the relative location of cities.

    This may increase the inertia of the system. Such inertia is certainly another characteristic of urban

    dynamics, and it can be explained by the fact that a city is not only an aggregate of inhabitants but it also

    has a material built-up structure. This concrete inscription of processes of accumulation of wealth and

    values slows down the momentary trends, which would tend to change the ordering of the cities in the

    urban hierarchy. In other words, spatial flows (interaction) emerge as a result of dynamic spatial

    configurations.

    The process can be described in the following terms: 1) An agricultural population grows, and an early

    human concentration emerges. 2) Those early cities provide a power base for emerging local elites, and

    their policies encouraging urban goods production lead to a rapid population shift from the periphery to

    the core area. 3) That moves some rural areas into net population decrease. 4) Elite control over the

    increased urban population continues until wealth produced and accumulated at the urban sector is no

    longer enough to maintain control over the transfers from periphery. 5) When elites lose control over

    social and economic interaction between core and periphery, urban population rebels or emigrates to the

    countryside. 6) If the regional population has decreased to the point that urban centers are weak and the

    population is restive, loss of control over the population in one polity can spread rapidly; the local urban

    centre is sacked and many of the elite are killed, and the population then flees elite control. With no one

    left, remaining local elite groups begin hiring mercenaries to help them take over areas in better shape.

    The loss of elite control over large portions of the countryside gives the peasantry refuges against tribute

    collection and elite control, leading to further migration and further decrease of the population of the

    remaining elite centres. Eventually, only locations isolated from the population movements or attractive

    to population can maintain the old levels. 7) System collapse takes place, the urban centres rapidly

    disappear, and the system returns to an agricultural economy and the first stage of the cycle (Frank 1993,

    Erwin 1997).

    This process suggest a non linear dependence of political power on urbanization. The intensity and

    duration of the urban process (involving the internal dynamics, dialectical and social struggle) is

    connected with the increasing spatial complexity and hierarchy. The dominance of single nucleated

    settlements is the final step of a process beginning with individual farms scattered over a territory, single

    village formation/nucleated village emergence/extension of the nucleated villages out of their areal

    borders/ and the formation of depending territories. By implication, control over population movements

    should be a primary concern of any emerging elites. This reflect the necessity to organize a region co-

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    8/18

    operatively with a common elite culture to stabilize local polities against emigration. The requirement for

    multiple centres, rather than a single city, is due to the limited span of control of local elite groups.

    Without cooperation between local elite groups in neighbouring areas, agriculturalists had the option of

    migrating away. The urban system at this stage of development can not produce enough surplus to

    support additional levels of hierarchy and centralized control that would not be available until theintroduction of the market system. It is in this context, where the very notion of Territory and political

    frontier appears. Once the system begins to generate a surplus, and is able to reproduce the means of

    capital accumulation, it depends critically of the frontiers created that ensure the dominance of periphery

    from the city. But when the reproduction of the frontier is impossible, capital transfers from periphery to

    the centre result in a cyclical process of expansion and contraction.

    The social processes towards the "origins of the city are necessary the same as those bringing to the

    "origins of the state", the "origins of social division of labour", or even the "origins of capital

    accumulation". The urban process is dependent upon the larger social order in which it occurs, and does

    not operate independently of that order. The city has to be studied as a relevant phenomenon in the

    context of production and distribution. The key point is here that the uneven spatial distribution of

    population and resources is a fundamental aspect of the general social reproduction process.

    Consequently, the increase of social power is always related to urbanization and the controlled nature of

    spatial interaction.

    The Origins of the City as an Archaeological Process. Towards an Observational Theory

    Given that the origins of the city is only a material (observable) effect of the origins of the State and the

    formation of class society, we should use this definition of the city and its dynamics in order to observe

    class society in the archaeological record. That is, State or class society are theoretical entities, without

    clear observable referents. Built spaces and human settlement concentrations are observable entities

    which should be related to social processes

    Our problem is then to understand the causal process producing the spatial accumulation of capital, and

    its "urban" consequences, as present in the archaeological record: spatial division of labour and the

    emergence of core-periphery relationships between the locus of capital accumulation and the hinterland

    whose exploitation allows the reproduction of the capital accumulation process.

    Accumulation implies Concentration. That is, concentration of people, resources and means of production

    is only the spatial appearance of the capital accumulation process. Consequently, where we find

    archaeological evidences of capital accumulation, we should calculate whether it is a related increase in

    the probability of human settlement in the vicinity or not, and then to be able to infer the existence of a

    dialectical process od territorial domination.

    Our preliminary investigation should be then the analysis of the degree of accumulation, in terms of the

    spatial concentration of capital components. Therefore, we have to investigate:

    The archaeological correlates for generators of capital accumulation the archaeological correlates for restraints on capital accumulation

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    9/18

    We begin by measuring qualitatively the presence/absence of social actions (settlement, resources

    acquisition, labour action, distributive/exchange activities, ritual action). For instance:

    Presence/absence of colonial import goods Presence/absence of indigenous import goods (pottery, metal) Presence/absence of locally produced valuable pottery Presence/absence of weapons Presence/absence of metallurgical activities Presence/absence of store buildings and structures Presence/absence rich burials Presence/absence of complex residential structures (multi-room houses) Presence/absence of subsistence activities (farming, husbandry, etc.)

    This data allow us to calculate the following factors:

    SPATIAL DENSITY OR SETTLEMENT CONCENTRATION. It is the Dependent Variable in our model. It

    can be empirically measured in terms of a spatial probability density measure associated to each location,

    based on the geographical proximity with neighbouring locations. Concentration maps, however, can be

    misleading. The causal mechanism of urban emergence is not physical proximity, nor spatial density. The

    real cause should be explained in terms of the influence capital accumulated at a location has over the

    residence or productive actions performed at other locations in the proximity . The analysis then pretends

    to examine if the characteristics in one location have anything to do with characteristics in a neighbour

    location through the definition of a general model of spatial dependence (Barcel & Pallars 1998,

    Barcel this volume).

    GLOBAL INTERACTION. If settlement concentration is a relevant variable, then distance is one of the

    main dynamic factor determining the process of city formation. Spatial Interaction is related to distance,

    in such a way that the less distance between social actor, the higher the probabilities of social interaction.

    If a city is a topological point where social interaction has its higher levels, then, any modification of the

    settlement pattern towards an increasing concentration of sites, and a reduction of inter site distances,

    should be also related. However, we have to remember that a city is not only a spatial container of people.

    It is an attractorfor interactions all interactions generated in its periphery and directed to the core area.

    Interaction flows between various places are proportional to the probability of contacts of their residents,

    and this probability is a function of the size of the places. We need demographic estimates to calculate the

    theoretical maximum degree of interaction depending on population. Demographic estimates can be

    obtained through extension measures of settlement areas (Hassan 1981). Estimates are always misleading,

    but we are not interested in the real figures of population at different historical phases, but in the

    population growth indexes. We will never been sure of the population during the 10 th century BC, but we

    can calculate if population grows or not between 10th. and 8th centuries.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    10/18

    DOMINANCE AND COERCION. We need to estimate also the inequality and directionality of

    interaction flows. In other words, we have to integrate into the model the hierarchy between core and

    periphery. We are studying the differentiation between the emergent urban core and the exploited rural

    periphery, therefore, capital accumulated in the center is a function of capital extracted from the

    periphery, and transferred:

    by force (through taxation) trough the coercitive fixation of prices between the city commodities and countryside

    commodities.

    through market relationships (supply and demand). It is always easier for urban products(manufacture) to be monopolized, than for agricultural goods.

    Therefore, if Power and Dominance may be analysed in terms of spatial attraction, then the inequality of

    interaction from core to periphery is directly proportional to capital generated in both points, and

    inversely proportional to the cost of coercion and domination

    ATTRACTION. The attraction force exerted by a city core area is directly proportional to the number

    or intensity of interactions between periphery locations and the centerand the squared distance between

    both entities, and inversely proportional to the attraction force exerted by alternative periphery locations.

    Local factors may be understood in terms of locally accumulated mobile capital (for instance: quantity of

    colonial imported goods, presence/absence of metallurgical luxury objects). If we consider process of

    capital accumulation at the city, then the volume of capital or wealth accumulated there is directly

    proportional to the level of dominance or power of the city over the surrounding rural area, plus the

    frictional effects due to the cost of coercion, and inversely proportional to the total amount of capital

    accumulated at the periphery. The more productive is a location, and the more independent are their local

    elites, the most difficult is to ensure dominance and capital transfers from periphery to core areas.

    MIGRATORY FLOWS. It is a measure of the probability of social agents at a given point of the periphery

    i travelling to a given urban centre j because of the work advantages the urban centre has to offer. It

    implies the conversion of human labour into a good, and the social consequences of market relationships.

    Core area attracts not only interaction flows, but also people from the countryside who go to the city for

    obtaining resources in the urban labour market. One of the main reasons to explain demographic

    advantages of urban-core areas is the increase in population due to migratory flows. Consequently, net

    migration is also roughly proportional to city size, as long as the migration and out-migration flows are

    also proportional to this size (D.L.Huff 1963, see also Carter 1972, Nijkamp and Reggiani 1992).

    We can obtain estimates of population and population growths, but migratory flows fast never are

    represented in the archaeological record. This is a sensible lack of archaeological information. In any

    case, the relevance of migration depends on the development of labour market. Migratory fluxes were not

    especially relevant in Europe until Industrial Revolution. It is important to differentiate those migratory

    fluxes to global population movements or settlement waves. The relevance of migration can be estimated

    in terms of population growth beyond fertility rates. If population estimates in an urban area increase in a

    very short time interval, beyond the reproductive rate, we have to include a migratory factor.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    11/18

    The Origins of the City as an Archaeological Phenomenon. The Etruscan Case

    It is in CentralItalian peninsula, ancient Etruria, where between the Final Bronze Age and the first Iron

    Age began a social process towards the development of cities. This process took place in a relativelyshort chronological period of time when scattered villages began an aggregation process (sinecism)

    towards urban formations (ProtoCities and City-State). It is particularly interesting the case South

    Etruria, and the formation of the city of Tarquinia. It can be considered a very suitable example and one

    of the most important (in its evolution from late Bronze Age to Early Iron Age) (Mandolesi 1999).

    Tarquinias historical territory consists of the Etruscan urban site called Civita and a vast region around it

    connected with important ancient roads. This area located between the coast line and the Marta river

    valley, once an important route to inner Etruria, was the heart of a very fertile land whose richness came

    from the sea, the coastal lagoon, the great extent of woods and the proximity of Tolfa mountains mineral

    deposits. The territory of Tarquinia is a homogeneous geographical area characterized since proto-history

    by a strong historical, political, cultural and economic unity. Here villages founded at the end of the

    Bronze Age gave rise to the development of Iron Age Tarquinia (9th-8th centuries B.C.) (Mandolesi

    1999).

    Archaeological researches at the Civita, focus of the settlement of Tarquinia, brought to light a relevant

    presence of Iron Age findings covering an area of 150 hectares, the average size of proto-urban villages

    rising on plateaux in coastal Etruria. The Civita Villanovan settlement develops on a vast area including

    several wide, flat summits (Pian di Civita, Pian della Regina, Castellina, Cretoncini). The bounds of the

    settlement, defined by the findings emerging on the surface, correspond exactly to the natural edges of the

    plateau. The proto-historical materials prove that the Iron Age settlement covered the whole surface of

    the Civita and had a high population density. Moreover, the even distribution of Villanovan remains

    shows the unitary character of the proto-urban settlement. The archaeological situation allows us to

    hypothesize the existence of a village organized into a number of neighbourhoods of different

    dimensions, each one consisting of several houses and functional constructions. They covered the whole

    plateau and were separated from each others by small fields destined to farming, breeding and open-air

    working activities.

    Several Iron Age cemeteries have been traced all around the Civita (Poggio Selciatello, Poggio SopraSelciatello, Impiccato, Poggio della Sorgente, Quarto degli Archi, San Savino, Civitucola, Gallinaro)

    some of which dating from the end of the Bronze Age. The burial areas tend to surround the vast

    Villanovan settlement according to a model traced in many other sites of Etruria (Veio, Cerveteri, Vulci,

    Bisenzio, Vetulonia). The cemeteries organization around the main site at the Pian di Civita plateau

    presents a radial disposition of the burials around the scattered villages of the previous phase, and are

    aligned directly to their original and dispersed pattern (with spatial neighbourhood between the burials

    and the settlements). From the half of the 8th century. B.C., the Cretoncini hill is no longer used as a

    settlement and a small cemetery developped in the area. At the end of the 7th. century B.C., however, the

    suburban area is inhabited again and constructions used for farming activities are built.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    12/18

    At the beginning of the Iron Age the Monterozzi hill, seat of the major Etruscan necropolis in Tarquinia,

    is settled. The area, located between the Civita hill and the coast line, was in a perfect strategic position as

    for territory control. Here, in contrast with the archaeological situation found on the Civita where one

    large settlement covers the whole plateau, three isolated Villanovan villages have been traced so far

    (Calvario, Infernaccio, Acquetta). They are separated from each others by large fields used for farmingand herding. These villages were presumably dependent on the proto-urban centre of the Civita. They

    played not only a strategic role controlling the coastal area and the roads that lead from the cost to the

    Civita, but also an economic role based on the exploitation of the vast coastal plain and lagoon, both rich

    in natural resources. The most important site at Monterozzi is the Calvario settlement where the

    excavations allowed the analysis, even if partial, of the urban organization of a Villanovan village

    covering an area of more than two hectares. Here rectangular shaped huts are flanked by more traditional

    oval shaped constructions probably used for functional purposes such as storage, stabling or working

    activities. These oval huts were probably dependent on the rectangular ones, presumably the houses,

    while the areas between them were probably destined to open-air domestic and working activities

    (Linnington et al. 1978). The dominant topographic position of this village compared to the other

    settlements at Monterozzi leads to the hypothis that the Calvario was the main centre on the hill, the

    focus where all strategic and economic activities carried out by the smaller villages (about one hectare)

    were planned and organized.

    The Tarquinian community began to exploit coastal resources at the end of the Bronze Age when small

    villages rise along the lagoon. At the beginning of the Iron Age an intense settlement of the coastal region

    takes place. The materials found at the Saline display a large quantity of impasto containers while there is

    little evidence of pottery for domestic use. It is worth noting that domestic pottery is usually found in

    great quantity only in coastal areas destined to residential purposes. Therefore, the absence of this kind of

    pottery and the abundance of container fragments in certain sites should presumably be the evidence of

    productive activities carried out in the area. In the case of the Saline site we can presume the presence of

    different specialized activities such as food storage and preservation and salt production. In ancient times

    salt was considered an extremely important resource not only for the preservation of meat but also for its

    religious significance being considered a protective, apotropaic element. An interesting theory concerning

    the Saline hypothesize a massive salt production in the area and a consequent exportation of it as a means

    of exchange to the most of Southern Etruria.

    As a consequence of east Mediterranean colonialism, this coastal area becomes an important attraction

    centre. Along with the proto-urban centre of the Civita another large and organized settlement develops

    on the coast in the Saline area. It is the bigger port of Villanovan Etruria ever discovered so far. It

    occupied an area of at least 60 hectares and it was probably organized into different sectors where various

    activities linked with sailing and marine resources exploitation took place. The archaeological materials

    found in the settlement lead us to hypothesize the existence of a functional area with berthing places,

    warehouses for the exchanged goods and for the preservation (salting) of sea food. The residential area

    was located in the inner part of the site, behind the sector destined to economic activities.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    13/18

    At the same time a number of little villages rose along the coast of Tarquinia, and not only on the Saline

    area. Their archaeological layers have been brought to light by the erosive action of the sea on the sandy

    cliffs. The archaeological excavations on the sites located in the southern coastal area brought to light

    residential and functional constructions. In the villages of Mattonara and Torre Valdaliga round shaped

    huts feature pits of different shapes and dimensions dug into the rock (Bellardelli & Pascucci 1999).Some of them were meant for supply and food storing and cooking whereas others were used as basins

    for seafood preserving processes. The overall economy of these coastal centres was therefore based not

    only on trade and exchanges but also on the exploitation of marine resources, even though the main centre

    for these kind of activities remained the Saline settlement. In the site of Acque Fresche an area destined

    to food preservation has come to light. It is an elliptic construction used in late Iron Age (second half

    VIII sec. B.C.) equipped with a circular furnace. The fact that most materials found here are impasto

    containers, shows that the site was destined to specialized preservation activities based on the use of fire

    (Mandolesi & Trucco 2000).

    The geographical vicinity and the homogeneity of the materials found in the coastal villages show that

    they were connected by social and economic links, probably under the political and cultural control of

    Tarquinia. The coastal settlements are therefore to be considered as a unit designed according to a precise

    project of the Tarquinian community. The coastal territory of Tarquinia appears divided into two different

    areas: the main settlement of the Saline, directly ruled by the political centre of the Civita and rising on

    the coast right in front of it, and this series of little villages covering the southern part of the Tarquinian

    coast. They were probably meant to control sailing along the coast making profits on the flourishing

    trading and exchanging activities which took place in the central Tyrrhenian sea at the time. They also

    controlled the routes from the coast to the Tolfa Mountains protecting their precious mineral deposits

    (Mandolesi 1999, Pacciarelli 2000).

    Towards the end of the Iron Age (late VIII sec. B.C.) the southern coastal area seems to be abandoned

    while another settlement develops on the nearby hill called Castellina del Marangone (Gran-Aymerich

    2001). The village was located in a strategic position from which it was possible to control most of the

    coast line. The large quantity and high quality of the pottery findings uncovered on the site (imported

    geometric pottery), together with its strategic position on the main route to the mineral deposits of the

    Tolfa Mountains (Marangone valley), prove the great importance of this settlement. Densely populated

    during the Bronze Age, the mountainous region of Tolfa seems to be almost abandoned at the beginningof the Iron Age. This phenomenon is probably due to the increasing settlement of the Tarquinian coastal

    area encouraged by a powerful political and social organ whose goal is to create an administrative centre

    at the Civita. Only in the VIII sec. B.C., once again following a design of Tarquinia to control and exploit

    the northern area of the mineral deposits, the Tolfa Mountains start to be inhabited again and small

    villages are founded.

    In conclusion, on the basis of this complex archaeological framework, it is possible to analyse the

    different areas ofCivita, Monterozzi, Salin, Southern coast, and even the Tolfa Mountains as a whole.

    They were parts of the same large territory and productive system organized by one community whose

    administrative focus was represented by the Civita centre.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    14/18

    The process can be described in terms of a a very gradual process of spatial concentration and capital

    attraction, where a core area placed on a large and uniform plateau, exerced domination upon the

    surrounding hills, mountains and coastal areas. Inertia is certainly another characteristic of such a

    dynamic system, and it can be explained by the fact that a evolving core area is not only an aggregate of

    inhabitants but that it also has a material built-up structure (capital contectration), which attracts spatialflows of capital (people, resources, information). Consequently the location of the main administrative

    center (the Civita) is not adapted to environmental conditions or resources, but it is the place where

    social agents perform actions like capital accumulation and the reproduction of capital accumulation

    through political and social control. The behaviour of individuals is influenced by the size of settlement

    and by the relative location of cities.

    We are not looking for an optimal spatial allocation of resources, but studying how the spatial features of

    capital accumulation are related to the development of spatial division of labour, which imploded in a

    unique geographical and topographical point or core area, because of the social difference expressed in

    spatial inequalities. A large and densely occupied core area was surrounded by different settlements

    through a network of dominance relationships. The core area built and reproduced spatial dominance on

    the base of social and economic activities that promoted a market economy, linked to the exchanges,

    trades and goods circulation. The urban centre became the crossroads for the network of the economical

    activities and interaction flows.

    This change was favoured by the emerging clientes relationships, depending on the elites. These

    dominated population acts as labour force able to increase the elites prestige; it is maintained and payed

    for its work, and it is specialized in some specific activities, according to the elite needs. The consequence

    is the appearance of a true market and exchange economy. At first this new economic setting is defined

    on a local scale, and after on a global dimension: this one implies an increase of the elites capital

    accumulation, their control on the craftsmanship and specialized activities. In this way, the origin of the

    city is also determined by the development of a territorial division of work, which relates in an unequal tie

    the developed societies of the Near East and indigenous central/western Mediterranean societies.

    We may compare the Etruscan way to urban systems with older process that first began in the Near East.

    Old Eastern cities represented the main agglomerations within very large territories: the Town became

    the main centre for the work specialization, while the smaller centres are subjected to lose their

    importance in this framework (LIVERANI 1986). The situation of the Near East is characterized by a

    very strong State organization, centred on the Towns that acquire a predominant rule and, from an

    autocratic and organizing point of view, carry out a very large effort, coordinating and controlling the

    territories on the largest scale, and extending their influence at great distances. As a consequence, the

    Town exercises its absolute power on a very large territory, against the smaller centres absorbed in the

    urban predominance. The hegemonic and centralized control on a very large scale is connected also to

    some needs of the environmental planning, deriving from the physical conditions and the management of

    the great alluvial plains (LIVERANI 1986).

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    15/18

    CONCLUDING REMARKS

    In this paper, we have archaeologically defined a city or town in terms of some specific built space. We

    use this concept as an archaeologically observable effect (correlate) of unobservable social processes,

    especially capital accumulation and social division of labour.

    We have tried to study the differentiation between the emergent urban core and the exploited rural

    periphery. The main point to focus is to understand the origin of town and cities in terms of

    intensification of production and concentration of wealth and capital, and the transformation of relations

    of production, characterized by a transition from domestic production to different forms of capital

    accumulation, individual enrichment, and class formation.

    In the case commented here, during the Iron Age, Tarquinia territory (1000 km2) was structured by the

    attraction force of a core area (City), concentrating the political, social and economic functions, over a

    periphery, where primary raw material production was located. This spatially more dense area is viewed

    as a deep and narrow attraction basin where all locations -settlements- are concentrated. Nucleated

    settlement in the Pian the Civita area was followed by the further spatial articulation in neighbouring

    Monterozzi and Saline area, in search for maritime resources. In a colonial economy (8th century BC

    onwards) the control and dominance of coastal areas is basic. This fact is exemplified by the creation of

    the Graviscaeemporium, which represented a first step in the origins of market circulation of resources,

    and favoured the participation of emergent towns into a network of traffics and exchanges. The Town

    became a focal junction of the exchanges utilizing directly the emporium for the immediate and fluent

    contact with the foreign colonial centres, which enable indigenous societies the participation into a market

    economy on a larger scale.

    This spatial configuration is also reproduced in the organization of ritual areas (cemeteries), initially

    surrounding the Civita and constituted by the cemeteries of the Eastern Hills (Poggio Selciatello, Poggio

    dellImpiccato). The location of cemeteries later extended in direction of the Monterozzi hill, where a

    new strategic area for the control of the market and the exploitation of the maritime resources emerged.

    Monterozzi becomes the main funerary area with individual and monumental burials depending from the

    Civita. The situation of Tarquinia cemeteries is interesting for the understanding of the complex dynamics

    that, together with the increasing social complexity, lead to an increasing spatial articulation through:

    dispersion, expansion and organization in a core area, further extension of the core area, final concentration in a great nucleous (the City and City-State)

    The consequence of all these social and spatial transformations is the creation of a very clear ideological

    frontier between Live and Death, Town (Pian di Civita) and Cemetery (Monterozzi). This ideological

    frontier appears also in other ambits the division between the Exchange areas (represented by the rest of

    the territory and the maritime lagoons) and the Political ones (the imploded Town), or between these ones

    and the Agrarian.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    16/18

    This historical process has been usually explained in terms of traditional economic theory, that is,

    prehistoric populations were looking for better resource allocation, in connection with agrarian facilities,

    salt, metal resources and exchange routes.

    Classical theory is empirically wrong, because the friction factor is not only travelling costs. We are not

    looking for an optimal spatial allocation of resources, because the causal mechanism of urban emergence

    is not the physical proximity to valuable resources or routes, nor the spatial density of human settlement

    locations. On the opposite, greater spatial interaction is more likely to appear where the effects of unequal

    exchange and social exploitation are also higher. The real cause should be explained in terms of the

    influence capital accumulated at a location has over the residence or productive actions performed at

    other locations in the proximity. Empirical evidence of inter-penetrating wealth or capital accumulation

    between the city and the rural countryside through the transfer or exchange of surplus is the minimum

    indicator of the action of this social process. Concomitantly, we should seek evidence that this inter-

    linkage causes at least some element of economic and/or political restructuring in the respective zones.

    In the Tarquinia case, spatial nucleation and the territorial expansion of dominance relatonships was

    accompanied by a social transformation from tribal and kinship structures, to the emergence of elites.

    Evidences of social change are very clear during Early Iron Age: increase of agrarian production and

    productivity, control of strategic resources, like the metals (also favoured by the introduction of a

    colonial market economy through the contacts with Greece and Eastern Mediterranean Empires).

    References

    Barcelo,J.A., Pallares,M., 1998, Beyond GIS: The archaeology of social spaces Archeologia eCalcolatori Num. 9, pp. 47-80

    Belardelli, C., Pascucci, P., 1999, Torre Valdaliga and La Mattonara. InAtti del Convegno F. RittatoreVonwiller e la Maremma, 1936-1976: paesaggi naturali, umani, archeologici: Ischia di Castro, pp. 79-102.

    Berry, B., Horton, F.E. 1970, Geographic perspectives on urban systems. New Jersey, Prentice-Hall.

    Camagni,R., 1992,Economia Urbana. Roma. La Nuova Italia Scientifica.

    Christaller, W., 1933,Die Zentralle rte in Sddeutschland. Jena, Gustav Fischer Verlag.

    Clark, D., 1982, Urban Geography The John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

    Dicken, P., Lloyd, P.E., 1990,Location in Space Harper and Row, Publ. New York.

    Erwin, H.R., 1997, The dynamics of peer polities. In Time, process and structured transformation inarchaeology. Edited by S. E. van der Leeuw and J. McGlade. London, Routledge.

    Frank, A.G., 1993, The Bronze Age world system and its cycles. Current Anthropology 34(3).

    Gills, B.K., and Frank, A.G., 1992, (eds.) The World System. Five Hundred Years or Five Thousand?Routledge, London and New York.

    Gran-Aymerich, J., Le Castellina prs de Civitavecchia: les travaux en cours par lquipe du CNRS. In

    XXIII Convegno Studi Etruschi ed Italici Dinamiche di sviluppo delle citt nellEtruria meridionale:Veio, Caere, Tarquinia, Vulci, (Roma-S.Marinella-Tarquinia-Montalto di Castro-Viterbo), 1-6 ottobre2001, Firenze, (in corso di stampa)

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    17/18

    Huff, D.L., 1963, A probabilistic analysis of shopping centre trade areas Land. Econ., 39, p. 81.

    Linington, R.E., Delpino, F., Pallottino, M., 1978, Alle origini di Tarquinia: scoperta di un abitato

    villanoviano sui Monterozzi. In Studi Etruschi, XLVI, pp. 3-23.

    Lsch, A., 1939, The Economics of Location Yale University Press (english translation, 1954).

    Mandolesi, A., 1999, Allorigine dellAger Tarquiniensis: il cantone meridionale tarquiniese nella prima

    et del Ferro. In Leopoli-Cencelle. Una citt di fondazione papale, Le preesistenze, I. Roma: PalombiEditori, pp. 19-35.

    Mandolesi, A., Trucco, F., 2000, Labitato costiero della prima et del Ferro di Acque Fresche

    (Civitavecchia). InAtti Preistoria e Protostoria in Etruria, IV. Firenze: Octavo, pp. 376-382.

    Mingione,E., 1981, Social Conflict and the City Blackwell Publ. Oxford.

    Nijkamp, P., Reggiani, A., 1992,Interaction, Evolution and Chaos in Space. Springer Verlag. Berlin.

    Pacciarelli, M., 2000, Dal villaggio alla citt. La svolta protourbana del 1000 a.C. nellItalia tirrenica,Grandi contesti e problemi della Protostoria italiana, 4. Firenze: AllInsegna del Giglio, pp. 170-176.

    Pumain, D., 1997, City-size dynamics in urban systems. In Time, process and structuredtransformation in archaeology. Edited by S. E. van der Leeuw and J. McGlade. London, Routledge.

    Wheeler, J.O., Muller, P.O., Thrall, G.I., Fik, T.J., 1998,Economic Geography John Wiley Publ. London.

  • 7/29/2019 Barcelo, Pelfer, Mandolesi - THE ORIGINS OF THE CITY FROM SOCIAL THEORY TO ARCHAEOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION.

    18/18