Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

182
Banking reform, and the importance of ownership: how the way banks are owned affects their behaviour A thesis submitted to the University of Manchester for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Faculty of Humanities 2018 Michael Wilkinson Alliance Manchester Business School People, Management and Organisation

Transcript of Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

Page 1: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

   

 Banking  reform,  and  the  importance  of  ownership:    

how  the  way  banks  are  owned  affects  their  behaviour  

     

A  thesis  submitted  to  the  University  of  Manchester    for  the  degree  of  Doctor  of  Philosophy  in  the  

Faculty  of  Humanities        

2018    

Michael  Wilkinson              

Alliance  Manchester  Business  School  People,  Management  and  Organisation  

   

   

Page 2: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  2  

Table  of  Contents  

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT   5  

ABSTRACT   6  

LIST  OF  CHARTS   7  

LIST  OF  TABLES   8  

LIST  OF  STATUTES   9  

DECLARATION  AND  COPYRIGHT  STATEMENT   10  

LIST  OF  ABBREVIATIONS   11  

CHAPTER  1.   INTRODUCTION   12  1.1   INTRODUCTION   12  1.2   PART  1:  BANK  OWNERSHIP,  AND  BANK  BEHAVIOUR   12  1.3   PART  2:  HOW  TO  EXPLORE  OWNERSHIP  AND  BEHAVIOUR?   15  

CHAPTER  2.   THE  BANKING  REFORM  AGENDA:  PRESERVING  THE  STATUS  QUO  18  2.1   INTRODUCTION   18  2.2   PART  1:  THE  ‘OFFICIAL  RESPONSE’   20  2.2.1   CONTROLLING  THE  DEBATE   20  2.2.2     SIR  ‘WIN’  BISCHOFF  AND  BOB  WIGLEY  –  PLEDGING  ALLEGIANCE  TO  THE  CITY   21  2.2.3   LORD  TURNER  –  PRESERVING  LIGHT  TOUCH  REGULATION   22  2.2.4   THE  BANKING  CRISIS  INQUIRY  –  THE  WRONG  BODY   23  2.2.5   SIR  DAVID  WALKER  –  PROTECTING  SHAREHOLDER-­‐OWNERSHIP   25  2.2.6   SIR  JOHN  KAY  –  REFORMING  EQUITY  MARKETS,  NOT  OWNERSHIP   27  2.2.7   SIR  JOHN  VICKERS  –  PRESERVING  UNIVERSAL  BANKING   28  2.2.8   PARLIAMENTARY  COMMISSION  ON  BANKING  STANDARDS  –  A  MISSED  OPPORTUNITY   29  2.2.9   THE  COMPETITIONS  AND  MARKETS  AUTHORITY  INVESTIGATION–A  STANDARD  RECIPE?   31  2.3   PART  2:  THE  WIDER  DEBATE   32  2.3.1   WHAT  WAS  MISSED?   32  2.3.2     CHALLENGING  THE  ‘OWNERSHIP’  PARADIGM   34  2.3.3     CHALLENGING  THE  ‘STRUCTURAL’  PARADIGM   35  2.4   CONCLUSIONS   38  

CHAPTER  3.   ‘OWNERSHIP  PRESSURES’:  WHAT  IT  IS,  TO  BE  OWNED?   39  3.1     INTRODUCTION   39  3.2   PART  1:  HISTORY   41  3.2.1   THE  BIRTH  OF  THE  CORPORATION   41  3.2.2     THE  RISE  OF  THE  STOCK  MARKET   44  3.3   PART  2:  DEFINING  CORPORATE  PURPOSE   45  3.4   PART  3:  THE  EMERGING  SHAREHOLDER  VALUE  PARADIGM   49  3.4.1   ENTRENCHING  THE  PARADIGM   52  3.5     PART  4:  THE  BACK-­‐LASH,  AND  RISE  OF  STAKEHOLDER  THEORY   53  3.6   CONCLUSION   55  

CHAPTER  4.   ‘STRUCTURAL  PRESSURES’  AND  COPING  WITH  THEM:  SURVIVING  IN  THE  ‘WILD  WEST’  FOLLOWING  THE  ‘BIG  BANG’   56  

Page 3: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  3  

4.1   INTRODUCTION   56  4.2   PART  1:  THE  SHIFT  FROM  INTERMEDIATION  TO  CREDIT-­‐CREATION   58  4.2.1   THE  EXPLOSION  OF  CREDIT-­‐CREATION   58  4.2.2     REMOVING  CONSTRAINTS  ON  CREDIT-­‐CREATION   61  4.3   PART  2:  THE  SHIFT  FROM  PRODUCTIVE  INVESTMENT  TO  PROPERTY-­‐LENDING   63  4.4   PART  3:  THE  SHIFT  INTO  RISKIER  BUSINESS   66  4.4.1     LAX  COMPETITION  CONTROL   69  4.5   PART  4:  THE  SHIFT  TOWARDS  EXPLOITING  RETAIL  CUSTOMERS   70  4.6   CONCLUSIONS   71  

CHAPTER  5.   METHODOLOGY   74  5.1     INTRODUCTION   74  5.2     PART  1:  THE  ONTOLOGICAL  AND  EPISTEMOLOGICAL  FRAMEWORK   74  5.3     PART  2:  THE  ESSENTIAL  INQUIRY   76  5.4     PART  3:  THE  METHODOLOGICAL  FRAMEWORK   78  5.4.1   WHY  NOT  OTHER  METHODOLOGIES?   79  5.4.2   LIMITS  OF  THE  INQUIRY  AND  METHODOLOGY   80  5.5     PART  4:  DESIGNING  THE  CASE  STUDY  RESEARCH   82  5.5.1   THEORY   82  5.5.2   CHOICE  OF  CASES   83  5.5.3   TIME  FRAME  FOR  STUDY   84  5.5.4   DATA  AND  SOURCES   85  5.5.5   TERMINOLOGY   91  5.6     PART  5:  SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSIONS   92  

CHAPTER  6.   ‘OWNERSHIP  PRESSURES’  AND  BARCLAYS  AND  LLOYDS   94  6.1     INTRODUCTION   94  6.2     PART  1:  DELIVERING  SHAREHOLDER  VALUE   95  6.2.1     COMMITTING  TO  THE  MARKET   95  6.2.2     EXCEEDING  EXPECTATIONS  -­‐  LLOYDS   96  6.2.3   THE  COST  OF  KEEPING  INVESTORS  HAPPY  –  LLOYDS   99  6.2.4     MEETING  MARKET  DEMAND  -­‐  BARCLAYS   103  6.2.5     EXCEEDING  EXPECTATIONS  -­‐  BARCLAYS   108  6.3     PART  2:  WHEN  THE  MARKET  DEMANDS  TOO  MUCH   110  6.3.1     LLOYDS’  STRATEGIC  BIND   110  6.3.2     DELIVERING  VALUE  IN  A  CRISIS  –  LLOYDS  AND  HBOS   114  6.3.3   AVOIDING  BAIL-­‐OUT  -­‐  BARCLAYS   117  6.3.4     BARCLAYS’  HALO   119  6.4     PART  3:  WIDESPREAD  MIS-­‐BEHAVIOUR,  AND  THE  NEED  FOR  REGIME  CHANGE   120  6.4.1   DIAMOND’S  DEPARTURE  -­‐  AMIDST  MARKET-­‐RIGGING   120  6.4.2     DANIELS’  DISAPPEARING  ACT  –  BEFORE  THE  PPI  SCANDAL   121  6.5   CONCLUSIONS   122  

CHAPTER  7.   ‘STRUCTURAL  PRESSURES’  AND  THE  CO-­‐OP  AND  THE  NATIONWIDE   124  7.1     INTRODUCTION   124  7.2     PART  1:  STRUCTURAL  PRESSURES,  AND  THE  CASE  OF  THE  CO-­‐OP   125  7.2.1   THE  CO-­‐OP’S  FAILURE   125  7.2.2   THE  CO-­‐OP’S  GROWTH  IMPERATIVE   127  7.2.3   GOVERNANCE  AND  OVERSIGHT  FAILURES   128  7.3     PART  2:  STRUCTURAL  PRESSURES  AND  THE  CASE  OF  THE  NATIONWIDE   132  7.3.1   THE  NATIONWIDE’S  RESILIENCE   132  

Page 4: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  4  

7.3.2     ITS  PART  IN  MIS-­‐SELLING   137  7.3.3   ITS  MORE  TRADITIONAL  BUSINESS   138  7.3.4     REINFORCING  FUNCTIONALISM   143  7.4     CONCLUSIONS   144  

CHAPTER  8.   CONCLUSION:  ‘OWNERLESSNESS’  MUST  BE  PART  OF  THE  SOLUTION   146  8.1   INTRODUCTION   146  8.2   PART  1:  THE  KEY  FINDINGS   147  8.2.1     EXTRACTIVE  OWNERSHIP  IS  NOT  FIT-­‐FOR-­‐PURPOSE   147  8.2.2   CHANGING  OWNERSHIP  IS  NOT  ENOUGH   149  8.2.3   THE  NEED  FOR  COMPARTMENTALISATION  AND  FUNCTIONAL  REGULATION   150  8.3   PART  2:  RELEVANCE  AND  IMPLICATIONS   151  8.3.1   IMPLICATIONS  FOR  REFORM   151  8.3.2   INADEQUACY  OF  CURRENT  REFORMS   152  8.3.3   SCOPE  FOR  DETERMINING  WHAT  WE  WANT  FROM  BANKS   153  8.3.4   REFORMS  UNRELATED  TO  OWNERSHIP   154  8.4   PART  3:  RE-­‐THINKING  AND  RE-­‐DESIGNING  OWNERSHIP   156  8.4.1   STAKEHOLDER  STEWARDS   156  8.4.2     A  PROPERLY  ‘OWNERLESS’  MODEL   158  8.4.3   AN  OWNERLESS  NATIONAL  INVESTMENT  BANK   161  8.4.4     ENCOURAGING  RESPONSIBILITY   162  8.5   PART  4:  EVALUATION  AND  CONTRIBUTION   163  8.6   CONCLUSIONS   164  

REFERENCES   167          WORD  COUNT:  76,834      

Page 5: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  5  

Acknowledgement  This  thesis  took  many  years  to  bring  to  completion,  and  would  not  have  

arrived  there  at  all  without  encouragement  from  a  range  of  remarkable  people,  to  whom  I  really  ought  to  say  a  word  of  thanks.  Between  having  the  idea  which  sparked  my  interest  in  what  became  this  thesis,  back  in  2002,  and  putting  a  part-­‐time  study  plan  into  action,  in  2010,  I  was  lucky  enough  to  be  shepherded  towards  doing  a  PhD  by  an  eclectic  assortment  of  bright  sparks.  Whilst  they  are  too  numerous  to  list  here,  I  am  thankful  to  them  for  pointing  me  in  the  direction  of  the  University  of  Manchester’s  Business  School,  where  I  had  the  good  fortune  to  encounter  my  eventual  tutors,  professors  Julie  Froud  and  Karel  Williams.  I  doubt  there  exist  any  two  persons  better  suited  to  the  task  of  guiding  me  through  the  journey  I  have  taken  to  write  this  thesis.  Julie  and  Karel  provided  me  with  tireless  support  and  direction  as  the  weeks  turned  to  months  and  the  months  to  years,  whilst  I  trundled  along  with  my  part-­‐time  writing,  also  keeping  a  busy  day  job.    They  have  taught  me  more  than  I  could  ever  thank  them  for,  and  lightened  my  burden  no  end  with  their  levity  and  humour.  They  also  put  me  in  touch  with  some  fascinating  sorts  at  Manchester’s  CRESC  with  whom  I  was  very  pleased  to  associate.    

I  should  also  like  to  express  some  thanks  to  my  examiners  for  taking  up  their  time  and  giving  me  the  benefit  of  their  insight  and  ideas.  They  helped  ensure  I  left  no  interesting  aspect  of  this  thesis  untouched.  In  the  same  vein,  I  should  add  to  that  list,    Adam  Leaver,  who  chaired  my  various  reviews  over  the  years.  Our  discussions  added  depth  and  dimension  to  my  inquiry.    

Last  but  by  no  means  least,  it  would  be  remiss  of  me  not  to  mention  my  long-­‐suffering,  and  significantly  better  half,  Vivian,  for  putting  up  with  my  peculiar  passion  for  the  subject  of  this  thesis,  when  I  dare  say  no  other  sane  person  would,  and  for  encouraging  me  to  keep  going  with  it.  This  thesis  would  not  have  been  written  without  her,  and  really  it  ought  to  belong  to  her,  but  alas,  in  her  honour,  I  would  instead  like  to  dedicate  it  to  our  son,  Lewin,  hoping  that  one  day  he  might  get  to  write  something  far  better  and  more  meaningful.      

   

Page 6: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  6  

 

Abstract  Despite  claims  made  by  the  UK  Government  in  2015  that  the  process  of  

banking  reform  had  come  to  an  end,  the  debate  about  how  to  reform  banks  very  much  continues.  There  is  now  an  increasing  willingness  to  question  both  whether  banks  should  be  owned  by,  and  run  for,  their  shareholders,  and  whether  the  role  they  play  in  creating  and  allocating  credit  can  safely  be  left  to  be  determined  solely  by  private  interests.    Where  banking  reform  goes  from  here  is  not  entirely  certain.  It  could  even  be  said  to  have  reached  something  of  a  fork  in  the  road.  The  obvious  way  open  to  us  is  to  continue  down  the  path  forged  by  the  neoliberal  agenda,  trusting  market  forces  to  determine  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation,  and  continuing  to  champion  the  banking  sector  as  a  sort  of  national  treasure  to  be  preserved  in  its  own  right.  An  alternative  course  could  be  to  more  radically  control  what  banks  do,  to  have  more  of  a  say  about  what  activities  they  should  finance  more  or  less  generously  and  to  treat  the  sector  not  as  an  end  in  itself,  but  more  as  a  means,  an  essential  engine  for  economic  growth  which  needs  to  be  more  carefully  controlled  and  driven.  

Whichever  way  we  go  from  here,  the  question  of  ‘ownership’  and  whether  it  needs  to  be  reformed  remains  relevant.  Indeed,  it  is  doubtful  whether  banks  can  really  be  trusted  to  behave  themselves  and  to  serve  our  interests  if  the  requirement  to  maximise  shareholder  returns  provides  conflicting  incentives  for  them  to  be  reckless,  self-­‐serving  and  exploitative.  Ultimately,  how  important  the  issue  of  ownership  is  depends  upon  how  far  the  way  banks  are  owned  drives  them  to  misbehave.  This  thesis  seeks  to  explore  that  relationship  and  its  relevance  to  banking  reform.  It  does  so  by  looking  at  how  pressures  arising  from  the  way  banks  are  owned  encourage  bad  strategic  decisions  and  bad  behaviours  in  a  number  of  UK  banks.  It  conducts  case  studies  of  two  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  and  two  shareholder-­‐owned  banks,  and  analyses  a  body  of  evidence  which  tends  very  strongly  to  suggest  that  the  way  banks  are  owned  is  indeed  liable  to  contribute  towards  the  adoption  of  unsafe  strategies,  and  bad  behaviours.      

The  thesis  proceeds  to  argue  that  we  still  need  to  tackle  this  ‘ownership’  problem  which  continues  to  drive  much  of  the  dysfunctionality  in  banking.    Fixing  ‘ownership’  will  not  necessarily  ensure  that  credit  is  created  in  sensible  quantities  and  allocated  in  sensible  ways  where  needed  in  the  economy,  and  it  will  not  be  the  only  reform  needed  to  discourage  bad  behaviour.  It  is  however  a  necessary  reform,  and  one  which  still  needs  to  be  made.  The  entire  notion  that  banks  are  owned  by  and  should  be  run  for  their  shareholders  needs  radically  to  be  reigned  in,  and  we  need  to  be  far  more  experimental  and  creative  in  exploring  ways  of  making  banks  act  more  like  stewards  or  trustees  administering  other  people’s  assets  –  and  in  safe  and  productive  ways  which  are  in  fitting  with  the  interests  of  the  state,  its  citizens  and  tax-­‐payers.  This  thesis  explores  ways  of  doing  that  by  making  banks  more  ‘ownerless’,  including  creating  any  National  Investment  Bank,  such  as  that  recently  proposed  by  the  Labour  Party,  as  a  truly  ‘ownerless’  institution.          

Page 7: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  7  

List  of  Charts  Chart  4.1:  Household  deposits  and  loans  in  %  of  GDP  (1964-­‐2009)……………….  59  Chart  4.2:  Business  deposits  and  loans  in  %  of  GDP  (1964-­‐2009)…………………   69  Chart  4.3:  UK  banks  lending  by  sector  in  £tr.  (1986-­‐2013)……………………………  64  Chart  5.1:  A  ‘research  onion’………………………………………………………………………..  92  Chart  6.1:  Lloyds:  returns  on  equity  in  %  (1988-­‐20013)……………………………….  96  Chart  6.2:  Barclays  and  Lloyds:  returns  on  equity  in  %  (1992-­‐2012)……………..  97  Chart  6.3:  Barclays  and  Lloyds:  return  on  assets  (RoA)  in  %  (1992-­‐2012)……..  98  Chart  6.4:  Barclays  and  Lloyds:  total  assets  in  £m  (1992-­‐2013)……………………..  99  Chart  6.5:  Barclays:  assets  by  business  in  £bn  (1993-­‐2012)…………………………  103  Chart  6.6:  Barclays:  profits  before  tax  by  business  in  £bn  (1993-­‐2012)………..  107  Chart  6.7:  Barclays  :  dividend  pay-­‐out  per  share  (2000  –  2017)……………………110  Chart  6.8:  Lloyds:  dividend  pay-­‐out  per  share  (2000  –  2017)……………………….112  Chart  6.9:  Lloyds  :  share  price  (2008-­‐2015)……………………………………………….    117  Chart  6.10:  Barclays:  equity  and  liabilities  (1993-­‐2012)……………………………..    119  Chart  7.1:  Barclays,  Lloyds,  Nationwide  and  Co-­‐op:  total  assets  in  £m  (2008-­‐2013)……………………………………………………………………………………………………….    133  Chart  7.2:  Lloyds  and  Nationwide:  total  assets  in  £m  (2008-­‐2013)……………..    134  Chart  7.3:  Nationwide  and  Co-­‐op:  total  assets  in  £m  (2008-­‐2013)……………….  134  Chart  7.4:  Nationwide’s  growth  trajectory  in  £m  (1991-­‐2013)…………………….  136  Chart  7.5:  Top  six  banks  provision  for  mis-­‐selling  by  category  (2010-­‐2014)...138                

Page 8: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  8  

 

List  of  Tables  Table  3.1:  Historical  Trends  in  Beneficial  Ownership  by  %  (snapshots  between  1963  and  2010)  ……………………………………………………………………………….………….  45  Table  5.1:  Table  of  data,  sources,  advantages  and  disadvantages…………………...    86  Table  5.2:  Saunder’s  ‘research  onion’……………………………………………………………..92  Table  6.1:  Lloyds:  assets  and  equity  in  £m  and  equity/  assets  in  %  (1988-­‐2013)………………………………………………………………………………………………………….101  Table  6.2:  Barclays:  assets  and  equity  in  £m  and  equity/assets  in  %  (1992-­‐2013)  ……………….………………………………………………………………………………………………….104  Table  6.3:  Barclays  book  value  (as  total  assets  less  total  liabilities)  and  market  capitalisation  (taking  average  of  final  month  each  year)  (2003-­‐2008)  …………..109  Table  6.4:  Lloyds  book  value  (as  total  assets  less  total  liabilities)  and  market  capitalisation  (taking  average  of  final  month  each  year)  (2003-­‐2009)………………………………………………………………………………………………………….113  Table  7.1:  Barclays,  Lloyds,  Nationwide  and  Co-­‐op:  total  assets  in  £m  (2008-­‐2013)...................................................................................................................................................127  Table  7.2:  Nationwide’s  total  assets  in  £m  (1990-­‐2014)…………………..……………135  Table  7.3:  complaints  upheld  (July-­‐December  2013)  ……………………………………138  Table  7.4:  Barclays,  Lloyds,  Nationwide  and  Co-­‐op:  %  of  assets  and  %  of  lending  composed  of  deposits  (2006-­‐2014)  ……………………………………………………………..139  Table  7.5:  Barclays,  Lloyds,  Nationwide  and  Co-­‐op  interbank  assets/interbank  lending  in  %  (2006-­‐2014)  …………………………………………………………………………..140  Table  7.6:  Nationwide:  amount  of  assets  comprised  of  mortgages  and  securities  in  %  (2009-­‐2014)………………………………………………………………………………………..141  Table  7.7:  Barclays:  amount  of  assets  comprised  of  mortgages  and  securities  (2009-­‐2013)  ………………………………………………………………………………………………142    Table  7.8:  Co-­‐op:  amount  of  assets  comprised  of  securities  in  £m  and  in  %  (2009-­‐2013)…………………………………………………………………………………………………………  142    

   

Page 9: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  9  

List  of  statutes      Acts  of  Parliament  in  England  and  Wales      The  Royal  Exchange  and  London  Assurance  Corporation  Act  1719………………..  42  The  Slavery  Abolition  Act  1822……………………………………………………………………  39  The  Competition  and  Credit  Control  Act  1971……………………………………………….61  The  Building  Society  Act  1986………………………………………………………140,  141,  148  The  Financial  Services  and  Markets  Act  2000………………………………………………  52  The  Companies  Act  2006……………………………………………………………………39,  51,  55  The  Financial  Services  (Banking  Reform)  Act  2013………………………………………  20  The  Co-­‐operative  and  Community  Benefit  Societies  Act  2014  ……………………….159    Foreign  statute  or  statutory  instruments    The  US  Foreign  Corrupt  Practices  Act  1977………………………………………………….118  The  EU  Directive  on  Takeovers  (2004/25/EC)……………………………………………   51  

   

Page 10: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  10  

   

 

Declaration  and  Copyright  Statement      

No  portion  of  the  work  referred  to  in  the  thesis  has  been  submitted  in  support  of  an  application  for  another  degree  or  qualification  of  this  or  any  other  university  or  other  institute  of  learning.      Note  on  copyright  and  the  ownership  of  intellectual  property  right:    The  author  of  this  thesis  (including  any  appendices  and/or  schedules  to  this  thesis)  owns  certain  copyright  or  related  rights  in  it  (the  ‘Copyright’)  and  has  given  The  University  of  Manchester  certain  rights  to  use  such  Copyright,  including  for  administrative  purposes.        Copies  of  this  thesis,  either  in  full  or  in  extracts  and  whether  in  hard  or  electronic  copy,  may  be  made  only  in  accordance  with  the  Copyright,  Designs  and  Patents  Act  1988  (as  amended)  and  regulations  issued  under  it  or,  where  appropriate,  in  accordance  with  licensing  agreements  which  the  University  has  from  time  to  time.  This  page  must  form  part  of  any  such  copies  made.        The  ownership  of  certain  Copyright,  patents,  designs,  trade  marks  and  other  intellectual  property  (the  ‘Intellectual  Property’)  and  any  reproductions  of  copyright  works  in  the  thesis,  for  example  graphs  and  tables  (‘Reproductions’),  which  may  be  described  in  this  thesis,  may  not  be  owned  by  the  author  and  may  be  owned  by  third  parties.  Such  Intellectual  Property  and  Reproductions  cannot  and  must  not  be  made  available  for  use  without  the  prior  written  permission  of  the  owner(s)  of  the  relevant  Intellectual  Property  and/or  Reproductions.        Further  information  on  the  conditions  under  which  disclosure,  publication  and  commercialisation  of  this  thesis,  the  Copyright  and  any  Intellectual  Property  and/or  Reproductions  described  in  it  may  take  place  is  available  in  the  University  IP  Policy  in  any  relevant  Thesis  restriction  declarations  deposited  in  the  University  Library,  The  University  Library’s  regulations  and  in  The  University’s  policy  on  presentation  of  Theses.    (See:http://www.campus.manchester.ac.uk/medialibrary/policies/intellectualproperty.pdf  and  http://www.manchester.ac.uk/library/aboutus/regulations)        

Page 11: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  11  

   

List  of  abbreviations      Barclays     Barclays  Bank  PLC  BBA       British  Bankers  Association  BoE       Bank  of  England    CEO       Chief  Executive  Officer    CMA     Competition  and  Markets  Authority    Co-­‐op     The  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC  Co-­‐op  Bank   The  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC  Co-­‐op  Group   The  Co-­‐operative  Group  CRESC     Centre  for  Research  on  Socio-­‐cultural  Change  EIB     European  Investment  Bank  FCA     Financial  Conduct  Authority    FSA     Financial  Services  Authority  GDP       Gross  Domestic  Product    GFC   Global  financial  crisis  ICB     Independent  Commission  on  Banking  ICFC     Industrial  and  Commercial  Financial  Corporation      IMF       International  Monetary  Fund    KfW     Kreditanstalt  für  Wiederaufbau    LIBOR       London  Interbank  Offered  Rate    Lloyds     Lloyds  Banking  Group  PLC,  or,  as  appropriate,  its  predecessor  

Lloyds  TSB  PLC,  or  indeed  its  predecessor,  Lloyds  Bank  Limited  M&A       Mergers  and  Acquisitions    Nationwide   The  Nationwide  Building  Society  PCBS       Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards    PLC     Public  Limited  Company  PPI       Payment  Protection  Insurance    PRA     Prudential  Regulation  Authority  RoA       Return  on  Assets    RoE     Return  on  equity    SME       Small  and  Medium-­‐sized  Enterprises    TBTF       Too  Big  to  Fail    TSC     Treasury  Select  Committee  UK       United  Kingdom  US       United  States    Vickers   The  Independent  Commission  on  Banking              

Page 12: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  12  

   

Chapter  1. Introduction    1.1   Introduction  

 This  chapter  introduces  the  inquiry  made  in  the  thesis,  explaining  briefly  why  that  inquiry  is  relevant  and  how  it  will  be  made.  It  is  broken  down  into  two  parts.  The  first  explores  some  of  the  main  literature  which  argues  that  the  way  banks  are  owned  affects  their  behaviour,  and  considers  why  that  topic  appears  relevant  for  any  discussion  about  banking  reform.  It  considers  what  inquiries  have  already  been  made  by  others  into  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour,  and  in  view  of  the  evidence  uncovered  by  such  inquiries,  it  explains  why  further  inquiry  is  still  required.  The  second  part  then  explains  how  that  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour  will  be  explored  and  provides  an  overview  of  the  thesis  outlining  a  brief  summary  of  each  of  the  chapters  to  follow.  

 

1.2   Part  1:  bank  ownership,  and  bank  behaviour    

How  banks  are  owned  and  organized  has  implications  for  how  they  behave  and  perform  (O’Hara,  1981;  Fama  et  al,  1983;  Rasmusen,  1988;  Bøhren  et  al  2013).  Shareholder-­‐owned  banks,  that  is  to  say  banks  whose  shares  are  publicly  traded,  tend  to  be  run  to  prioritise  the  maximisation  of  value  for  their  shareholders  (Haldane,  2011,  2015;  Mayer  2013,  pp111-­‐115,  144;  Black  et  al,  2015).  On  the  other  hand,  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks,  that  is  banks  which  are  either  mutually-­‐owned  by  their  customer-­‐members  or  owned  by  co-­‐operative  societies,  tend  to  return  value  to  a  wider  set  of  stakeholders  (Coco  et  al,  2010;  Ferri  et  al,  2010;  Bøhren  et  al,  2012,  2013).    Following  the  financial  services  reforms  in  the  1980s  which  came  to  be  known  as  the  ‘Big  Bang’,  it  was  routinely  claimed  in  the  UK  that  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  were  more  profitable  than  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  and  behaviourally  superior  (Cuevas  et  al,  2006).  Many  argued  that  the  latter  were  less  competitive  than  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  and  that  they  only  existed  due  to  protectionist  regimes  (O’Hara,  1981).    

The  events  following  on  from  the  global  financial  crisis  (‘GFC’)  which  began  in  2007  and  the  subsequent  banking  crisis  in  the  UK  have  provided  ample  evidence  to  undermine  these  pro-­‐shareholder  and  anti-­‐stakeholder  claims.  Following  the  failure  of  many  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  and  the  multiple  banking  scandals  and  behavioural  problems  which  subsequently  came  to  light,  there  has  been  an  increasing  willingness  to  critically  question  whether  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  are  fit-­‐for-­‐purpose  and  whether  they  perform  and  behave  better  than  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks.  It  is  commonly  observed  that  shareholders  tend  to  be  principally  concerned  with  capturing  and  extracting  value  through  the  buying  and  selling  of  shares,  and  consequently  that  they  care  more  about  making  short-­‐term  gains  from  trading  than  they  do  about  taking  a  

Page 13: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  13  

long  term  interest  in  and  governing  the  businesses  which  they  notionally  own  (Kay,  2012,  ch.1;  Haldane,  2011,  2015;  Ertürk,  2015).      

An  array  of  academics  and  policy-­‐makers,  including  some  mainstream  and  influential  officials  and  not  least  the  Bank  of  England’s  Chief  Economist  Andy  Haldane,  have  argued  that  the  way  that  main  banks  in  the  UK  are  owned  gives  them  powerful  incentives  to  take  excessive  short  term  risks  to  the  detriment  of  other  stakeholders,  such  as  employees,  investors,  tax  payers,  and  society  in  general  (Mayer,  2013;  Haldane,  2015;  Black  2015).  Shareholder-­‐owned  banks  have  not  only  been  criticized  for  driving  risky  strategy  and  behaviour,  but  also  for  negatively  affecting  the  role  banks  play  in  creating  and  allocating  credit  (Haldane,  2015;  Turner,  2016,  pp109,  172-­‐174).  Haldane  (2015)  for  example  suggests  that  the  net  effect  of  having  banks  run  for  their  shareholders  is  that  ultimately  banks  finance  the  stock  market  rather  than  the  stock-­‐market  financing  banking.  Haldane  (2015)  observes  a  series  of  macro-­‐economic  trends  which  tend  to  indicate  that  the  stock-­‐market  is  a  net  drain  on  bank  assets,  rather  than  a  net  contributor  :  instead  of  issuing  new  equity,  banks  tend  to  buy  back  more  and  more  of  their  shares;  and  shareholders  extract  apparently  increasing  dividends  from  banks  regardless  of  their  performance;  whilst  at  the  same  time  productivity  growth  is  declining,  and  investment  into  R  &  D  is  declining.    

It  has  also  been  increasingly  argued  that  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  are  better  behaved  than  shareholder-­‐owned  banks.    Not  being  expected  to  return  value  to  their  shareholders,  it  is  commonly  claimed  that  they  have  less  incentive  to  take  excessive  risks  and  to  adopt  unsustainable  business  strategies  and  to  exploit  rather  than  fostering  good  relationships  with  their  customers  (Allen  et  al.  1997,  2000,  2004,  2009;  Coco  et  al,  2010;  Ferri  et  al,  2010,  2012;  Amess,  2002;  Hakenes  et  al  2009).  Comparing  return  on  assets,  cost  efficiency  and  their  loan  quality  across  300  European  banks,  Ferri  et  al  (2010,  2012)  found  that  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  performed  more  efficiently  in  terms  of  loan  losses  and  cost  efficiency  than  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  and  that  there  was  no  compelling  evidence  to  suggest  that  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  behave  better  than  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks.  Their  evidence  suggested  that  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  behaved  more  prudently  and  more  sustainably  than  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  across  the  economic  cycle  both  before  the  crisis,  and  afterwards.    

There  is  also  another  type  of  ownership  model  which  cannot  accurately  be  described  as  a  stakeholder-­‐owned  organisation  because  it  is  not  ‘owned’  by  its  members,  or  in  more  accurate  terms  it  does  not  have  any  residual  claimants  to  whom  it  distributes  its  proceeds,  but  instead  retains  its  earnings  to  meet  its  social  aims.  This  model  of  organisation,  which  is  sometimes  referred  to  as  a  ‘social  purpose  not-­‐for-­‐profit’,  rather  than  a  ‘member-­‐owned  not-­‐for-­‐profit’,  is  not  without  precedent  in  the  world  of  banking.    Distinguishing  this  model  from  stakeholder-­‐owned  models,  Bøhren  et  al  (2012,  2013)  called  this  type  of  bank  ‘ownerless’  and  identified  two  examples:  the  Spanish  Cajas,  and  the  Norwegian  Sparkassen.  In  both  cases,  the  banks  are  neither  shareholder-­‐owned,  nor  owned  by  other  stakeholders,  but  have  governance  regimes  which  require  them  to  retain  their  proceeds  rather  than  distribute  them  directly  or  indirectly  to  members  and  to  apply  such  proceeds  to  meet  their  socially-­‐oriented  banking  goals  (in  relation  to  the  Spanish  Cajas,  see  also  Crespì  et  al  2004).    As  Bøhren  et  al  (2012,  2013)  observed  this  ownerless  model  has  particularly  interesting  and  positive  implications  for  banking  because  it  appears  to  be  apt  to  do  well  in  

Page 14: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  14  

sectors  where  there  are  high  informational  asymmetries  and  customers  are  vulnerable  or  liable  to  be  exploited  by  organisations  which  would  otherwise  be  run  to  extract  or  return  profits  for  their  owners  (Hansmann,  1980,  1981,  1988).  Hansmann  claimed  that  organizations  which  were  not  ‘owned’  and  which  were  not  run  to  extract  their  profits  for  the  benefit  of  outsiders  but  which  recycled  such  proceeds  by  continually  applying  and  re-­‐applying  them  to  meet  their  aims,  behaved  more  responsibly  than  organizations  which  in  the  pursuit  of  profits  for  their  owners  otherwise  had  incentives  to  compromise  their  behaviour  (Hansmann,  1980,  1981,  1988).  

As  for  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks,  there  was  also  evidence  to  suggest  that  such  ownerless  banks  also  perform  more  sustainably  and  behaved  more  responsibly  than  shareholder-­‐owned  banks.  Comparing  the  return  on  assets  employed  by  ownerless  and  shareholder-­‐owned  banks,  the  former  were  found  to  have  performed  and  behaved  better  (Crespí  et  al,  2004)  and  both  in  ‘crisis  times’  and  ‘normal  times’  (Bøhren  et  al,  2013).    Bøhren  et  al  (2013)  also  considered  the  disciplining  effect  of  competition  in  product  markets  and  concluded  that  shareholder-­‐ownership  only  really  presents  benefits  for  governance  in  inadequately  competitive  markets  and  where  stakeholder  governance  is  otherwise  inadequate  as  a  disciplining  force.    In  other  words,  it  was  suggested  that  in  competitive  markets,  shareholder-­‐ownership  does  not  present  any  benefits  in  terms  of  its  governance  model.  

These  various  claims  and  counter-­‐claims  are  far  from  settled  but  continue  to  be  argued  in  what  is  an  on-­‐going  corporate  governance  debate  between  shareholder  versus  stakeholder  advocates.  We  need  only  look  to  the  failure  of  the  Spanish  Cajas  or  the  failure  of  the  UK’s  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC  (‘Co-­‐op  Bank’)  to  find  some  prima  facie  evidence,  which  tends  to  undermine  those  who  advocate  universally  for  stakeholder-­‐ownership  or  ownerlessness.      Nevertheless,  in  the  wake  of  the  crisis,  there  is  now  what  can  fairly  be  described  as  some  very  serious  doubt  about  whether  the  shareholder-­‐ownership  model  is  fit-­‐for-­‐purpose.  On  the  micro  and  meso  levels,  there  are  concerns  about  whether  it  encourages  mis-­‐behaviour  and  unsafe  strategy  for  banks  (Bowman  et  al  2014;  Haldane,  2011,  2015;  Mayer,  2013),  and  on  the  macro  level  there  are  also  concerns  about  whether  it  encourages  harmful  and  unproductive  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  (Turner,  2016,  pp109,  172-­‐174).  There  is  also  a  growing  body  of  evidence  to  suggest  that  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  perform  and  behave  worse  than  stakeholder-­‐owned  or  ownerless  banks  across  the  economic  cycle  (Bøhren  et  al,  2013;  Ferri  et  al  2010,  2012;  Birchall,  2014).    

At  the  same  time,  it  is  increasingly  recognised  that  the  way  banks  are  owned  and  organized  is  not  an  inevitable  or  logically  necessary  arrangement,  but  a  political  and  economic  choice,  and  one  which  can  be  changed  (Ireland,  2011;  Haldane,  2015).  Banks,  after  all,  are  social  constructs,  and  the  form  they  take  is  ultimately  decided  upon  by  the  law-­‐makers  governing  the  societies  within  which  they  operate  (Haldane,  2015).  We  can  construct  and  regulate  banks  in  ways  which  ensure,  or  at  least  which  aim  to  ensure,  that  they  better  serve  society’s  interests  and  needs  (Haldane,  2015).  That  being  the  case,  following  the  crisis,  one  would  reasonably  expect  there  to  have  been  a  serious  debate  and  inquiry  into  whether  banks  can  and  should  be  owned  in  different  ways.    What  is  surprising  in  the  UK  is  that  whilst  the  debate  about  how  the  banking  sector  should  be  reformed  considered  corporate  governance  issues,  there  was  no  

Page 15: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  15  

official  inquiry  into  whether  banks  should  even  be  run  for  shareholders  in  the  first  place  –  notwithstanding  that  the  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  (PCBS)  called  for  an  inquiry  into  whether  banks  should  be  run  also  in  the  interest  of  others  and  not  just  for  shareholders  (PCBS,  2013b,  p.344,  see  also  annex  5  ‘bank  ownership’).    Even  amongst  academics,  that  issue  has  not  received  a  great  deal  of  attention.  Whilst  there  is  a  vast  body  of  literature  addressing  how  the  GFC  was  caused  and  making  proposals  for  tackling  such  causes,  there  has  been  far  less  critical  inquiry  into  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour.    Save  for  the  statistical  analyses  performed  by  Ferri  et  al  (2010)  and  Bøhren  (2013)  which  compares  bank  performance  across  sectors  and  countries,    there  appears  to  have  been  little  attempt  within  the  banking  reform  literature  to  compare  the  behaviour  of  shareholder-­‐owned  and  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks.    For  example  there  are  no  case  studies,  or  at  least  none  that  are  widely  published,  which  compare  different  ownership  models  and  contemplate  how  the  same  affects  bank  behaviour.  This  thesis  aims  to  fill  that  gap.  It  hopes  to  contribute  to  the  relatively  scarce  body  of  literature  that  explores  the  relationship  between  bank  behaviour  and  ownership.    

In  the  light  of  recent  banking  scandals  and  crises,  such  an  inquiry  appears  to  be  more  relevant  now  than  ever  before.  This  thesis  aims  to  explore  the  relationship  between  ‘ownership’  and  behaviour,  and  to  consider  whether  shareholder-­‐ownership  is  fit  for  purpose  or  whether  stakeholder-­‐ownership  or  ownerless  models  might  obtain  better  behaviours.  It  asks  how  the  way  banks  are  owned  affects  their  behaviour,  and  conversely  how  other  unrelated  pressures  arising  instead  out  of  the  market  and  regulatory  environments  within  which  banks  operate  also  affect  bank  behaviour.  It  refers  to  the  latter  as  ‘structural  pressures’  and  the  former  as  ‘ownership  pressures’,  and  considers  them  in  connection  with  differently  owned  banks.  It  both  explores  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour  and  then  considers  the  implications  for  banking  reform  and  how  we  should  go  about  thinking  about  ownership  and  how  we  design  or  might  re-­‐design  what  the  thesis  refers  to  as  the  ‘ownership  model’.    

1.3   Part  2:  How  to  explore  ownership  and  behaviour?    

This  thesis  tries  to  explore  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour  in  the  case  of  four  British  banking  institutions  (or  technically,  three  banks  and  one  building  society),  namely,  Barclays  Bank  PLC,  the  Lloyds  Banking  Group  PLC,  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC,  and  the  Nationwide  PLC.  The  thesis  thus  considers  two  ‘shareholder-­‐owned’  banks  and  looks  at  their  behaviour  and  it  considers  two  ‘stakeholder-­‐owned’  banks  and  considers  their  behaviour.  In  each  case,  it  considers  how  the  banks  behaved,  paying  special  attention  to  the  strategy  or  ‘business  model’  adopted  by  the  banks,  and  in  other  words  how  they  planned  their  business  to  generate  revenue  to  more  than  recover  their  operating  costs.  The  thesis  considers  how  behaviour  and  strategy  was  influenced  by  the  ownership  model  as  opposed  to  other  factors  arising  out  of  the  environment  within  which  each  bank  operated.    

By  adopting  a  case  study  methodology,  the  thesis  considers  the  phenomena  of  ‘ownership’  and  its  behavioural  implications  alongside  various  claims,  such  as  Hansmann’s  claim  (1980,  1981,  1988)  that  social  purpose  not-­‐

Page 16: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  16  

for-­‐profits  are  apt  to  behave  more  responsibly  and  claims  made  by  Kay  (2015,  pp248,  299)  and  Turner  (2016,  pp57-­‐60)  that  banks  have  departed  from  the  role  we  need  them  to  play  and  are  creating  and  allocating  credit  in  ways  we  need  to  reign  in.  By  exploring  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour  within  a  case  study  framework,  the  thesis  not  only  considers  such  behavioural  phenomena  within  the  context  within  which  they  arise,  but  allows  them  to  be  evaluated  in  the  light  of  broader  questions  and  claims  such  as  what  role  should  banks  be  expected  to  perform,  and  whether  the  shareholder-­‐ownership  model  is  fit  for  performing  such  roles.  The  thesis  thus  considers  how  the  ownership  model  influences  behaviour  both  in  real  terms,  according  to  existing  normative  standards,  and  in  putative  terms,  according  to  the  role  many  would  argue  banks  should  be  performing.  Conversely,  but  necessarily,  the  thesis  also  explores  how  other  pressures,  un-­‐related  to  how  banks  are  owned,  also  influence  behaviour.  It  identifies  how  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks,  such  as  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  are  subject  to  pressures  arising  out  of  the  structure  of  the  market  environment  they  operate  in  and  how  such  pressures  also  have  behavioural  implications.    

The  thesis  is  broken  up  into  8  chapters.    Chapters  2  to  4  review  the  relevant  literature  and  seek  to  frame  the  inquiry  into  how  ownership  affects  behaviour  within  the  context  of  the  current  reform  agenda  and  the  wider  debates  surrounding  ownership  and  what  we  want  from  the  banking  sector.    It  does  this  by  first  considering  how  the  banking  reform  debate  has  been  shaped  and  directed  in  a  way  which  has  avoided  any  attempt  to  challenge  the  ownership  paradigm  or  to  revisit  the  relationship  between  finance  sector,  market  and  state  which  was  brokered  in  the  Big  Bang.  Chapter  2  charts  the  ‘official  response’  to  the  crisis  and  how  the  same  has  failed  to  grapple  with  these  issues.  Chapter  3  goes  on  to  explore  ownership  within  the  broader  corporate  governance  literature  and  the  shareholder  versus  stakeholder  governance  debate.  This  chapter  describes  how  that  debate  has  evolved  over  the  centuries  to  reach  the  point  where  the  shareholder-­‐governance  paradigm  appears  conceivably  to  be  losing  its  grip  amidst  a  barrage  of  recent  criticism  and  accusations  that  it  is  liable  to  incentivize  unsafe  strategy,  and  mis-­‐behaviour.    

In  chapter  4,  the  thesis  considers  how  other  pressures  exerted  on  banks  through  the  structure  and  regulation  of  the  banking  market  also  drive  misbehaviour,  and  encourage  banks  to  create  and  allocate  credit  in  ways  which  are  unproductive  or  unsafe.  These  other  pressures  unrelated  to  ownership  are  referred  to  throughout  the  thesis  as  ‘structural  pressures’.  Chapter  4  considers  the  changes  brought  about  in  the  Big  Bang,  and  how  the  settlement  brokered  between  state,  market  and  financial  sector  caused  a  shift  in  the  role  performed  by  banks,  and  how  banks  have  coped  with  those  pressures.  In  particular,  it  considers  how  banks  are  encouraged  to  grow  to  be  as  big  as  they  can,  to  exploit  their  customer-­‐base  to  recover  heavy  operating  costs,  and  how  the  resulting  dynamics  have  put  pressures  on  smaller  banks  making  it  difficult  to  compete  without  also  engaging  in  similar  bad  behaviours  as  their  larger  peers.      

Chapter  5  then  describes  the  methodology,  clarifying  the  reasons  for  selecting  the  particular  banks  chosen  and  justifying  the  sources  of  data  consulted.  It  explains  that  Barclays,  Lloyds,  the  Co-­‐op  and  the  Nationwide  were  chosen  because  they  represent  a  range  of  different  ownership  models,  each  encountering  behavioural  problems  or  issues  which  were  remarkable  in  their  own  rights,  with  three  of  the  banks  exhibiting  behaviour  which  can  be  

Page 17: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  17  

characterised  as  ‘misbehaviour’  and  one  bank  mostly  avoiding  allegations  of  misbehaviour.  Chapter  6  then  explores  Barclays  and  Lloyds  and  ownership  pressures,  and  chapter  7  explores  the  Co-­‐op  and  Nationwide  and  structural  pressures.  

Chapter  8  then  attempts  to  draw  together  the  analysis  and  conclusions,  considering  what  lessons  should  be  learnt  from  the  case  studies  and  what  the  broader  implications  are  for  banking  reform  and  in  particular  for  how  we  should  approach  the  subject  of  ownership.  Whilst  recognising  that  an  ‘ownership  fix’  is  insufficient  to  resolve  all  of  the  problems  in  banking,  it  argues  that  reforming  ownership  is  necessary  to  tackle  the  underlying  causes  driving  much  of  the  misbehaviour  in  banking.    It  calls  for  more  functional  regulation  and  suggests  we  need  to  be  far  more  courageous  in  clarifying  what  we  expect  of  our  banks  and  we  need  to  be  both  more  interventionist  in  regulating  banks  to  perform  such  functions,  and  more  experimental  in  designing  new  forms  of  ownership  which  are  fit  for  performing  such  purposes.  Rather  than  prescribing  how  to  reform  ownership  it  then  sets  out  an  array  of  options  for  reducing  shareholder  primacy,  including  creating  the  newly  proposed  National  Investment  Bank  (the  Labour  Party,  2017)  within  an  ownerless  model.        

       

Page 18: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  18  

 

Chapter  2. The  banking  reform  agenda:  preserving  the  status  quo  

 2.1   Introduction      

‘The  laws  of  power  Law  31  Control  the  Options:  Get  Others  to  Play  with  the  Cards  you  Deal    The  best  deceptions  are  the  ones  that  seem  to  give  the  other  person  a  choice:  Your  victims  feel  they  are  in  control,  but  are  actually  your  puppets.  Give  people  options  that  come  out  in  your  favour  whichever  one  they  choose.  Force  them  to  make  choices  between  the  lesser  of  two  evils,  both  of  which  serve  your  purpose.  Put  them  on  the  horns  of  a  dilemma:  They  are  gored  wherever  they  turn.’  (Green,  1998,  p254)    ‘The  art  of  always  being  right:  thirty  eight  ways  to  win  when  you  are  defeated  18.  Interrupt,  break-­‐up,  divert  the  debate  If  you  observe  that  your  opponent  has  taken  a  line  of  argument  which  will  end  in  your  defeat  you  must  not  allow  him  to  take  it  to  its  conclusion,  but  interrupt  the  course  of  the  dispute  in  time  or  break  it  off  altogether  or  lead  him  away  from  the  subject,  and  bring  him  to  others.  In  short  you  must  effect  a  change  of  debate.’  (Schopenhauer,  2004,  p79  and  p95)  

 The  UK  banking  crisis,  which  began  in  2007,  was  part  of  what  was  widely  

viewed  as  the  worst  financial  crisis  since  the  1930s.  Some  of  Britain’s  biggest  banks  were  faced  with  insolvency  and  collapse,  which  in  turn  threatened  the  functioning  of  the  financial  sector  and  the  wider  economy.  It  called  for  immediate  and  radical  government  intervention  and  on  an  unprecedented  scale  to  ensure  that  banks  could  continue  to  provide  some  of  the  rather  basic  functions  required  of  them.  Several  mainstream  banks  and  building  societies  were  bailed  out  or  nationalised,  and  many  more  were  subsequently  propped  up  by  an  extensive  and  prolonged  programme  of  quantitative  easing  which  subsidised  bank  lending  with  taxpayer  funds.  After  a  crisis  of  such  magnitude,  the  UK  had  an  opportunity  to  think  about  what  went  wrong  with  banking,  how  it  could  be  fixed,  and  how  banks  might  be  reformed  and  made  fit  for  performing  the  purposes  we  require  of  them.    

Ordinarily,  one  would  have  expected  there  to  be  some  fairly  quick  mainstream  discussions  about  what  reforms  were  required  to  ensure  banks  never  again  hold  society  to  ransom  in  the  same  way.  One  might  have  expected  some  radical  proposals  to  have  been  adopted  by  government  seeking  to  break  up  the  biggest  banks,  and  create  an  overall  smaller  sector,  with  constraints  being  placed  on  the  identifiably  more  harmful  and  unsustainable  financial  activities.    Instead,  what  we  got  in  the  UK  was  a  rather  leisurely  drawn  out  reform  debate  which  spanned  several  years,  and  which  concluded  with  a  rather  modest  set  of  reforms  proposals  (Woolf,  2014a).      

Page 19: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  19  

The  ‘official  response’  to  the  crisis  –  that  is  to  say,  the  published  findings  and  proposals  of  parliamentary  and  government  bodies  and  the  various  watchdogs,  and  experts  commissioned  by  government  –  essentially  avoided  asking  the  big  questions  about  what  needed  to  be  done  to  fix  banks  and  make  them  more  fit  for  purpose.  Whilst  there  was  no  shortage  of  reports,  the  official  bodies  involved  in  preparing  and  publishing  such  reports  tended  to  focus  instead  on  answering  a  number  of  narrower  pre-­‐determined  issues,  generally  referred  to  them  by  government,  whose  own  reform  agenda  appeared  to  have  been  set  with  a  view  to  preserving  the  dominance  of  the  financial  sector  (CRESC,  2009,  pp11-­‐12;  PCBS,  2013b,  paras190,  237).    Following  the  first  signs  of  financial  crisis,  a  halo  was  quickly  constructed  around  the  City  as  the  government  quickly  commissioned  and  endorsed  the  findings  of  Sir  Win  Bischoff,  committing  itself  first  and  foremost  to  a  thriving  internationally  successful  City  (CRESC,  2009,  p18).      

As  we  shall  explore  in  this  chapter,  any  reforms  which  might  threaten  such  a  thriving  and  successful  City  were  soon  marginalised  in  the  reform  debate  by  the  ‘official  response’.  In  the  sense  referred  to  by  Schopenhauer  and  Greene  in  the  opening  quotations  at  the  head  of  this  chapter,  the  government  appeared  to  ‘divert  the  debate’  and  ‘control  the  options’,  setting  the  pace  and  agenda  for  discussion,  which  resulted  in  the  reform  debate  arriving  at  a  modest  set  of  reform  proposals.    Ultimately,  the  proposals  adopted  by  Government  did  not  seek  to  tackle  the  perverse  incentives  arising  from  the  way  banks  are  owned,  nor  did  they  seek,  at  least  on  the  national  scale  Basel  III  notwithstanding,  to  radically  change  the  wider  structural  setting  and  regulatory  environment  within  which  banks  operate  to  encourage  them  to  reduce  the  amount  of  unsustainable  and  risky  speculative  lending.    The  ownership  pressures  and  structural  pressures  which  this  thesis  is  concerned  with  were  largely  overlooked  by  the  official  response.    

The  purpose  of  this  chapter  is  to  consider  the  reports  and  inquiries  undertaken  in  response  to  the  crisis  in  order  to  look  at  how  the  ‘official  response’  to  the  crisis  dealt  with  the  issue  of  ownership.  This  chapter  considers  what  the  official  response  was,  what  issues  it  considered  and  why  that  response  failed  to  question  whether  banks  should  be  owned  in  different  ways.  In  explaining  how  the  official  response  failed  to  ask  the  big  questions  and  to  tackle  what  this  thesis  refers  to  as  ‘ownership  pressures’  and  ‘structural  pressures’  this  chapter  also  sets  the  scene  for  the  review  of  the  literature  into  ‘ownership  pressures’  in  chapter  3  and  ‘structural  pressures’  in  chapter  4.    

The  chapter  is  broken  down  into  two  parts.  The  first  and  biggest  part  follows  the  reform  debate  broadly  in  chronological  fashion.  It  deals  with  the  official  and  semi-­‐official  reports  and  inquiries  which  were  instigated  in  response  to  the  banking  crisis,  such  as  the  reports  produced  by  Bischoff,  Wigley,  Turner,  Walker  and  Vickers,  as  well  as  the  various  reports  by  the  Treasury  Select  Committee  within  its  ‘Banking  Crisis  Inquiry’.  It  also  considers  the  reports  produced  later  on  in  response  to  the  public’s  reaction  to  the  market-­‐rigging  scandals  which  emerged  in  2012,  chiefly  the  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  report  (2013a,  2013b)  and  later  the  Competition  and  Markets  Authority  (2016)  review  into  competition  in  the  retail  banking  sector.  It  describes  how  the  banking  reform  debate  was  influenced  and  even  steered  by  the  government,  and  how  the  government  itself  has  been  in  hock  to  financial  

Page 20: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  20  

interests,  seeking  to  preserve  light-­‐touch  regulation  and  a  thriving  City  by  setting  the  agenda  for  the  debate  and  defining  the  issues  for  determination.  It  describes  how  the  government  stage-­‐managed  the  debate  by  appealing  to  authority,  appointing  its  own  experts  to  make  proposals  on  a  predefined  set  of  issues,  which  inevitably  sought  to  preserve  shareholder-­‐value  banking  and  limited  regulation,  without  disturbing  the  dominance  of  the  big  banks,  or  breaking  up  universal  banking.    

The  second  part  of  the  chapter  then  discusses  what  was  overlooked  by  the  official  response,  namely  how  banks  are  owned  and  how  the  space  within  which  they  operate  should  be  regulated  to  ensure  they  meet  our  expectations  of  them.  Having  explained  how  and  why  these  issues  were  side-­‐lined  in  the  first  part  of  the  chapter,  there  is  an  analysis  of  how  such  ownership  and  structural  issues  have  been  raised  at  the  margins  of  the  debate  but  in  ways  which  have  failed  to  engage  political  imagination  and  enable  any  meaningful  challenge  to  the  status  quo,  resulting  in  the  banking  reform  debate  missing  an  historical  opportunity.        

2.2   Part  1:  The  ‘official  response’      

2.2.1   Controlling  the  debate    On  5  March  2015,  the  Government  announced  that  the  ‘banking  reform  

agenda’  had  been  completed  (H.  M.  Treasury,  2015).  It  announced  that  the  implementation  of  the  Financial  Services  (Banking  Reform)  Act  2013  represented  ‘the  final  piece  of  the  biggest  reforms…’  which,  according  to  Andrea  Leadsom  then  the  City  Minister  ‘mark[ed]  the  end  of  a  five  year  process,  led  by  the  government,  to  make  the  UK  banking  system  stronger  and  safer.’  (H.  M.  Treasury,  2015).  The  Government’s  banking  reform  agenda  essentially  incorporated  some  of  the  proposals  made  by  the  Independent  Commission  on  Banking  chaired  by  Sir  John  Vickers,  as  well  as  some  of  the  recommendations  of  the  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards.  The  Government’s  reform  package  comprised  a  set  of  measures:  re-­‐empowering  the  Bank  of  England  as  bank  supervisor  responsible  for  identifying  and  mitigating  systemic  risks;  obliging  banks  to  ring-­‐fence  the  more  publicly-­‐sensitive  parts  of  their  business  to  protect  them  in  the  event  of  bank  failure;  encouraging  competition  by  stream-­‐lining  account  switching  services;  tightening  up  the  approval  regime  for  the  appointment  of  senior  bankers  and  introducing  a  series  of  criminal  offences  to  penalize  ‘reckless  misconduct’  in  an  effort  to  improve  banking  ‘culture’.  As  far  as  the  government  was  concerned,  the  banking  reform  which  they  boasted  was  ‘led  by  the  government’  had  officially  concluded  in  2015,  culminating  in  the  2013  Act  coming  into  force.    

That  2013  Act  was  the  culmination  of  ‘the  official  response’.  It  formally  put  into  effect  those  proposals  which  were  accepted  by  government  and  put  before  Parliament  which  themselves  were  made  at  the  conclusion  of  various  inquiries  and  reports  undertaken  by  those  state  agencies  or  appointees  commissioned  by  the  government  following  the  banking  crisis  in  2008.  The  ‘official  response’  to  the  crisis  did  not  hold  a  comprehensive  inquiry  investigating  the  types  of  questions  

Page 21: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  21  

one  would  expect  to  be  asked  in  the  wake  of  the  banking  crisis  such  as  what  went  wrong  with  banking,  what  do  we  want  banks  to  do  and  what  reforms  are  needed  to  achieve  the  type  of  sector  we  want  and  to  avoid  banks  failing  again.    

Instead,  as  we  shall  see,  the  official  response  essentially  delegated  the  task  of  policy  formulation  and  inquiry  to  a  number  of  agencies  and  experts  supposedly  independent  of  government  with  an  emphasis  on  their  familiarity  with  and  experience  of  the  financial  industry.  This  process,  which  we  shall  explore  more  fully  below  in  this  part,  began  in  2008  when  the  crisis  became  apparent  and  lasted  for  years,  until  2016  when  the  Competition  and  Markets  Authority  concluded  its  review.  In  2008,  the  government  asked  a  City  grandee,  the  former  Chairman  of  Citigroup,  Sir  Win  Bischoff  essentially  whether  he  thought  it  was  important  for  policy-­‐makers  to  protect  the  competitiveness  of  the  City.  Shortly  afterwards  in  2009,  the  Mayor  of  London  asked  another  City  man  Wigley  essentially  the  same  question.  The  Government  then  went  on  to  ask  the  head  of  the  FSA,  an  institution  which  itself  had  been  implicated  in  regulatory  failure  (Treasury  Committee,  2009e,  pp3,  13),  to  inquire  into  what  caused  the  crisis  with  a  view  to  considering  how  regulation  should  be  reformed.    It  asked  another  City  heavyweight,  Sir  David  Walker  to  look  into  corporate  governance  in  banking  and  what  reforms  were  needed.  As  well  as  the  various  inquiries  performed  by  the  Banking  Crisis  Inquiry  by  Parliament’s  select  committee,  Parliament  asked  a  number  of  City  figures,  led  by  Sir  John  Vickers,  to  make  reform  proposals  for  the  banking  sector  generally.          

2.2.2     Sir  ‘Win’  Bischoff  and  Bob  Wigley  –  pledging  allegiance  to  the  City      

In  July  2008,  at  a  stage  when  it  was  becoming  apparent  that  the  UK  was  entering  into  a  financial  crisis,  H.  M.  Treasury  asked  the  former  Chairman  of  Citigroup,  Sir  Win  Bischoff  whether  he  thought  it  was  important  for  policy-­‐makers  to  protect  the  competitiveness  of  the  City.  Specifically,  this  enquiry  was  asked  :    

‘to  examine  medium  to  long  term  challenges  to  London’s  continued  competitiveness  in  international  financial  markets  and  to  develop  a  framework  on  which  to  base  policy  and  initiatives  to  keep  UK  financial  services  competitive  over  the  next  10  to  15  years’    (H.M.Treasury,  2009).      

 Around  the  same  time,  the  Mayor  of  the  City  of  London,  Boris  Johnson,  asked  another  City  man  what  needed  to  be  done  to  preserve  the  City’s  competitiveness.  Bob  Wigley,  European  chair  of  Merrill  Lynch  was  asked  to  undertake  a  ‘review  of  the  competitiveness  of  London’s  financial  centre’  (Wigley,  2008,  p6).  These  reviews  were  asked  to  consider  how  to  preserve  a  prominent  and  thriving  City,  rather  than  to  make  a  broader  inquiry  into  what  sort  of  financial  sector  the  UK  needed.  Unsurprisingly,  both  Bischoff  and  Wigley  produced  reports  boasting  the  importance  of  the  City  for  Britain’s  national  economy  which  suggested  that  policy-­‐makers  should  be  careful  not  to  prejudice  its  competitive  position.    Bob  Wigley’s  report,  ‘London:  winning  in  a  changing  world:  review  of  the  competitiveness  of  London’s  financial  centre’,  published  in  December  2008,  stressed  the  need  for  London  to  compete  as  the  global  financial  centre,  boasting  the  benefits  of  its  regulatory  regime  and  cautioning  against  excessive  regulation  (Wigley,  2008,  pp17,  41).    

Page 22: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  22  

The  Bischoff  report  ‘UK  international  financial  services  –  the  future’  was  published  in  April  2009.  Advocating  for  the  promotion  of  the  City  and  a  balanced  approach  to  regulation  it  dismissed  the  need  to  create  narrow  banks  and  rejected  outright  the  notion  of  completely  separating  retail  and  investment  banking  (Bischoff,  2009,  p2).  Any  reforms,  it  suggested  would  have  to  minimally  disrupt  the  City’s  freedom  to  compete  with  other  global  financial  centres  to  be  a  hot-­‐bed  for  global  capital  and  should  have  a  view  to  preserving  and  promoting  the  City’s  success  as  a  global  financial  centre  (Bischoff,  2009,  pp38-­‐39).    It  rejected  the  idea  of  breaking  up  universal  banks  and  big  banks  (Bischoff,  2009,  pp2,  21),  and  instead  advocated  for  macro-­‐prudential  regulation,  regulating  capital  ratios  to  manage  growth  and  encourage  banks  to  lend  more  during  downturns  and  less  during  economic  booms  (Bischoff,  2009,  p2)  and  it  called  for  periodic  reviews  of  regulation,  and  cooperating  internationally  with  others  rather  than  radical  regulatory  change  (Bischoff,  2009,  p39).    

The  apparent  aim  of  the  policy  being  advocated  for  was  not  to  inquire  into  what  caused  the  banking  crisis  and  needed  to  be  done  to  avoid  it,  or  to  ask  more  generally  what  we  want  from  the  sector  but  rather  to  preserve  the  City’s  role  as  a  global  financial  centre.  Bischoff  and  Wigley  epitomise  a  form  of  regulatory  capture  with  the  official  response  buying  into  a  narrative  which  was  lobbied  for  by  the  financial  sector  (CRESC,  2009,  p11).  Without  even  questioning  what  the  financial  sector  cost  society,  Bischoff  accepted  that  the  City  was  a  large  net  contributor  to  gross  domestic  produce  (‘GDP’)  and  good  for  the  economy  (CRESC,  2009,  p24).  The  report  was  keen  to  recognise  that  banks  were  an  important  part  of  the  UK  economy  and  very  quick  to  suggest  that  they  should  not  be  treated  as  any  special  case  but  rather  approached  like  any  other  industry  driven  by  commercial  interests  (Bischoff,  2009,  p23).  Bischoff  advocated  in  favour  of  such  laissez  faire  approach  without  identifying  that  banks  perform  vitally  important  public  functions  essential  for  the  running  of  the  economy,  and  without  observing  that  their  shareholders  tend  to  contribute  only  a  tiny  fraction  of  their  overall  assets.    

Before  inquiring  into  what  went  wrong  with  banks  and  how  they  needed  to  be  reformed,  the  policy  line  adopted  by  the  elite  position  was  that  regulatory  reforms  had  to  be  limited  to  preserving  London’s  competitiveness.  Indeed,  any  attempt  to  undertake  an  official  inquiry  into  the  causes  of  the  crisis  came  after  Alistair  Darling  publicly  pledged  allegiance  to  a  thriving  City.  Any  doubt  about  whether  the  government  supported  such  policy  aims  were  immediately  dispelled  before  the  banking  reform  debate  even  got  started  upon  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  Alistair  Darling,  signing  up  to  Bischoff  proposals,  and  co-­‐authoring  the  report  (Bischoff,  2009,  p2).  The  Government’s  banking  reform  agenda  and  policy  priorities  were  thus  set,  or  confirmed,  by  a  City  appointee,  who  whilst  independent  of  government,  had  very  close  connections  with  a  City  bank  who  had  obvious  interests  in  preserving  what  Bischoff  described  as  internationally  ‘competitive  regulation’  (Bischoff,  2009,  p37).      

2.2.3   Lord  Turner  –  preserving  light  touch  regulation      

Having  already  appointed  Bischoff,  in  October  2008,  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  Alistair  Darling  then  asked  Lord  Turner,  who  was  at  the  time  still  

Page 23: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  23  

director  of  the  FSA,  to  consider  what  regulatory  changes  were  needed,  and  specifically:  ‘to  review  the  causes  of  the  current  crisis,  and  to  make  recommendations  on  the  changes  in  regulation  and  supervisory  approach  needed  to  create  a  more  robust  banking  system  for  the  future’(p5,  Turner  2009).  The  choice  of  the  FSA  as  agent  to  review  the  adequacy  of  regulation  and  make  proposals  for  reform  was  rather  peculiar,  given  that  the  FSA  had  been  roundly  criticised  for  failing  to  do  its  job  properly  and  adequately  regulate  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c,  para.63)  and  therefore  arguably  had  the  least  incentive  to  find  regulatory  failure,  or  to  propose  any  radical  change  in  regulation.  Before  the  government  had  debated  or  proposed  how  to  reform  the  banking  sector  Turner  was  asked  to  make  proposals  for  reforming  the  way  the  sector  was  regulated  and  he  was  asked  to  do  so  without  being  asked  to  consider  what  type  of  banking  sector  the  country  needed  or  wanted.  His  remit  tacitly  assumed  that  we  would  continue  to  have  the  same  type  of  sector  as  indeed  Bischoff  and  Wigley  had  already  argued  for,  and  the  government  had  apparently  committed  itself  to.  Turner  was  specifically  asked  to  make  proposals  to  enhance  the  ‘robustness’  of  the  sector,  and  not  to  consider  how  banking  crises  might  be  avoided  altogether  in  the  future.    

 Unsurprisingly,  the  Turner  Review,  ‘A  regulatory  response  to  the  global  banking  crisis’  did  not  pin  blame  for  the  banking  crisis  at  the  door  of  the  FSA.  The  Turner  Review  was  not  heavily  critical  of  the  regulatory  regime  but  instead  presented  the  crisis  as  an  inevitable  and  unavoidable  systems  failure:  an  unfortunate  combination  of  complex,  but  unpredictable  macro-­‐economic  forces  playing  out  within  a  regulatory  climate  which  had  become  permissive  in  reliance  on  mathematical  models  (Turner,  2009,  pp11-­‐22).  This  explanation  criticised  excessive  faith  being  placed  on  mathematical  models,  but  in  marked  contrast  with  his  later  2016  analysis  of  the  crisis  (Turner,  2016),  Turner  was  not  scathing  of  the  entire  light-­‐touch  approach  of  regulators.  The  cause  of  the  crisis,  Turner  argued  in  his  review,  was  the  macro-­‐economic  imbalance  caused  by  the  Eurasian  savings  glut  seeking  yield  in  a  highly  innovative  and  permissible  regulatory  environment  where  trade  in  complicated  financial  instruments  was  rife,  and  able  to  cause  a  critical  accumulation,  and  occlusion,  of  risk  (Turner,  2009,  pp11-­‐22).  This  narrative  ‘macro  trends  meeting  financial  innovation’  (Turner,  2009,  p11)  had  few  guilty  parties  deserving  punishment,  and  no  identifiably  singular  flawed  part  of  the  system  which  could  be  readily  fixed.  Turner  instead  proposed  an  array  of  measures.  He  got  behind  the  proposal  for  greater  macro-­‐prudential  regulation  already  suggested  by  Bischoff  (Bischoff,  2009,  p2),  and  canvassed  the  possibility  of  regulating  financial  products,  warning  of  the  need  to  more  carefully  police  shadow  banking  and  cross  boarder  activities  (Turner,  2009,  pp7-­‐9).    He  proposed  greater  capital  buffers,  closer  supervision  of  credit  rating  agencies,  and  reform  of  director  remuneration  structures,  as  well  as  a  more  pro-­‐active  counter-­‐cyclical  role  for  regulation  (Turner,  2009,  pp7-­‐9).      

2.2.4   The  Banking  Crisis  Inquiry  –  the  wrong  body      The  Banking  Crisis  Inquiry  (BCI)  was  not  an  independent  commission  set  

up  by  Parliament  to  inquire  into  what  caused  the  banking  crisis  and  how  to  avoid  it,  and  consequently  it  did  not  produce  a  comprehensive  single  report  on  that  

Page 24: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  24  

subject.    Rather  the  BCI  was  performed  by  the  Treasury  Committee  (TC),  which  is  one  of  the  House  of  Commons  select  committees  which  had  been  set  up  by  the  House  of  Commons  with  the  express  purpose  of  examining  ‘the  expenditure,  administration  and  policy  of  HM  Treasury,  HM  Revenue  &  Customs,  and  associated  public  bodies,  including  the  Bank  of  England  and  the  Financial  Conduct  Authority’  (House  of  Commons,  2002).  

 Rather  than  being  tasked  with  performing  a  singular  comprehensive  inquiry,  it  was  free  to  choose  its  own  subjects  of  inquiry,  as  relevant  to  examining  the  expenditure  of  the  Treasury  and  associated  bodies.  On  25  November  2008,  the  Treasury  Committee  announced  its  intention  to  launch  a  Banking  Crisis  Inquiry,  its  own  terms  of  reference  being  to  identify  lessons  that  can  be  learnt  from  the  crisis,  specifically  with  a  view  to  ‘securing  financial  stability,  protecting  the  tax  payer,  protecting  consumers,  and  protecting  shareholder  interests’  (Treasury  Committee,  2008a)      The  Treasury  Committee  held  a  series  of  public  hearings  predominantly  in  2009,  in  which  it  heard  evidence  from  a  number  of  different  stakeholders,  and  it  consequently  produced  a  number  of  reports.  The  first  report  ‘Banking  crisis:  the  impact  and  failure  of  Icelandic  banks’  published  on  4  April  2009  dealt  with  problems  emerging  from  the  Icelandic  banking  sector  (Treasury  Committee,  2009a).  The  second  published  on  1  May  2009,  dealt  with  ‘The  failure  of  the  UK  banks’  (Treasury  Committee,  2009b).    The  third,  published  on  15  May  2009  considered  ‘Reforming  corporate  governance  and  pay  in  the  City’  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c).  The  fourth,  published  on  24  July  2009  considered  ‘The  international  dimension’  (Treasury  Committee,  2009d).  And  the  fifth  report,  published  on  31  July  2009  considered  more  generally  ‘Regulation  and  supervision’  (Treasury  Committee,  2009e).    

The  House  of  Commons  Treasury  Committee  also  undertook  various  other  inquires  related  to  banking  reform  outside  of  its  Banking  Crisis  Inquiry,  including  its  report  into  ‘The  Run  on  the  Rock’  published  on  26  January  2008  (Treasury  Committee,  2008b),  its  report  into  moral  hazard:  ‘Too  important  to  fail–too  important  to  ignore’  which  was  published  on  22  March  2010  (Treasury  Committee,  2010),  its  report  on  ‘Competition  and  choice  in  retail  banking’  which  was  published  on  24  March  2011  (Treasury  Committee,  2011a)  and  its  report  into  ‘The  Financial  Conduct  Authority’  (Treasury  Committee,  2012a).      

The  proposals  of  the  Treasury  Committee,  which  were  spread  across  the  various  reports,  are  constrained  by  the  practice  of  making  recommendations  by  unanimity.  Whilst  able  to  vent  criticism  and  question  witnesses,  the  proposals  were  less  radical  than  its  inquiry  and  criticisms.  In  its  second  report,  ‘dealing  with  the  banks  in  the  UK’,  for  example,  the  committee  heavily  criticized  the  FSA,  the  Bank  of  England,  and  indeed  the  government  itself  for  spreading  the  illusion  that  banking  growth  and  profitability  was  sustainable  in  the  long  or  medium  term  and  also  for  permitting  the  culture  of  ‘easy  rewards’  for  risky  behaviour  (Treasury  Committee,  2009b,  para.17),  but  it  did  not  go  on  to  make  a  set  of  clear  and  radical  proposals  for  reforming  the  culture  of  light  touch  regulation.  In  the  same  report,  the  Committee  rejected  the  suggestion  that  bankers  were  merely  innocent  victims  of  unfortunate  external  circumstance  and  it  explicitly  rejected  the  apologies  given  by  senior  bankers  during  some  of  the  hearings  in  2009  as  being  too  insincere  and  even  rehearsed,  (Treasury  Committee,  2009b,  paras.132-­‐134).  Yet  whilst  unaccepting  of  apologetic  bankers,  its  proposals  for  reform  fell  

Page 25: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  25  

short  of  those  later  proposed  by  the  PCBS  which  for  example  recommended  the  introduction  of  new  criminal  offence,  and  overhauling  the  approved  person  regime  (2013a,  ‘summary  of  recommendations’).  Its  analysis  was  also  obscured  by  being  spread  over  a  large  variety  of  reports  looking  into  multiple  diverse  issues.  Instead  of  producing  a  singular,  definitive  report  on  the  causes  of  the  banking  crises  and  the  implications  for  reform,  there  was  a  proliferation  of  analysis  across  many  different  reports  which  watered  down  what  might  otherwise  have  been  a  more  cogent  compelling  set  of  proposals.        

Whilst  considering  that  there  were  corporate  governance  failures  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c)  the  Treasury  Committee  did  not  question  whether  banks  should  be  run  for  shareholder  value.  In  its  third  report  in  2009,  on  corporate  governance,  it  did  not  explore  how  far  shareholder  value  banking  contributed  to  the  crisis,  but  proceeded  on  the  assumption  that  there  had  been  some  form  of  corporate  governance  failure,  involving  a  failure  of  shareholder  oversight  which  called  for  reform  of  the  corporate  governance  regime  to  encourage  further  shareholder  activism  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c,  para.176).  It  sought  to  narrow  what  it  presumed  to  be  an  agency  gap,  without  questioning  whether  such  agency  should  exist  and  in  other  words  whether  banks  will  behave  if  run  primarily  for  their  shareholders.  

Although  it  had  identified,  in  its  second  report  on  the  failure  of  UK  banks,  that  building  societies  tended  to  be  inherently  less  risky  business  models  than  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  (Treasury  Committee,  2009b,  para63),  it  did  not  go  on  to  question  either  in  that  report  or  in  its  report  on  corporate  governance  what  the  relevance  of  the  shareholder-­‐ownership  model  was  to  the  risks  banks  took  upon  themselves.  In  its  report  on  corporate  governance,  the  Treasury  Committee  appeared  to  accept  that  shareholders  tended  to  vote  with  their  feet,  rather  than  take  an  active  interest  in  governance  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c,  paras.75  and  176),  yet  it  nevertheless  it  proposed  more  of  the  same  corporate  governance  regime  rather  than  challenging  whether  shareholder  supervision  could  ever  be  adequate.    In  that  report  the  Treasury  Committee  accepted  that  shareholder-­‐value  banking  tended  to  encourage  leverage,  short  termism  and  excessive  risk  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c,  para.167)  but  it  did  not  question  whether  banks  should  be  run  for  shareholder  value.  The  committee  argued  more  had  to  be  done  to  enhance  shareholder  activism  and  indeed,  it  called  for  Sir  David  Walker  to    look  into  how  that  could  be  done  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c,  paras.75  and  176).      

2.2.5   Sir  David  Walker  –  protecting  shareholder-­‐ownership      

In  February  2009,  three  months  after  Turner  was  asked  to  report  on  the  cause  of  the  crisis,  the  Prime  Minister,  Gordon  Brown,  then  asked  another  City  grandee  to  look  into  problems  with  corporate  governance  in  banking.  Just  after  receiving  the  Wigley  report,  Sir  David  Walker  –  a  man  known  to  have  close  connections  with  a  number  of  big  City  financial  institutions,  and  significant  professional  and  financial  interests  (Treasury  Committee,  2009c,  para.161)  –  was  asked  to  consider  the  subject  of  corporate  governance  in  banks  and  to  make  proposals  for  reform  (Walker,  2009  pp5,  6,  127).    The  reasons  for  Walker’s  selection  were  not  published.  His  explicit  terms  of  reference  were  which  were  

Page 26: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  26  

made  public  are  noticeably  limited.  Sir  David  was  not  asked  to  consider  the  causes  of  corporate  governance  failure  and  bank  failure  in  general  or  to  make  proposals  to  prevent  the  same.  He  was  not  asked  to  consider  whether  the  ‘ownership  model’  was  unfit  or  another  model  could  be  more  fit  for  purpose  nor  to  consider  what  the  effects  of  banks  being  shareholder-­‐owned  had,  and  how  to  address  them.    

Instead  the  Prime  Minister  asked  Walker  specifically  to  propose  measures  to  encourage  ‘greater  shareholder  activism’  (Walker,  2009,  p5).  And  he  was  engaged  on  the  assumptions  which  he  explicitly  recorded  in  his  report  that  banks  would  continue  to  engage  in  speculative  activities  and  continue  to  provide  both  retail  banking  services  as  well  as  engaging  in  wholesale  and  investment  banking  (‘IB’)  activities  (Walker,  2009,  pp25-­‐27).  He  was  further  clear  that  he  only  intended  to  propose  more  soft  law  reforms  which  did  not  require  any  primary  legislation  or  radical  change  in  the  law.  As  he  clarified  in  his  report,  he  considered  proposals  on  the  basis  of  adding  further  to  the  ‘comply  and  explain’  regime  of  the  Combined  Code,  which  companies  voluntarily  adhere  to.  And  he  was  specifically  asked  to  make  his  proposals  on  the  basis  that  they  would  not  risk  putting  UK  banks  at  a  competitive  disadvantage  vis-­‐a-­‐vis  their  non-­‐UK  domiciled  competitors  (Walker,  2009,  pp27,  31).    Any  discussion  about  whether  shareholder-­‐ownership  itself  provided  problematic  incentives  which  needed  to  be  addressed,  or  on  how  to  address  such  incentives,  was  implicitly  off-­‐limits.  

Rather  predictably  therefore,  Sir  David  Walker’s  report,  ‘A  review  of  corporate  governance  in  UK  banks  and  other  financial  industry  intermediaries’  published  on  26  November  2009,  both  blamed  inadequate  corporate  governance  arrangements  for  failing  to  prevent  excessive  risk-­‐taking,  whilst  proposing  more  of  the  same  type  of  corporate  governance  arrangements  which  he  had  found  failing,  and  it  did  so  without  questioning  whether  shareholder  value  banking  encouraged  risk  or  whether  shareholder  supervision  could  ever  adequately  guard  against  excessive  risk  (Walker,  2009).  Like  Bischoff  before  him  (Bischoff,  2009,  p23),  he  treated  banks  like  any  other  economic  venture  run  for  commercial  interests.  Even  though  bank  capital,  unlike  the  capital  of  companies  operating  in  other  sectors,  tends  to  be  composed  of  only  a  tiny  proportion  of  shareholder  capital,  Walker  did  not  differentiation  between  the  ownership  of  banks  and  the  ownership  of  any  other  company.  He  did  not  distinguish  banking  from  other  sectors  of  activity  by  recognising  the  extent  to  which  banks  handle  other  people’s  money  nor  did  he  consider  the  important  socially  valuable  functions  banks  perform.      Unlike  John  Kay  after  him,  who  we  shall  consider  next,  Walker  did  not  consider  how  shareholder  value  banking  caused  incentivised  for  senior  management  to  take  risks.  

Instead  Walker  proposed  some  modest  soft  law  improvements  for  the  corporate  governance  regime  applicable  to  banks.  He  proposed  tighter  controls  over  risk  and  pay  by  non-­‐executive  directors  (NEDs),  the  introduction  of  risk  committees  and  risk  officers  to  scrutinise  big  transactions,  the  adoption  of  a  stewardship  code  to  encourage  greater  activism  by  institutional  investors,  greater  disclosure  on  pay  (for  employees  earning  more  than  £1m)  and  more  use  of  deferred  or  long  term  (dividend)  bonuses  –  proposals  which  he  himself  was  noticeably  later  powerless  to  implement  when  he  became  Chairman  of  Barclays.  His  rather  inevitable  conclusions  were  to  propose  more  shareholder  activism,  and  to  seek  to  further  align  the  interests  of  management  with  shareholders,  in  

Page 27: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  27  

the  expectation  that  such  alignment  would  lead  to  more  prudent  long  term  management  (Walker,  2009,  pp14-­‐22).  Assuming  that  the  failings  in  corporate  governance  arose  out  of  inadequacies  in  the  existing  corporate  governance  regime  rather  than  intrinsic  problems  in  the  ownership  and  supervision  structure  of  PLC  banks,  he  proposed  more  of  that  soft  law  regime  calling  for  oversight,  rather  than  thinking  about  reforming  the  ownership  structure  and  tackling  its  adverse  incentives.  Walker’s  entire  report  was  predicated  on  the  assumption  that  banks  would  continue  to  be  run  for  shareholder  value;  indeed  Walker  confirmed  as  much  at  the  start  of  his  report  in  para.1.1:  ‘the  role  of  corporate  governance  is  to  protect  and  advance  the  interests  of  shareholders’  (Walker,  2009,  p23).  Like  the  Banking  Crisis  Inquiry  (2009c,  para.176)  Walker’s  review  presumed  there  was  an  agency  gap  which  needed  to  be  narrowed  without  questioning  the  logic  of  having  banks  act  as  agents  for  their  shareholders.  Walker’s  review  thus  sought  to  side-­‐line  from  the  official  response  and  the  wider  banking  reform  debate  any  question  about  whether  banks  should  be  run  for  shareholder  value.      

2.2.6   Sir  John  Kay  –  reforming  equity  markets,  not  ownership      

Kay’s  review  in  UK  equity  markets,  published  in  July  2012,  contrasts  starkly  with  the  Walker  Review  and  for  that  reason  it  is  worth  exploring  here  both  out  of  chronological  order  and  notwithstanding  that  the  review  was  not  limited  to  reform  in  the  banking  sector  as  it  is  illuminating  to  consider  the  review  alongside  the  Walker  review.    Asked  by  the  Business  Secretary,  Vincent  Cable,  to  make  proposals  for  making  ‘equity  markets’  ‘more  efficient’  and  less  ‘short  term’  (Kay,  2012,  p7).    John  Kay  reported  on  a  number  of  issues  which  were  conspicuously  absent  from  Walker’s  review.  He  reported  that  shareholders  are  demonstrably  failing  to  govern  companies  and  have  little  incentive  to  do  so  (Kay,  2012,  p22);  that  share  ownership  is  not  functioning  in  accordance  with  its  purpose  to  provide  new  sources  of  investment  and  that  shareholders  are  increasingly  removed  from  having  any  supervisory  function  (Kay,  2012,  p32)  and  that  the  structure  of  shareholding  favours  trading,  transactions  and  intermediation,  over  long  term  productive  and  sustainable  investment  leading  to  chronic  problems  of  short  termism  and  under-­‐investment  (Kay,  2012,  p10).    

Kay  proposed  the  imposition  of  fiduciary  duties  upon  financial  intermediaries  so  that  they  owe  duties  to  investors  and  those  involved  in  trading  and  investment  to  put  the  interests  of  investors  first  (Kay,  2012,  p13).  He  proposed  that  trading  intermediaries  disclose  their  own  interests,  charges  and  commissions  (Kay,  2012,  ch.9);  and  he  called  for  reporting  standards  to  be  improved,  and  quarterly  reporting  to  be  eradicated  (Kay,  2012,  ch.10).  He  also  called  for  the  incentives  of  managers  and  intermediaries  to  be  aligned  with  more  long  term  value  creation  in  companies  through  scrapping  cash  bonuses  and  delaying  equity  interests  until  after  directors  had  exit  the  company  (Kay,  2012,  ch.11)  and  he  called  for  regulators  to  focus  on  the  interests  of  investors,  not  on  those  of  intermediaries  and  to  abandon  their  reliance  on  the  efficient  market  theory  (Kay,  2012,  ch.12).    

What  is  interesting  about  the  Key  review  is  not  merely  that  his  proposals  in  the  main  went  by  the  way-­‐side  and  were  not  adopted,  but  that  Kay  was  given  

Page 28: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  28  

scope  to  inquire  into  the  problem  of  shareholder  ownership  in  a  way  which  effectively  precluded  him  from  introducing  the  shareholder  value  critique  into  the  banking  reform  debate.  Kay  was  given  a  very  limited  mandate,  being  asked  not  to  consider  problems  caused  by  shareholders  owning  companies,  but  rather  problems  caused  more  generally  by  equity  markets  and  the  increasing  financialisation  and  distancing  of  shareholders.  Further  he  was  asked  not  to  consider  problems  with  equity  in  banking,  but  generally  to  undertake  an  inquiry  across  all  sectors  into  the  functioning  of  equity  markets  in  the  UK.  He  was  thus  asked  essentially  to  consider  the  problem  of  trading  in  shares,  and  not  whether  there  is  a  fundamental  problem  with  companies  being  owned  by  shareholders  and  run  for  their  benefit.    That  device,  which  distinguished  between  the  problem  of  shareholders  trading  shares  rather  than  retaining  an  interest  in  owning  shares,  required  him  to  assume  that  shareholders  should  own  shares  and  enabled  him  to  critique  problems  caused  by  shareholder  ownership  in  only  a  limited  and  indirect  way.  Kay  was  invited  to  consider  the  controversial  subject  which  the  official  response  had  otherwise  avoided,  but  in  a  way  which  did  not  risk  trespassing  upon  the  modest  proposals  recommended  by  Walker.  He  was  asked  to  consider  problems  arising  through  the  holding  of  equities,  rather  than  whether  shareholders  were  fit  to  govern.  Having  thus  not  been  asked  to  consider  whether  shareholder  ownership  drives  problems  particularly  in  banking,  he  avoided  bringing  the  ownership  issue  being  any  part  of  the  official  response.      

2.2.7   Sir  John  Vickers  –  preserving  universal  banking        

In  2010,  a  year  after  the  former  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  Alistair  Darling  had  confirmed  that  there  would  not  be  a  full  separation  of  retail  and  wholesale  functions  (Bischoff,  2009,  p2),  the  new  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  George  Osborne,  announced  that  Sir  John  Vickers  would  chair  a  commission  to  formulate  government  policy  recommendations  for  banking  reform  with  a  view  to  :    

‘Reducing  systemic  risk  in  the  banking  sector…  Mitigating  moral  hazard  …  Reducing  both  the  likelihood  and  impact  of  firm  failure;  and…  Promoting  competition  …  with  a  view  to  ensuring  that  the  needs  of  banks’  customers  and  clients  are  efficiently  served,  and  in  particular  considering  the  extent  to  which  large  banks  gain  competitive  advantage  from  being  perceived  as  too  big  to  fail’.  (H.M.  Treasury,  2010)      Vickers  was  asked  to  do  that    ‘with  specific  attention  paid  to  the  potential  

impact  of  its  recommendations  on…  the  competitiveness  of  the  UK  financial  and  professional  services  sectors  and  the  wider  UK  economy;  and  Risks  to  the  fiscal  position  of  the  Government’  (H.M.  Treasury,  2010).  Rather  than  being  asked  to  consider  the  big  questions  about  what  went  wrong  with  banks,  what  we  want  from  the  sector  and  what  needs  to  be  changed  to  deliver  that,  Vickers  was  instead  charged  with  only  ‘mitigating  moral  hazard’,  not  avoiding  it  altogether  (ICB,  2010a).  He  was  called  upon  to  make  proposals  which  reduce  the  impact  of  systemic  failure  (ICB,  2010a),  not  to  prevent  it  from  occurring  in  the  first  place;  he  was  asked  to  address  ‘the  competitive  advantage  from  [banks]  being  perceived  as  too  big  to  fail’  (ICB,  2010a),  rather  than  to  tackle  the  problems  caused  by  banks  being  too  big  to  fail  and  he  was  asked  to  consider  ways  of  making  banks  

Page 29: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  29  

better  able  to  absorb  losses  and  less  costly  to  sort  out  when  they  get  into  trouble  (ICB,  2011,  p8),  not  to  do  whatever  was  necessary  to  ensure  banks  avoided  getting  into  such  serious  trouble  in  the  first  place.  The  Independent  Commission  on  Banking's  chief  function,  as  encapsulated  by  Sir  John  Vickers'  executive  summary,  was  to  ‘insulate  essential  banking  services’,  to  minimize  the  damage  caused  to  those  essential  services,  and  to  the  tax  payer,  in  the  event  of  financial  collapse  but  to  do  so  ‘with  specific  attention…  to…  the  competitiveness  of  the  UK  financial  and  professional  services  sector’  (ICB  2011,  p10).    He  was  asked  to  make  recommendations  with  specific  attention  being  paid  to  the  ‘complex  issue  of  separating  retail  and  investment  banking  functions’  (ICB,  2010a)  and  to  make  such  recommendations  whilst  also  bearing  in  mind  the  need  for  the  City  of  London  to  remain  a  thriving  financial  centre  (ICB,  2011,  p145),  the  inference  being  that  intervention  should  be  subordinate  to  that  aim.    

Unsurprisingly,  Vickers  recommended  proposals  which  he  had  essentially  been  called  upon  to  make.  As  Martin  Wolf,  one  of  the  ICB’s  members  later  clarified  (Wolf,  2014a)  the  ICB  recommended  the  most  modest  ways  of  achieving  what  had  been  called  for.  Vickers  proposed  insulating  essential  banking  functions  by  ring-­‐fencing  them,  rather  than  separating  them  out  risky  and  socially  important  banking  functions.  Having  been  asked  to  think  the  unthinkable  (ICB,  2011c)  Vickers  made  recommendations  to  minimally  disrupt  the  status  quo.  Although  Vickers  was  asked  to  make  recommendations  to  promote  competition,  the  ICB  merely  proposed  that  the  sector  be  referred  to  the  Competition  Commission.  Rather  than  making  radical  proposals  to  break  up  banks  and  reduce  their  size  and  dominance  in  an  oligopolistic  market,  the  ICB  kicked  the  issue  into  the  long  grass  calling  for  future  inquiry  by  the  Competition  Commission.  Having  not  been  asked  to  consider  how  and  why  bank  failure  was  caused  in  the  first  place,  and  how  it  could  be  avoided  Vickers  made  proposals  for  ameliorative  and  not  radical  reform,  and  did  so  in  a  modest  way  which  insulated  business  as  usual,  and  allowed  banks  considerable  time  (8  years)  to  implement  his  proposals  and  a  considerable  degree  of  discretion  to  determine  what  activities  can  and  cannot  be  protected  and  need  to  be  ring-­‐fenced.        

2.2.8   Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  –  a  missed  opportunity  

Following  the  market-­‐rigging  scandal  which  revealed  that  banks  had  submitted  false  submissions  to  set  the  London  Interbank  Official  Rate  (‘LIBOR’),  a  growing  consensus  emerged  that  there  was  a  problem  within  banking  and  that  something  needed  to  be  done  to  change  it  (Treasury  Committee,  2012b).  The  PCBS  was  subsequently  empowered  to  investigate  the  issue  of  ‘culture’  and  to  make  wide-­‐ranging  proposals  for  reforming  the  banking  sector  with  a  view  to  reforming  ‘culture’.  Specifically,  it  was  appointed  by  both  Houses  of  Parliament  to  consider  and  report  on:    

 ‘professional  standards  and  culture  of  the  UK  banking  sector,  taking  account  of  regulatory  and  competition  investigations  into  the  LIBOR  rate-­‐setting  process,  lessons  to  be  learned  about  corporate  governance,  transparency  and  conflicts  of  interest,  and  their  implications  for  regulation  and  for  Government  policy  and  to  make  recommendations  for  legislative  and  other  action’    (PCBS,  2013b,  ‘terms  of  reference’).  

Page 30: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  30  

 Properly  resourced,  the  13  members  who  employed  19  members  of  staff  

and  engaged  14  others  outside  parliament,  including  independent  counsel  to  cross  examine  witnesses,  conducted  an  extensive  public  inquiry  over  the  best  part  of  a  year,  which  under  the  glare  of  public  scrutiny  and  television  cameras,  heard  evidence  from  more  than  250  witnesses.  On  19  June  2013,  the  PCBS  published  its  final  report  ‘Changing  banking  for  good’  in  two  volumes  (2013a,  2013b)  which  ran  to  more  than  500  pages  and  cost  more  than  £850,000  to  produce  (PCBS,  2013a,  annex  1,  para.10).    

The  report  made  wide-­‐ranging  recommendations  to  deal  with  the  problem  of  ‘culture’  in  banking.    Its  main  proposals  were:  to  overhaul  the  way  senior  bankers  are  vetted  and  authorized;  to  introduce  a  clearer  allocation  of  responsibilities;  to  introduce  new  criminal  offences  for  reckless  banking;  to  make  changes  to  banker  remuneration  to  align  rewards  with  longer  term  performance  including  making  greater  use  of  bail-­‐in  bonds,  and  claw-­‐backs;  as  well  as  introducing  greater  powers  for  regulators  to  defer  rewards  (PCBS,  2013a,  ‘conclusions  and  recommendations’).    

Unlike  the  inquiries  before  it,  the  PCBS  did  not  ignore  the  issue  of  ownership  and  how  shareholder  value  banking  can  provide  incentives  for  bad  behaviour.  In  annex  5,  which  considered  ‘bank  ownership’,  the  PCBS  observed  how  :  

‘bank  shareholders  typically  have  limited  interest  in  the  operation  of  banks,  and  tend  to  place  a  premium  on  short-­‐term  returns’    (PCBS,  2013b,  p533).      

 Indeed,  the  main  report  observed  how  shareholders  gave  banks  every  incentive  to  push  for  greater  leverage  (PCBS,  2013b,  p154)  and  as  such  suggested  that  they  were  ill-­‐equipped  to  hold  bank  boards  to  account.  It  also  considered  that  institutional  shareholders  had  incentives  to  encourage  directors  to  pursue  high  risk  strategies  in  pursuit  of  short-­‐term  returns  (PCBS,  2013b,  p155).        

Nevertheless,  the  PCBS’s  investigation  into  the  relevance  of  ownership  was  relatively  limited.  Focusing  instead  on  the  problem  of  ‘culture’,  it  considered  what  Helmke  at  al  (2004)  would  have  described  as  ‘informal’  institutions,  namely  banking  ‘culture’,  ‘standards’  and  ‘practices’,  rather  than  seeking  to  address  and  contemplate  reforming  what  might  be  called  more  ‘formal’  institutions,  such  as  the  law  of  corporate  governance  or  regulation  of  the  sector.  The  PCBS’s  ownership-­‐related  reforms  for  example  were  limited.  Having  identified  how  banks  have  perverse  incentives  to  act  for  shareholders  it  merely  suggested  that  government  should  consult  on  whether  IFI’s  should  be  run  not  only  for  shareholders  but  also  for  other  stakeholders  putting  ‘the  financial  safety  and  soundness  of  the  company  ahead  of  the  interests  of  its  members’  (PCBS,  2013b,  p344)  –  a  proposal  which  has  not  been  adopted  or  taken  up.  Although  the  PCBS  recognized  that  problems  were  caused  by  banks  being  run  for  the  benefit  of  largely  disinterested  shareholders,  who  contributed  proportionately  little  to  bank  assets  (PCBS,  2013b,  annex  5  ‘bank  ownership’),  the  government  was  unwilling  to  adopt  any  of  its  proposals  to  consider  reforming  ownership  incentives,  and  has  instead  watered  down  the  validity  of  this  analysis  by  cherry-­‐picking  other  proposals  for  adoption,  unrelated  to  ownership.    

Page 31: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  31  

This  omission  represents  more  than  mere  oversight  and  a  missed  opportunity  but  suggests  a  wilful  refusal  on  the  part  of  government  to  think  about  any  alternative  to  the  shareholder  value  paradigm  of  banking  (Black  et  al,  2015).  Having  effectively  shut  the  door  to  any  debate  about  removing  shareholder  value  banking  by  side-­‐lining  the  issue  from  the  official  response,  the  issue  was  not  let  in  through  the  back  door  by  the  PCBS’s  inquiry.  

The  PCBS  was  instead  asked  to  consider  the  problems  of  ‘banking  standards’  and  what  was  widely  perceived  to  be  a  problem  with  ‘culture’.  ‘Culture’  is  a  complex  concept  open  to  divergent  interpretations  and  meanings.  Indeed,  it  has  been  described  as  one  of  the  most  complex  words  to  define  in  the  entire  English  language  (Williams,  2014).  Presupposing  that  the  banking  industry  had  a  problem  with  ‘culture’,  the  PCBS  was  not  asked  to  consider  how  the  way  banks  are  owned  created  a  problem  with  culture  and  how  such  causes  might  be  tackled.  As  Luyendijk  (2015)  argues  the  PCBS  addressed  the  symptoms  and  not  the  cause  of  misbehaviour,  like  addressing  damp  from  water  ingress  without  fixing  the  hole  in  the  roof.  It  addressed  the  proximate  and  not  the  underlying  causes  of  bad  behaviour,  trying  to  fix  the  problem  of  culture  without  any  mandate  to  tackle  the  causes  driving  such  problems.    

The  PCBS  also  made  its  proposals  without  investigating  the  causes  of  the  banking  crisis  or  what  is  needed  to  avoid  future  problems,  and  without  considering  what  reforms  are  necessary  to  ensure  banks  do  what  we  want  of  them.  Indeed,  its  final  report  explicitly  clarified  that  it  was  not  making  such  inquiries:    

‘67.  A  commission  on  banking  standards  cannot  address  the  causes  of  the  financial  cycle  which  is,  in  any  case,  extremely  unlikely  to  be  eradicable.  Nor  should  the  recommendations  of  a  UK  body  be  expected  to  correct,  or  attempt  to  correct,  all  that  is  wrong  in  a  global  industry.  However,  that  does  not  mean  that  nothing  should  be  done.  A  great  deal  can  and  should  be  done  to  reduce  the  risk  of  future  crises  and  to  raise  standards.  There  is  currently  a  widespread  appetite  for  measures  to  constrain  the  misconduct,  complacency  and  recklessness  that  characterised  the  last  boom  and  its  aftermath…’    (PCBS,  2014,  para.67)  

 

2.2.9   The  Competitions  and  Markets  Authority  investigation–a  standard  recipe?  

Asked  to  look  into  enhancing  competition  in  the  retail  banking  market,  and  having  been  prevailed  upon  also  by  Vickers  to  do  so,  on  6  November  2014,  the  CMA  launched  an  investigation  into  retail  banking.  It  produced  its  final,  report,  entitled    ‘retail  banking  market  investigation’  on  9  August  2016.  Unsurprisingly,  the  CMA  found  a  lack  of  competition  in  retail  banking.  It  was  observed  that  the  biggest  banks  enjoy  a  dominant  position  in  a  highly  concentrated  oligopolistic  market  with  high  barriers  to  entry  (CMA,  2016,  para.93).  Rather  than  exercising  any  of  its  extensive  statutory  powers  for  example  to  break  up  the  banks  and  reduce  their  size  to  reduce  their  stranglehold  or  to  end  free-­‐whilst-­‐in-­‐credit  banking,  however,  the  CMA  instead  proposed  a  modest  set  of  measures  aimed  to  make  it  easier  for  retail  consumers  and  SME’s  to  change  bank  accounts  and  understand  what  charges  they  pay  banks.    The  proposals  were  widely  received  with  criticism  for  failing  to  do  enough  to  address  competitive  failures  and  for  failing  to  adopt  measures  others  had  called  for  such  

Page 32: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  32  

as  ending  free  whilst  in  credit  services,  or  capping  overdraft  fees  and  charges  and  the  report  has  been  widely  criticized  for  not  doing  enough  for  consumers  or  to  reform  competition  (Treanor,  2016).    

2.3   Part  2:  the  wider  debate        

2.3.1   What  was  missed?      The  official  response  arose  in  the  face  of  elite  political  resistance  to  radical  reform  of  the  banking  sector  (CRESC,  2009,  p11).  As  was  made  clear  by  Bischoff,  the  prevailing  political  climate  favoured  reforms  which  were  minimally  disruptive  and  were  subordinated  to  the  aim  of  promoting  a  competitive  City.  There  was  evidence  of  what  Carpenter  et  al  (2004)  described  as  ‘non-­‐materialist’  regulatory  capture,  in  other  words  the  sort  of  cultural  or  cognitive  capture  often  witnessed  around  industries  that  fund  powerful  pressure  groups.  Certainly,  there  was  no  shortage  of  lobbying  on  banking  reform.  In  2011  alone,  the  year  in  which  Vickers  produced  his  report,  the  British  Banking  Association  (‘BBA’)  spent  £92  million  on  lobbying  government  in  an  attempt  to  secure  favourable  policy  changes  (Mathiason  et  al,  2012).  As  its  chairwoman,  Angela  Knight,  who  ironically  argued  in  2007  that  banks  could  be  trusted  in  setting  the  LIBOR  rates  in  2007  and  in  2011  that  there  was  nothing  wrong  with  the  way  banks  had  sold  customers  PPI  in  2011  (Bloomberg,  2013),  gave  over  800  interviews  and  1000  speeches  in  the  banking  crisis,  and  was  heavily  involved  in  lobbying  for  the  reforms  which  the  banks  wanted  (Garside,  2012).  CRESC  in  particular  discovered  that  the  Bischoff  report  was  produced  following  consultation  with  mainly  financial  actors,  with  non-­‐financial  actors  being  largely  excluded  (2009,  p24).      

In  this  environment  of  considerable  political  capture  (CRESC,  2009,  p11),  there  was  an  absence  of  any  radical  challenge  to  the  status  quo,  and  as  we  shall  explore  further  in  chapter  4,  the  political  and  economic  settlement  which  was  brokered  in  the  Big  Bang,  remained  fundamentally  undisturbed  by  the  official  response.  The  prevalence  of  the  PLC  ownership  model,  strongly  favoured  following  the  Big  Bang,  was  not  affected  by  banking  reforms.  On  the  whole  the  vast  majority  of  banks  continue  to  be  run  for  shareholder  value,  and  the  way  they  are  owned  and  run  has  not  been  altered.    

Without  holding  an  official  inquiry  into  what  went  wrong  in  banking  and  how  it  can  be  avoided,  and  without  having  engaged  more  openly  in  public  debate  about  what  we  want  our  banks  to  do,  it  is  unsurprising  that  the  Government’s  reform  agenda  has  been  widely  criticized  by  academics  and  other  commentators  as  being  inadequate  (Wolf,  2014a,  2014c,  chs8-­‐9;  Bowman  et  al,  2014,  ch.5;  King,  2016,  ch.9;  Turner,  2016,  p240)  or  representing  a  ‘missed  opportunity’  (Black,  2015).  Many  feel  that  the  government  has  not  gone  nearly  far  enough  to  effect  needed  reforms.  Some  consider  it  to  be  in  hock  to  finance  in  an  elite  coalition  around  banking  (CRESC,  2009,  pp11-­‐14;  Engelen  et  al,  2011,  pp14-­‐18).  What  is  clear  from  the  main  reports  produced  within  the  official  response  is  that  the  government  managed  to  avoid  asking  the  sorts  of  big  questions  one  would  expect,  and  it  appeared  to  be  committed  to  preserving  the  status  quo.      

Unfortunately,  the  critics  of  the  Government’s  position  who  have  generally  called  for  more  radical  reforms  have  not  emerged  in  the  wider  banking  

Page 33: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  33  

reform  debate  with  a  coherent  and  unified  message  and  clear  voice.  Absent  from  the  wider  debate  has  been  a  dominant  Keynes-­‐like  figure  behind  whom  others  could  rally  and  mobilise  to  challenge  the  established  status  quo  and  call  for  radical  reforms.  In  the  wake  of  the  last  depression,  Keynes  enjoyed  a  significant  public  platform.  He  commanded  the  respect  not  only  of  academics  but  also  of  many  prominent  politicians  who  were  eager  to  seek  his  views  (Wapshott,  2012,  ch.2).  After  the  GFC,  there  has  not  been  any  singular  prominent  proponent  for  change,  as  Keynes  was.  The  picture  which  emerged  instead  from  the  wider  reform  debate  is  one  of  a  number  of  disparate  figures  and  factions  raising  divergent  issues  whilst  grappling  with  diverse  and  complex  issues,  and  lacking  any  unified  movement  and  coherent  voice.    

Many  (such  as  Admati  et  al  2012)  have  focused  for  greater  capital  adequacy,  increased  fractional  reserves  and  the  need  to  de-­‐leverage  banks  or  for  banks  to  take  greater  equity  positions  in  real  estate  lending  (Mian  et  al,2014;  Turner,  2016,  ch.12).  Others  (such  as  Wolf  2014a)  have  called  for  more  radical  competition  intervention  to  break  up  the  banking  oligopoly  to  better  insulate  narrow  banking  and  allow  riskier  parts  of  the  banking  business  to  safely  fail.  Others  (such  as  Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p114)  have  suggested  that  retail  banks  should  be  regulated  as  utilities  with  lower  expectations  on  returns  on  equity.  Some  have  called  for  greater  regulatory  powers  to  control  financial  activities,  licencing  financial  instruments  like  dangerous  chemicals,  or  for  the  simplification  of  lending  products,  or  to  enable  losses  to  be  imposed  on  others  in  the  event  of  bank  failure  (Turner,  2016,  p173).  And  others  have  focused  on  greater  reform  of  the  criminal  law,  or  regulatory  powers  or  reform  of  the  tax  system  -­‐  calling  for  tax  relief  for  debt  to  be  cancelled  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.10)  or  for  tax  incentives  to  be  reversed  so  that  equity,  not  debt  is  privileged  (Haldane  2011)  or  for  the  creation  of  a  Tobin-­‐style  tax  on  credit  intermediation,  or  indeed  for  a  global  tax  on  wealth  (Picketty,  2014).      

Out  of  this  diverse  assortment  of  analyses  emerge  two  distinct  critiques  of  the  official  response,  which  are  relevant  to  this  thesis.  Both  are  more  willing  to  question  and  challenge  the  status  quo.  The  first  can  be  characterised  as  challenging  the  pro-­‐City  narrative,  namely  that  banks  should  be  left  largely  undisturbed  in  order  to  perform  ‘business  as  usual’  with  only  minimal  and  essential  reforms  and  intervention  subordinated  to  the  aim  of  promoting  a  thriving  City.  The  second  challenges  the  pro-­‐stock  market  narrative,  questioning  the  dominant  assumption  that  there  is  no  alternative  to  banks  being  publicly  traded  and  run  for  their  shareholder-­‐owners.    We  have  already  explored,  in  the  first  part  of  this  chapter,  how  the  government  itself  claimed  to  steer  the  banking  reform  debate  and  how  these  two  issues  were  avoided  by  the  official  response,  which  set  the  agenda  for  debate,  and  marginalised  those  issues  in  the  way  it  delegated  policy  issues  to  be  decided  upon  by  experts,  whose  proposals  were  invited  through  limited,  generally  leading  terms  of  reference.  That  the  government  has  been  unwilling  to  consider  these  two  issues  critical  of  the  status  quo  suggests  a  high  level  of  political  and  regulatory  capture,  and  a  lack  of  political  imagination  and  productive  vision  for  any  alternative  experiment  to  that  brokered  in  the  Big  Bang  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  ch.5).        

Page 34: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  34  

2.3.2     Challenging  the  ‘ownership’  paradigm    

Andy  Haldane  is  perhaps  the  most  dominant  figure  to  emerge  in  the  wider  reform  debate  who  has  been  willing  to  challenge  orthodoxy  and  question  some  of  the  assumptions  made  by  the  official  response  in  a  way  which  has  stoked  interest  in  more  radical  reforms  from  a  wider  audience  than  might  otherwise  have  been  reached  by  academics.    Widely  regarded  as  a  rising  star  in  the  Bank  of  England  (see  for  example  :  Ralph,  2012  and  Cassidy,  2013),  Haldane,  who  became  Executive  Director  of  Financial  Stability  on  1  January  2009  and  Chief  Economist  on  1  June  2014,  is  an  atypical  central  banker.  In  October  2012,  Haldane  spoke  out  in  favour  of  the  ‘Occupy’  movement,  whose  protesters  had  camped  outside  of  St.  Paul’s  Cathedral,  arguing  that  they  had  been  right  to  criticise  the  financial  sector  and  that  their  protest  had  had  an  impact  in  persuading  bankers  and  politicians  ‘to  behave  in  a  more  moral  way’  (Kuchler  et  al,  2012).    

Haldane  published  some  radical  and  controversial  ideas  in  the  banking  reform  debate  for  example  introducing  epidemiology  as  a  means  of  analysing  the  spread  and  containment  of  financial  crisis  (Haldane,  2009);  challenging  the  orthodox  view  that  banks  are  net  contributories  to  the  economy  (Haldane,  2010);  and  challenging  the  assumption  that  banks  should  be  run  for  shareholder  value  (Haldane,  2011;  Haldane,  2015).  Shortly  after  the  publication  of  Vickers  in  October  2011,  Haldane  questioned  how  banks  should  be  owned  in  his  article  ‘Control  rights  (and  wrongs)’  (Haldane,  2011).  In  that  lecture,  and  his  later  lecture  in  2015  ‘Who  owns  a  company?’  (Haldane,  2015)  he  challenged  the  assumption  that  banks  should  be  run  for  their  shareholders,  explaining  how  shareholders  provide  only  a  vanishingly  tiny  fraction  of  bank  assets.  Unlike  the  official  response  which  marginalised  this  critique,  Haldane  explored  how  shareholder-­‐value  banking  provides  perverse  incentives  for  management  to  take  socially  excessive  risks,  dangerously  leveraging  the  bank  and  becoming  ‘volatility  junkies’  by  engaging  in  risky  business  (Haldane,  2011;  Haldane,  2015).    

That  this  radical  analysis  has  come  from  within  the  Bank  of  England  has  lent  significant  credibility  to  the  stakeholder  debate  and  those  who  challenge  the  pro-­‐stock  market  narrative  that  banks  should  be  run  as  any  other  PLC  as  if  owned  by  its  shareholders  and  for  their  sole  benefit.  As  we  shall  explore  in  the  next  chapter,  prior  to  the  GFC,  proponents  of  stakeholder  management  theory  were  very  much  marginalised  and  in  a  minority  within  the  corporate  governance  debate.  The  stakeholder  debate,  which  contends  that  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  (Ferri  et  al,  2010)  or  ownerless  banks  (Bøhren  et  al,  2013)  are  less  likely  to  sacrifice  the  long  term  interests  of  wider  stakeholders  and  less  prone  to  take  excessive  risks  and  to  adopt  unsustainable  and  dangerous  business  strategies  (Allen  et  al,  1997,  2000,  2004,  2009)  gained  prominence  following  the  GFC.      

Nevertheless,  as  we  shall  see  in  the  next  chapter,  the  balance  of  political  and  economic  thinking  tended  to  favour  shareholder  value  governance  and  discounted  stakeholder  ideas.  By  differentiating  between  banks  and  other  sectors  of  activity,  and  emphasising  how  shareholders  contribute  so  little  to  bank  capital,  Haldane  has  helped  to  tilt  the  scales  in  this  debate,  opening  it  up  for  others  to  credibly  argue  that  banks  and  IFI’s  are  not  like  any  other  company,  and  there  is  accordingly  little  sense  in  having  them  managed  as  if  owned  exclusively  by  shareholders  who  contribute  so  little  to  the  colossal  amounts  of  money  they  

Page 35: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  35  

handle  (see  for  example:  Haldane,  2012,  2015;  Turner,  2016,  pp172-­‐174,  245-­‐246;  Black  2015;  and  also  PCBS,  2013b,  para708).  Whilst  the  ownership  debate  still  remained  at  the  fringes  of  the  wider  banking  reform  debate,  a  loose  consensus  has  now  emerged  around  the  idea  first  that  it  is  better  to  have  a  diversity  of  ownership  models  and  not  only  shareholder-­‐owned  publicly  traded  banks  (The  Oxford  Centre  for  Mutual  &  Employee-­‐owned  Business,  2009;  Nissan  et  al  2009;  The  Ownership  Commission,  2012;  Ayadi  et  al.  2009;  Hakenes  et  al  2009;  Llewellyn  2010;  PCBS,  2013b,  paras343,  356),  and  also  that  running  banks  to  achieve  shareholder-­‐value,  and  rewarding  management  for  doing  so,  can  provide  perverse  incentives  for  banks  to  misbehave  and  take  on  excessive  risks  (Haldane  2011;  Coco  et  al  2010;  Hakenes  et  al  2009;  Coco  et  al,  2010;  Ferri  et  al  2010,  2012;  PCBS,  2013b,  paras176,  203,  597,  660-­‐666,  684,  703,  708).    

But  whilst  Haldane  enjoys  a  public  platform  from  which  he  can  reach  a  wide  audience,  unlike  Keynes  who  was  able  to  disseminate  radical  proposals  as  well  as  analysis,  Haldane  has  been  limited  in  the  degree  to  which  he  has  been  able  to  call  for  concrete  reforms.  Being  a  Bank  of  England  ‘insider’,  not  enjoying  the  independence  for  example  which  Keynes  enjoyed,  he  has  been  somewhat  constrained  in  how  far  he  can  make  radical  reform  proposals.  His  connection  with  Threadneedle  Street  has  inevitably  inhibited  his  ability  to  call  for  radical  reform.  He  has  been  able  to  produce  radical  analysis  and  openly  discuss  fundamentals  but  he  has  not  been  able  to  discuss  the  logic  of  such  analysis  and  how  the  same  translates  into  concrete  proposals  for  widespread  reform,  as  taking  any  radical  political  position  might  compromise  and  jeopardise  his  independence  and  that  of  the  Bank  of  England.  The  pro-­‐stock-­‐market  narrative  was  not  the  only  aspect  of  the  official  response  with  which  others  took  issue  in  the  wider  banking  reform  debate.    

2.3.3     Challenging  the  ‘structural’  paradigm    

Other  academics  have  questioned  the  extent  of  finance’s  political  and  regulatory  capture,  and  whether  the  political  and  economic  settlement  brokered  in  the  Big  Bang  needs  to  be  re-­‐balanced  to  enable  banks  better  to  do  what  we  expect  from  them.  Amongst  other  literature,  chapter  4  explores  how  pressures  are  exerted  on  banks  from  the  structure  and  regulation  of  the  environment  within  which  banks  operate  -­‐  as  opposed  to  the  way  banks  are  owned.  Emerging  from  the  wider  reform  debate,  there  are  really  two  schools  with  distinct  geographical  groupings  which  have  questioned  the  extent  of  political  capture  and  considered  how  the  structure  of  the  wider  economy  and  the  regulatory  environment  within  which  banks  operate  affects  what  they  do  and  how  they  behave.  There  is  the  Manchester  collective  and  the  London  collective.    

In  Manchester,  revolving  largely  around  the  Centre  for  Research  on  Socio-­‐cultural  Change  (‘CRESC’),  a  group  of  Manchester  academics  and  intellectuals  have  published  various  materials  on  banking  reform  including  the  2009  ‘Alternative  report  on  UK  banking  reform’  (CRESC,  2009),  the  2011  ‘After  the  great  complacence’  (Engelen  et  al,  2011)  and  the  2014,  ‘The  end  of  the  experiment’  (Bowman  et  al,  2014).  This  collective  has  been  heavily  critical  of  the  political  and  financial  coalition  around  banking,  challenging  the  assumption  that  banks  add  value  to  the  economy  and  calling  for  more  public  engagement  in  the  

Page 36: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  36  

debate  about  reforming  the  sector  (CRESC,  2009,  pp5-­‐7;  Engelen  et  al  2011,  p371).  By  comparing  tax  revenues,  employment  statistics  and  the  benefits  of  bank  claimed  wealth-­‐creation  against  the  ultimate  cost  to  the  public  of  the  bail  out  and  programme  of  quantitative  easing,  this  collective  challenged  the  pro-­‐city  narrative,  arguing  that  banks  did  not  add  value  and  are  not  net  contributors  to  the  state  but  that  they  exert  a  disproportionate  influence  over  government  policy  (CRESC,  2009,  p32)  and  argue  that  the  state’s  commitment  to  a  light  tough  regulatory  environment  for  finance  has  moved  beyond  naivety  and  into  the  realms  of  hubris  (Engelen  et  al,  2011,  p15).  They  warned  of  the  politically  corruptive  nature  of  finance,  providing  a  compelling  narrative  about  the  dangers  of  alignment  between  political  and  financial  interests  (CRESC,  2009,  pp5-­‐6)  and  they  reduced  down  issues  in  the  banking  reform  debate  into  political,  not  specialist  and  technical,  issues  (CRESC,  2009,  pp9-­‐10).  Calls  for  clarifying  what  we  want  from  banking  and  regulating  their  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  functions  with  such  purposes  in  mind,  have  been  repeated  by  others  such  as  Turner  (2016),  and  in  view  of  the  failure  of  the  Government’s  ‘funding  for  lending’  initiative  (Jenkins  et  al,  2013),  many  would  argue  that  there  are  good  reasons  for  trying  to  set  explicit  targets  and  regulating  banks  to  achieve  certain  levels  of  funding  for  certain  activities.        

The  Manchester  collective  also  identified  how  the  underlying  structure  of  banking  drives  excessive  risk-­‐taking  and  inherent  financial  instability  (CRESC,  2009,  pp40-­‐51;  Engelen  et  al,  2011,  pp97-­‐187).    In  ‘The  end  of  the  experiment’,  it  was  also  critical  of  the  political  settlement  brokered  in  the  Big  Bang  with  shareholder-­‐value  banking  becoming  ubiquitous,  arguing  that  the  continuing  over-­‐commitment  to  the  neoliberal  experiment,  is  evidence  of  a  lack  of  productive  vision  and  leadership  to  create  an  alternative  to  depart  from  the  light-­‐touch  regulatory  status  quo  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p145).  

Revolving  around  the  London  School  of  Economics,  another  grouping  of  academics  and  policy-­‐makers  have  published  various  materials  on  banking  reform  chiefly  the  2010  ‘Future  of  Finance’  report,  as  well  as  a  mass  of  scholarly  articles  including  those  which  have  been  heavily  critical  of  shareholder  value  banking  (such  as  Black  et  al  2015).  This  collective  has  been  more  willing  to  challenge  the  orthodox  pro-­‐City  narrative  and  the  assumption  that  bankers  give  to  society  more  than  they  take.  Rich  in  the  variety  of  its  offerings  and  analysis,  ‘The  future  of  finance’  brings  together  an  assortment  of  contributions  from  an  array  of  academics,  commentators  and  officials  including,  Adair  Turner,  Martin  Wolf  and  Andy  Haldane.  It  covers  topics  such  as  the  need  for  greater  capital  reserves  and  macro  prudential  regulation  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.1);  the  need  for  narrow  banking  functions  to  be  protected  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.8);  the  need  to  align  banker's  pay  directly  with  banks'  long  term  performance  and  the  need  to  regulate  the  shadow  banking  industry  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.9);  the  need  to  create  an  international  financial  regulatory  architecture  through  treaty  organisations  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.10);  and  the  proposal  for  living  wills  for  banks  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.5).  This  collective  was  not  averse  to  blaming  bankers  and  regulators  for  contributing  towards  the  crisis,  and  to  criticise  socially  useless  financial  activities  such  as  momentum  trading  for  exacerbating  bubbles  and  asset  inflation  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch3).  This  collective  has  also  been  critical  of  the  politicisation  of  finance  and  the  political  and  regulatory  capture,  

Page 37: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  37  

challenging  the  claimed  value  of  the  City  and  questioning  its  disproportionate  influence  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  ch.2).    

Following  on  from  the  early  work  of  these  two  schools,  a  loose  but  noticeable  consensus  appears  to  have  emerged  from  the  wider  banking  reform  debate  which  is  critical  of  the  settlement  brokered  in  the  big  bang,  and  its  deference  and  over-­‐reliance  on  economic  models  and  ideas,  including  the  efficient  market  hypothesis  and  light-­‐touch  regulation.    The  post-­‐1980s  experiment  has  come  under  increasing  criticism  from  a  wide  range  of  sources  who  have  variously  challenged  the  assumptions  bound  up  by  neoliberalism  and  chiefly  the  notion  that  perfectly  functioning  and  efficient  financial  markets  mean  that  we  can  largely  ignore  the  role  fractional  reserve  banks  play  in  creating  credit  and  allocation  (Bowman  et  al  2014,  ch.1;  Turner,  2016,  ch.2;  King  2016,  ch.1).    After  concluding  his  chairmanship  of  the  FSA,  Turner  in  particular  became  a  lot  more  critical  of  the  political  establishment  for  letting  the  banking  sector  go  largely  unmonitored  in  creating  increasing  amounts  of  credit.  He  argued  that  fractional  reserve  banking  is  liable  to  create  too  much  credit  and  cause  economic  instability,  and  that  the  credit  creation  function  needs  to  be  limited  or  reigned  in  (Turner,  2016,  ch.9).    

Turner  (2016,  ch.12)  further  suggested  that  society  had  collectively  forgotten  the  realizations  made  following  the  Great  Depression,  and  he  rehearsed  arguments  made  by  the  Chicago  School,  in  the  first  half  of  the  last  century  in  favour  of  abolishing  fractional  reserve  banking.  The  Financial  Times  commentator  Martin  Wolf  also  resurrected  arguments  made  earlier  in  the  last  century  by  the  Chicago  School,  for  example  by  Soddy  (1926),  Knight  (1933),  Fisher  (1936),  and  Simons  (1936),  not  only  warning  of  the  dangers  of  having  the  credit-­‐creation  function  run  for  private  interests,  but  also  arguing  that  fractional  reserve  banking  should  be  abolished  or  controlled  by  the  state.  

Within  this  wider  debate,  many  have  argued  for  radical  reform  contending  that  more  needs  to  be  done  if  the  banking  sector  is  to  avoid  existing  in  an  unstable  relationship  with  the  market  for  the  production  of  assets  with  speculative  bubbles  being  followed  by  collapse,  risking  destabilizing  the  whole  system  (Foster  et  al,  2009,  p16;  Turner,  2016,  pp172-­‐174;  Wolf,  2014b).  Alternative  visions  for  organising  the  economy  have  emerged  from  this  debate.  Some  envisage  greater  constraints  and  control  on  credit-­‐creation  by  banks  (Turner,  2016,  pp57-­‐60)  while  others  envisage  the  state  playing  more  of  a  role  in  clarifying  what  functions  need  to  be  financed  more  generously  and  directing  credit  towards  such  investment  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p6).  Many  popular  politicians  have  advocated  for  greater  productive  investment,  arguing  that  the  existing  system  fails  to  direct  credit  towards  financing  the  sorts  of  capital  investments  needed  to  generate  additional  income  to  repay  existing  debts  and  sustain  new  ones.  Leaders  of  the  Opposition,  including  Ed  Miliband  (Eaton,  2012)  Jeremy  Corbyn  (Elgot,  2016),  and  his  rival  contender  Owen  Smith  (Stone,  2016),  all  calling  for  the  creation  of  a  well  capitalized  national  investment  bank,  similar  to  that  proposed  by  Keynes  and  the  Macmillan  committee  following  the  war  (Mayer,  2012).  Such  bank,  the  Labour  Party  suggests  (Elgot,  2016),  could  operate  along  the  lines  of  the  German  Kreditanstalt  für  Wiederaufbau  (KfW)  or  Scandinavian  Nordic  Investment  Bank  and  in  other  words  be  tasked  with  investing  in  industry  and  business  to  increase  productive  investment,  and  subsidised  with  state  funding.  

Page 38: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  38  

 

2.4   Conclusions      

Despite  many  years  of  inquiries  and  many  volumes  of  proposed  reforms,  the  banking  sector  remains  largely  unreformed,  doing  much  of  what  it  used  to  do  in  much  the  same  way  with  all  of  the  same  drivers  in  play  as  existed  before  the  banking  crisis  (Wolf,  2014a,  2014c,  chs.8-­‐9;  King,  2016,  ch.9).  According  to  some  commentators,  banks  remain  dangerously  large,  continuing  to  engage  too  heavily  in  speculative  activities  which  are  neither  sustainable  nor  socially  beneficial  but  which  threaten  the  stability  of  the  real  economy  (Turner,  2016,  pp172-­‐174).  They  still  have  every  incentive  to  engage  in  risky  business  and  to  misbehave,  to  pump  out  too  much  credit  and  to  allocate  it  in  unproductive  and  destabilizing  ways  (Turner,  2016,  pp245-­‐246).      Having  banks  run  for  extraction  is  thought  not  only  to  pose  dangers  in  terms  of  future  crises  (Wolf,  2014a,  2014b,  2014c;  Turner,  2016,  pp173-­‐174),  but  is  symptomatic  of  a  broader  societal  trend  which  tends  to  prioritize  property  wealth  over  other  forms  of  productive  investment  (Turner,  2016,  pp85,  178)  and  is  liable  to  lead  to  further  wealth  inequalities  (Piketty  2014,  pp21-­‐24).    

The  official  response  to  the  crisis  failed  to  ask  how  we  can  reform  banks  to  prevent  future  crisis  and  to  make  them  serve  the  broader  needs  of  our  society  and  in  particular  the  real  economy  and  its  need  for  productive  investment.    Those  two  aims  –  the  need  to  avoid  further  crisis,  and  to  create  a  banking  sector  which  does  what  we  need  of  it  –  could  not  be  accomplished  without  fundamentally  challenging  the  political-­‐economic  experiment  in  which  the  UK  has  been  heavily  engaged  since  the  Big  Bang  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  chs.1,  5).  The  reluctance  to  depart  from  this  paradigm  and  challenge  orthodox  thinking,  notwithstanding  the  banking  crisis  and  the  subsequent  banking  scandals  strongly  suggests  a  lack  of  any  productive  vision  for  an  alternative  experiment.    Those  two  aims  –  avoiding  future  crises  and  reforming  the  sector  to  better  serve  society’s  needs  –  require  us  to  radically  re-­‐assess  what  we  want  from  banks,  and  how  they  are  owned  and  how  the  space  within  which  they  operate  is  structured  to  help  them  to  perform  what  we  want  from  them.  Those  two  issues  ‘ownership  pressures’  and  ‘structural  pressures’  form  the  subjects  around  which  the  literature  is  considered  over  the  next  two  chapters.  

   

     

Page 39: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  39  

Chapter  3. ‘Ownership  pressures’:  what  it  is,  to  be  owned?  

     

3.1     Introduction    

‘…ownership  is  really  a  misnomer  when  applied  to  shareholders.  What  defines  shareholders  is  not  that  they  own  most  or  all  of  the  company.  Rather  they  ‘own’  least,  as  residual  claimants.  Associating  ‘shareholding’  with  ‘ownership’  thus  makes  little  substantive  sense,  despite  its  widespread  use  in  popular  discourse.    Indeed  it  is  precisely  because  shareholders  own  least,  not  most,  that  justifies  granting  them  control  rights  over  management  in  the  first  place.  By  vesting  control  rights  in  the  stakeholder  whose  claim  is  riskiest,  the  firm  is  immunised  against  taking  too  much  risk  in  the  first  place.’  (Haldane  2015,  p14)  

 As  a  matter  of  law,  in  England  and  Wales  it  is  not  possible  for  a  person  to  

own  land.  A  person  can  own  title  to  an  estate  in  land,  but  not  the  land  itself  (Grey  et  al,  2008,  ch.2.2).  The  above  excerpt,  taken  from  Haldane’s  lecture  ‘Who  owns  a  company?’  (Haldane,  2015)  highlights  a  similar  legal  distinction  in  relation  to  companies.  As  a  matter  of  law,  a  person  can  very  well  own  shares  in  a  company,  which  are  a  species  of  intangible  property  embodying  various  control  rights  including  the  right  to  have  a  company  run  in  the  shareholders’  interest  (see  s172,  Companies  Act  2006).    Whilst  shareholders  can  own  shares,  however,  they  cannot  own  the  company  itself.  Indeed,  as  a  matter  of  law,  a  company  is  a  fictional  entity  with  separate  legal  personality  distinct  from  that  of  the  persons  who  own  shares  in  it  or  who  direct  it  (Kelly,  2003).  Being  a  separate  person  with  its  own  legal  personality,  it  is  no  more  possible  for  another  to  ‘own’  it  than  it  is  for  a  person  to  own  any  other  human  being,  a  practice  which  has  been  illegal  in  Britain  since  the  Slavery  Abolition  Act  1822.    

Since  companies  in  the  UK  are  required  by  law  to  act  for  the  benefit  of  their  shareholders  (s172,  Companies  Act  2006),  it  is  nevertheless  common  to  talk  about  companies  being  ‘owned’  by  their  shareholders  (Eccles,  2015).  Indeed,  in  mainstream  economics  and  political-­‐thinking,  companies  are  commonly  described  as  being  owned  by  their  shareholders  (Mayer,  2013,  pp26-­‐31),  which  is  widely  known  as  the  ‘agency  theory’  of  corporate  governance  (Eccles,  2015),  and  in  consequence  it  is  common  also  to  reason  that  companies  should  be  run  for  the  benefit  of  their  owners,  which  is  known  as  the  theory  of  ‘shareholder  sovereignty’  or  ‘shareholder  primacy’  or  ‘shareholder  value  maximisation’  theory  of  corporate  governance  (Jenson  et  al,  1976).  As  is  explained  in  chapter  5,  at  5.5.5,  the  terminology  of  ‘ownership’,  whilst  not  technically  exact,  is  employed  throughout  this  thesis  as  useful  shorthand  for  more  readily  describing  the  relationship  whereby  companies  are  run  for  their  shareholders,  or  other  members  as  in  the  case  of  building  societies.  ‘Ownership  pressures’  refers  to  the  corporate  governance  relationship  whereby  businesses  are  expected  to  act  in  the  interests  of  their  shareholders,  and  in  other  words  being  run  with  a  view  to  making  them  capital  gains  in  financial  markets  or  indeed  paying  them  dividends.  

Page 40: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  40  

The  question  about  corporate  purpose  and  in  whose  interests  companies  should  be  managed  remained  unsettled  for  many  years  and  has  occupied  a  vast  body  of  literature  on  ‘corporate  governance’  traversing  different  fields  of  social  science,  including  law,  accountancy,  business,  economics,  politics  and  philosophy.  Shortly  before  the  GFC,  it  was  widely  considered  that  the  debate  around  corporate  purpose  had  been  settled  (Kraakman  et  al,  2000)  and  that  advocates  of  shareholder  governance  had  won:  companies  should  be  run  for  the  benefit  of  their  ‘owners’  (or  more  accurately,  their  ‘shareholders’)  in  priority  to  others.  Advocates  of  stakeholder  governance  –  who  argued  that  companies  should  it  be  run  for  a  wider  community  of  interests,  in  recognition  of  the  contribution  made  and  risk  taken  by  others  involved  in  the  success  and  operations  of  the  companies,  for  example  their  employees,  directors,  customers,  suppliers,  lenders,  the  wider  society  in  which  it  operates,  or  even  the  counter-­‐parties  with  whom  it  does  business  –  were  marginalised  by  the  political  and  economic  consensus  which  favoured  shareholder  governance  (Kraakman  et  al,  2000).    

As  we  observed  in  chapter  2,  the  official  response  to  the  banking  crisis  presumed  that  there  had  been  an  agency  failure,  and  that  it  could  be  fixed  by  further  aligning  management  duties  with  the  interests  of  shareholders.  The  UK’s  policy  response  was  for  ‘more’  corporate  governance  or  to  try  to  ‘fix’  corporate  governance  by  adding  to  the  body  of  rules  requiring  management  to  act  more  in  line  with  shareholder  interests  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p129).    The  official  response  did  not  observe  how  reinforcing  shareholder  governance  conflicted  with  the  interests  of  other  stakeholders  and  undermined  a  company’s  scope  to  act  more  broadly  in  the  interests  of  others  (Meyer,  2013,  p115;  Haldane,  2015)  nor  did  it  even  question  the  ‘ownership  paradigm’  and  in  other  words  ask  whether  it  made  sense  to  have  banks  run  primarily  for  their  shareholders.  

However,  what  appears  to  be  an  entrenched  consensus  or  paradigm  is  in  fact  a  relatively  new  development,  and  is  also  perhaps  more  susceptible  to  change  than  might  otherwise  be  suggested  by  the  assumptions  made  by  the  official  response.  What  has  become  axiomatic  today  –  that  companies  should  be  run  in  the  interest  of  their  shareholders,  and  that  management  who  do  not  maximise  shareholder  value  risk  being  removed,  or  replaced  or  the  company  taken  over  –  was  not  at  all  commonplace  at  all  in  the  mid-­‐nineteenth  century  when  corporations  were  first  bestowed  with  separate  personality  and  limited  liability  (Ireland,  2007,  p5).  As  we  shall  explore  below,  the  current  shareholder  value  or  ‘ownership  paradigm’  –  whereby  companies  are  run  for  their  shareholders,  and  vulnerable  to  take  over  if  they  do  not  deliver  sufficient  shareholder  value  –  only  really  took  root  in  mainstream  political  and  economic  thinking  in  the  latter  half  of  the  twentieth  century.    And  as  we  shall  explore  below,  it  is  also  a  paradigm  which  is  increasingly  challenged,  particularly  in  the  context  of  banking.  Indeed,  the  realisation  appears  to  be  dawning  that  shareholder  value  governance  is  causing  particularly  acute  problems  in  banking  (Mayer,  2013,  pp128-­‐129;  Haldane,  2011,  2015;  Black  et  al,  2015).      

This  chapter  considers  the  ‘corporate  governance’  literature  and  how  it  has  dealt  with  the  issue  the  thesis  seeks  to  explore  namely  how  the  way  banks  are  ‘owned’  affects  their  behaviour  (or  more  accurately,  how  the  way  banks  are  required  to  be  run  in  the  interests  of  shareholders,  or  others,  affects  their  behaviour).  The  first  part  briefly  explores  the  history  of  the  publicly  traded  form  

Page 41: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  41  

of  organisation  charting  the  creation  and  evolution  of  the  joint  stock  company,  limited  liability,  and  the  development  of  the  stock  market.  The  second  part  then  considers  the  wider  shareholder  versus  stakeholder  debate,  and  how  in  the  first  half  of  the  twentieth  century  the  debate  around  corporate  purpose  was  adverse  to  shareholder  primacy.  The  third  part  then  goes  on  to  explain  how  that  debate  was  eventually  settled  in  favour  of  shareholder  sovereignty  and  how  since  the  1960s  onwards,  the  political  and  economic  consensus  which  emerged  and  became  increasingly  entrenched  has  favoured  this  ‘shareholder  value’  or  ‘ownership’  paradigm,  effectively  treating  shareholders  as  owners  and  expecting  companies  to  be  run  for  their  benefit.    The  final  part  then  explores  the  growing  resistance  to  this  ownership  paradigm,  and  how  its  critics  have  been  given  a  new  lease  of  life.      

3.2   Part  1:  history      

3.2.1   The  birth  of  the  corporation        

The  ability  to  trade  not  in  one’s  own  name  but  in  the  name  of  another  person,  and  one  who  is  not  actually  alive  or  even  a  human  being  but  has  been  entirely  made  up  and  is  not  a  person  at  all,  is  hardly  an  obvious  or  natural  concept.  Yet,  in  the  business  world,  that  precise  device  has  become  second  nature,  and  a  way  of  life,  so  much  so  that  many  would  consider  it  their  economic  right  to  conduct  their  business  through  a  company  rather  than  any  form  of  special  privilege.  Historically  speaking,  however,  until  relatively  recently  the  ability  to  deflect  one’s  own  liability  entirely  onto  a  fictitious  person  was  not  available  as  of  right,  but  was  a  concession  and  one  only  rarely  granted  (Ireland,  2007,  p7).  Before  the  industrial  revolution,  corporate  personality  was  bestowed  on  only  a  few  bodies:  other  than  the  medieval  commerce  and  merchant  guilds,  who  were  able  to  trade  on  account  of  their  ‘joint  stock’  (hence  that  term  of  phrase),  joint  stock  companies  had  to  be  created  by  the  Crown  or  by  Parliament  and  typically  were  only  created  to  advance  foreign  trade  interests  or  in  order  to  galvanise  investments  for  large  infrastructure  projects,  such  as  canal,  rail,  dock,  bridge  and  gas  works  (Ireland,  2007,  pp4-­‐5).    

Typically,  the  early  joint  stock  companies  thus  performed  public  functions,  one  example  being  the  Bank  of  England,  which  was  set  up  in  1694  under  both  a  Royal  Charter  and  an  Act  of  Parliament  with  its  purpose  being  ‘to  promote  the  public  good  and  benefit  of  our  people’  (Haldane,  2015).    It  was  only  in  the  latter  half  of  the  nineteenth  century  when  the  companies’  acts  of  1844  to  1856  were  enacted  that  the  joint  stock  franchise  was  opened  up  for  all  sectors  and  industries.  The  origins  of  the  corporation  and  of  corporate  purpose  thus  lie  in  the  public,  and  not  the  private,  sphere.  The  modern  corporation  is  a  descendant  of  the  old  trade  and  merchant  guilds,  which  were  permitted,  often  with  monopoly  rights  to  trade  on  their  own  account  in  their  sectors  of  activity  on  the  back  of  their  members’  ‘joint  stock’  (Mayer,  2012,  p217).    

The  early  joint  stock  companies  were  also  generally  only  temporary  affairs:  their  capital  was  liquidated  and  distributed  out  to  members  after  each  voyage  or  project  completed  and  it  was  only  from  1614  onwards,  that  it  became  

Page 42: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  42  

possible  for  joint  stock  to  be  subscribed  for  a  period  of  a  year  and  only  from  1654  onwards,  that  it  became  possible  to  permanently  subscribe  capital  (Mayer,  2012,  pp215-­‐217).  After  companies  were  permitted  to  trade  in  their  own  name,  in  1658  it  then  became  possible  for  those  owning  shares  to  trade  in  those  shares  (Mayer,  2012,  p216)  -­‐  something  which  judges  were  initially  reluctant  to  allow,  for  example  in  cases  such  as  Blundell  v  Winsor  (1808)  1  Camp  547  and  R  v  Stratton  (1811)  14  East  406.  Early  joint  stock  companies  were  thus  limited  in  number,  their  shares  were  not  always  readily  transferrable,  and  they  were  not  all  given  limited  liability.  The  right  to  trade  in  a  separate  name  was  essentially  a  public  concession  involving  some  sort  of  activity  beneficial  to  the  realm.  The  South  Sea  Company,  and  the  Bank  of  England,  for  example  provided  public  financing  for  important  investments  or  for  national  expeditions  (Mayer,  2012,  p216).    

After  the  collapse  of  the  South  Sea  Company,  the  Royal  Exchange  and  London  Assurance  Corporation  Act  1719  which  has  come  to  be  known  as  ‘the  Bubble  Act’  was  passed  making  it  illegal  to  operate  joint  stock  companies  without  a  royal  charter  or  Parliamentary  enactment  (Mayer,  2012,  p215-­‐217).  The  Courts  subsequently  prosecuted  those  who  attempted  to  trade  on  joint  stock  or  to  trade  shares  (Talbot,  2013,  pp794-­‐795).  With  the  industrial  revolution  came  pressure  to  repeal  the  Bubble  Act  and  to  extend  the  corporate  franchise  (Haldane,  2015).  The  Crown  and  Parliament  were  inundated  with  applications  for  joint  stock  status,  having  already  created  all  manner  of  other  exceptions  to  the  Bubble  Act  in  order  to  galvanise  investment  for  new  business  and  infrastructure,  in  particular  the  various  Canals  Acts  which  were  passed  in  the  late  eighteenth  century,  creating  corporations  to  build  the  canals  (Mayer,  2012,  p218).  Rail,  dock,  bridge  and  other  infrastructure  projects  gave  rise  to  similar  concessions.    

To  stem  the  tide  of  applications  and  to  reduce  state  monopoly,  parliament  made  the  joint  stock  company  universally  available  (Mayer,  2012,  p218).  In  1820  the  Bubble  Act  was  repealed.  In  1826  ‘Joint  Stock’  banks  were  legalised  outside  of  London  (within  a  65  mile  radius)  and  in  1833  they  were  legalised  in  London  (Mayer,  p128).  In  1844,  Parliament  passed  an  act  permitting  the  universal  creation  of  joint  stock  companies.  The  same  act  also  removed  the  6-­‐partner  limit  on  issuing  bank  notes.  Not  all  agreed  with  the  extension  of  the  joint  stock  company.  Emphatically,  Adam  Smith  disagreed  with  the  use  of  dispersed-­‐ownership  joint  stock  companies,  believing  they  made  efficient  operations  impossible  and  that  they  should  be  reserved  only  for  capital  intensive  public  projects  (Smith,  1776,  p741;  Berle  &  Means,  1932,  p345-­‐346).  In  1776,  Adam  Smith  argued  for  a  very  limited  use  of  the  joint  stock  company:    

 ‘directors  of  [joint  stock]  companies…  being  the  managers  rather  of  other  people's  money  than  of  their  own,  it  cannot  well  be  expected  that  they  would  watch  over  it  with  the  same  anxious  vigilance  with  which  the  partners  in  a  private  co-­‐partnery  frequently  watch  over  their  own’    (Smith  (1776,  republished  1976),  p741).        With  the  extension  of  the  corporate  franchise,  the  banking  sector  changed  

from  having  a  large  number  of  small  banks  dispersed  around  the  country,  to  having  a  small  number  of  ever  larger  banks  operating  predominantly  out  of  London  (Haldane,  2015).  In  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth  century  there  were  

Page 43: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  43  

approximately  500  banks  (not  including  the  700  or  so  building  societies),  none  of  which  were  publicly  traded,  and  most  of  which  had  less  than  6  partners  to  avoid  the  prohibition  on  issuing  bank  notes  for  banks  with  more  than  6  partners.  These  banks  did  not  have  limited  liability.  By  1843,  100  banks  were  publicly  traded  (Haldane  2012).    

But  in  those  early  days,  even  with  a  joint  stock  company,  investors  could  incur  personal  liability  for  losses.  With  unlimited  liability  they  had  every  incentive  to  manage  and  control  the  banks  diligently:  shareholder  assets  were  on  the  line:  if  the  bank  made  losses,  the  shareholders  would  be  personally  liable  to  repay.  Managers  thus  had  powerful  incentives  to  be  prudent  with  depositor  money  and  they  tended  to  issue  shares  only  to  investors  with  deep  pockets  to  bear  any  losses.  Indeed,  for  this  reason,  William  Gladstone  who  headed  up  the  Treasury  Select  Committee  which  recommended  the  various  company  acts  between  1844  to  1856,  argued  in  relation  to  companies  generally  in  whichever  sector  of  activity,  that  shareholders  were  best  placed  to  govern  companies  to  protect  their  interests  against  fraud  and  misfeasance  from  those  who  managed  joint  stock  companies:  they  had  the  most  incentive  to  do  so  (see  Ireland  2010,  p.7).  Adam  Smith  had  also  recognized  the  disciplinary  effects  of  unlimited  liability.  As  well  as  opposing  the  use  of  the  company  as  a  separate  personality  (Smith,  1776,  p741)  Smith  vehemently  opposed  the  extension  of  limited  liability  to  those  owning  shares  in  companies.  As  Paddy  Ireland  observed  (2009,  p5)  Smith  argued  that  it  was  only  appropriate  to  extend  limited  liability  to  shareholders  in  special  cases,  in  particular  where  non-­‐routine  works  were  involved  which  worked  towards  delivering  an  identifiable  public  benefit,  and  only  where  there  was  unusually  high  risk  such  that  the  amounts  of  capital  required  for  investment  could  not  otherwise  be  generated  from  partnership  businesses.    

Unlimited  liability  was  not  to  last  for  long  however.  Along  with  pressures  to  extend  the  corporate  franchise,  Parliament  was  prevailed  upon  to  introduce  limited  liability  at  large.    As  Haldane  (2015)  notes,  in  the  early  19th  century  France  had  already  allowed  limited  liability  for  its  companies,  which  had  encouraged  fears  in  Britain  of  capital  flight  from  investors.  Economists,  such  as  Bagehot,  exploited  those  fears  arguing  that  unlimited  liability  also  deterred  wealthy  people  from  investing  in  Britain  (Haldane,  2015).  In  1858  and  1862,  limited  liability  was  introduced  at  large  and  by  1889,  British  banks  had  converted  from  being  mostly  unlimited,  to  being  almost  entirely  limited  liability  companies  (Haldane,  2015).  By  1913,  the  number  of  banks  had  reduced  from  more  than  500  less  than  a  hundred  years  earlier  to  only  70  (Haldane  2015).    

In  a  short  period,  banking  changed  from  being  fragmented  and  localised  to  being  highly  concentrated,  and  central  to  London.    Building  societies  followed  a  similar  trend,  declining  in  popularity,  and  making  way  for  other  forms  of  savings  institute,  particularly  fractional  reserve  banks  (Talbot,  2010).  In  1890  there  were  more  than  2000  societies;  by  1920  there  were  only  1271;  by  1950  there  were  819  societies;  and  by  1971  there  were  481  (Talbot,  2010,  p7).  The  trend  became  more  pronounced  in  the  later  half  of  the  20th  century.  Upon  being  permitted  to  float  on  the  stock  market  in  the  Big  Bang,  the  process  of  consolidation  in  the  banking  market  and  decline  of  the  building  society  sector  increased  (Talbot,  2010;  Haldane,  2015).  By  expanding  the  joint  stock  franchise  the  state  took  away  its  monopoly  on  determining  what  activities  were  fit  for  

Page 44: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  44  

being  run  by  corporations.  In  so  doing,  it  opened  the  floodgates  of  limited  liability  and  separate  legal  personality  to  all  manner  of  economic  activity  subverting  what  was  essentially  once  a  public  institution,  for  private  use.        

3.2.2     The  rise  of  the  stock  market    

The  rise  of  the  stock  market  was  an  unplanned  consequence  of  extending  the  corporate  franchise  with  limited  liability  (Fergurson,  2008,  ch.2).  After  shares  were  recognised  as  legal  property  capable  of  being  bought  and  sold,  the  stock  market  was  permitted  to  come  into  its  own.  It  is  commonly  thought  that  its  birth  was  not  the  product  of  intelligent  design  or  careful  planning,  but  was  an  unintended  and  spontaneous  reaction  to  the  creation  of  the  company,  with  its  tradable  intangible  shares  (Ferguson,  2008,  ch.2).  As  the  stock  market  grew,  shareholders  had  less  incentive  to  take  an  interest  in  the  company  they  notionally  ‘owned’  and  became  more  interested  in  their  ability  to  trade  shares  for  a  short  term  profit.  With  limited  liability,  they  had  zero  liability  for  company  losses.  If  the  company’s  share  value  fell,  shareholders  could  readily  cut  their  losses,  sell  their  shares  and  invest  their  capital  elsewhere.    Whilst  such  capital  flight  materialises  immediate  losses,  it  might  prove  significantly  less  costly  and  more  straightforward  than  having  to  police  against  mis-­‐management  and  discover  the  cause  for  poor  performing  share  value  and  then  having  to  exercise  control  rights  and  exert  sufficient  influence  over  management  to  govern  the  company  into  implementing  appropriate  corrective  measures  to  improve  share  value.  Conversely,  if  share  value  increased,  shareholders  could  capitalise  on  any  gains  quickly  by  selling  their  shares  and  even  if  they  retained  them,  they  had  little  incentive  to  investigate  the  soundness  of  the  business  operations  as  there  is  no  need  to  fix  something  which  is  working.    Whilst  management  was  expected  to  act  in  the  interests  of  shareholders,  shareholders  were  thus  incentivised  to  care  less  for  the  company’s  long-­‐term  success.    

As  trading  on  the  stock  market  grew,  the  ownership  of  public  companies  became  increasingly  ‘disinterested’  in  the  long  term  and  more  interested  in  short  term  trading  (Ireland,  2010;  Mayer,  2012).  Shareholding  became  more  dispersed  and  removed  from  the  company  as  intermediary  trading  and  investment  funds  got  in  on  the  action  (Kay,  2012).  Whilst  individuals  owned  roughly  half  of  the  traded  companies  in  the  UK  in  the  1960s  by  2010  they  owned  near  to  10%  (see  Table  3.1  below).    Direct  institutional  shareholding  also  declined.  Whereas  pension  funds  used  to  own  a  large  proportion  of  shares,  their  stake  is  now  dwarfed  by  comparison  to  intermediary  trading  and  investment  funds  (see  Table  3.1).  In  1990,  pension  funds  used  to  own  roughly  half  of  the  traded  shares  in  the  UK  yet  by  2010,  they  owned  as  little  as  15%.  The  time  horizon  for  shareholding  also  decreased  (Kay,  2012,  ch.2).  Average  shareholding  fell  from  6  years  in  the  1950s  to  less  than  6  months  in  2012  (Haldane,  2011).                

Page 45: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  45  

Table 3.1: Historical Trends in Beneficial Ownership by % (snapshots between 1963 and 2010)

(Source:  The  Kay  Review  of  UK  Equity  Markets  and  Long-­‐term  Decision  Making,  Final  Report,  p  31,  citing  data  collated  from  the  Office  of  National  Statistics)    Historical  Trends  in  Beneficial  Ownership  (Percentage  Held)     1963   1975     1981    1991  2001    2008  2010    

Rest  of  the  world     7     5.6     3.6     12.8    35.7    41.5    41.2    Insurance  companies     10   15.9     20.5    20.8    20     13.4    8.6    Pension  funds     6.4     16.8     26.7    31.3    16.1    12.8    5.1    Individuals     54     37.5     28.2    19.9    14.8    10.2    11.5    Other     22.6     24.2     21     15.2    13.4    22.1    33.6    

3.3   Part  2:  Defining  corporate  purpose    

With  the  ownership  of  companies  becoming  increasingly  dispersed,  disinterested  and  short  term  (Mayer,  2012;  Haldane,  2011;  Ireland,  2010),  the  logic  of  having  companies  run  solely  for  their  shareholders  began  to  be  questioned  and  by  an  array  of  academics,  commentators  and  policymakers,  who  throughout  the  course  of  the  twentieth  century  and  in  diverse  fields  of  social  science  variously  questioned  and  criticized  shareholder  sovereignty,  arguing  that  running  companies  for  the  benefit  of  shareholders  encouraged  unsafe  and  reckless  behaviours.    Following  the  last  depression,  for  example,  in  a  widely  publicised  work  entitled  ‘The  modern  corporation  and  private  property’  Berle  and  Means  (1932,  republished  1968),  observed  the  danger  of  management  running  companies  in  the  interests  of  shareholders  as  such  prioritisation  essentially  benefitted  investment  banks,  who  facilitated  much  of  the  short  term  trade  in  shares  on  the  stock  market.    

Berle  and  Means  (1932)  argued  that  companies  were  not  actually  ‘owned’  by  their  shareholders,  but  were  separate  entities  pursuing  a  community  of  interests  and  they  suggested  that  companies  should  not  be  conceived  of  as  private  property  owned  by  their  shareholders  and  it  was  wrong  to  think  of  the  company  as  capable  of  being  repackaged  into  parcels  of  intangible  property  which  could  simply  be  owned  and  traded  (Berle  et  al,  1932).  They  instead  postulated  a  different  conception  of  the  company  entity  and  one  which  better  reflected  the  community  of  individuals  contributing  to  its  overall  wealth  and  success.  Berle  (1954),  in  particular,  saw  directors  as  ‘administrators  of  a  community  system’,  and  not  merely  as  fiduciaries  that  acted  for  shareholders.  In  his  conception,  a  company  was  more  than  a  private  affair  but  some  form  of  community  institution  (Berle  et  al,  1932;  Berle  1954).  

This  ‘communitarian’  or  ‘stakeholder’  conception  gained  wide  support  in  the  early  part  of  the  twentieth  century.  In  the  USA,  Dodd  (1932)  advocated  that  directors  should  owe  duties  not  only  to  shareholders  but  also  to  employees,  consumers  and  society  as  a  whole.  And  at  the  end  of  the  20th  century,  Porter  (1992)  and  Blair  (1995)  continued  to  argue  that  companies  are  made  up  of  a  community  of  human  stakeholders,  and  that  they  ought  accordingly  to  be  run  in  the  interests  of  the  wider  set  of  stakeholders  who  also  contributed  to  generating  

Page 46: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  46  

profits.  Blair  (1995)  argued  that  we  needed  to  devise  a  system  of  compensation  for  wider  firm-­‐specific  contributions  beyond  those  made  by  shareholders.    

The  logic  of  shareholder  value  governance  was  thus  by  no  means  universally  accepted,  and  communitarian  or  stakeholder  ideas  of  governance  gained  support  in  the  UK  as  well  as  in  the  USA.  Parkinson  (1993)  and  John  Kay  (1995)  were  critical  of  companies  subordinating  the  interests  of  stakeholders  such  as  employees,  the  local  community,  and  company  creditors  to  the  short-­‐term  interests  of  shareholders,  particularly  where  the  same  could  harm  the  long-­‐term  interests  of  the  company.  They  advocated  for  a  ‘stakeholder’  system  of  governance,  whereby  companies  would  consider  all  of  their  stakeholders'  interests.    And  more  recently,  Mayer  (2013,  pp111-­‐115,  144)  very  forcefully  criticised  the  shareholder  value  governance  model  for  encouraging  an  extraction  of  value  from  the  company  for  the  benefit  of  shareholders  and  at  the  expense  of  other  creditors  and  stakeholders.  In  pursuing  shareholder  value  governance,  the  corporation  places  the  stakes  of  other  parties,  who  also  invest  in  and  contribute  to  the  corporation  at  risk  in  order  to  extract  returns  on  their  equity,  creating  what  Haldane  called  frictions  and  tensions  (Haldane,  2015;  Haldane,  2011).    

These  criticisms  are  by  no  means  new  developments.  As  Paddy  Ireland  observed  (2009,  p14)  in  the  inter-­‐war  years,  Keynes  (1936,  chapters  12  and  24)  was  critical  of  social  interests  being  subordinated  to  shareholder  interests.  Whilst  shareholder  value  and  productivity  might  sometimes  coincide  with  these  broader  public  aims,  Keynes  observed  that  there  was  :  

 ‘no  clear  evidence  from  experience  that  the  investment  policy  which  is  socially  advantageous  coincides  with  that  which  is  most  profitable’    (Ireland  2009,  p14,  citing  Keynes,  1936).        Keynes’  objection  was  that  prioritising  shareholders  could  undermine  

other  corporate  purposes,  such  as  promoting  a  sound  long  term  business,  meeting  the  needs  and  interests  of  customers  and  society  and  keeping  employees  in  jobs.    Keynes  (1936,  chapters  12  and  24)  observed  how  the  value  of  shares  was  not  an  accurate  reflection  of  the  soundness  of  a  company's  underlying  business.  Market  value  often  differed  from  a  company’s  book  value.  Although  share  value  is  a  specific  measure,  it  is  determined  by  competition  and  trading  in  a  parallel  market,  according  to  the  interests  and  beliefs  of  persons  generally  far  removed  from  the  company  who  do  not  necessarily  have  much  knowledge  at  all  about  its  underlying  fundamentals.  Shareholders  are  typically  ‘in’  the  stockmarket,  not  ‘in’  the  company,  to  make  money.    Keynes  famously  likened  share  value  to  a  beauty  contest:  the  judges  chose  the  value  of  contestants  not  by  considering  the  model's  intrinsic  beauty  but  by  thinking  about  how  others  may  view  the  model's  beauty,  and  often  based  on  speculation  or  hearsay  about  what  others  like  and  how  they  appreciate  beauty.      

Even  before  Keynes,  Veblen  (1904)  described  a  disconnect  between  what  is  good  for  shareholders  and  what  is  good  for  society  and  the  wider  community  of  stakeholders.  He  warned  of  a  depletion  of  productive  resources,  with  management  putting  otherwise  what  could  be  useful  capital  at  risk  or  applying  it  in  ways  aimed  to  keep  shareholders  happy  and  not  to  achieve  productivity  (Veblen,  1904).    He  witnessed  that  management,  in  order  to  satisfy  short  term  shareholder  demands,  had  incentives  to  cut  costs  to  the  detriment  of  the  long  term  viability  of  the  business  often  disinvesting  the  business  of  valuable  assets.    

Page 47: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  47  

Froud  et  al  (2006)  also  observed  this  phenomenon  of  ‘hollowing  out’  of  businesses,  observing  in  the  case  of  GM  Motors  the  phenomenon  of  value  transfer,  whereby  management  effectively  exploit  other  creditors  for  the  benefit  of  shareholders.  And  in  the  case  of  banking,  Engelen  et  al  (2011)  observed  how  shareholder  value  banking  provides  incentives  for  management  to  borrow  significant  amounts  from  creditors,  to  leverage  the  balance  sheet  in  risky  and  potentially  unsustainable  ways  (Engelen  et  al,  2011,  pp158-­‐172).  In  more  colourful  language,  the  former  member  of  the  Independent  Commission  on  Banking,  Martin  Wolf  (2012)  likened  the  process  of  dis-­‐investment  caused  by  shareholder  value  governance  to  ‘the  larva  of  a  spider  wasp  eating  out  its  host’.  Jenson  et  al  (1976)  described  the  process  whereby  management  increases  company  risk  in  a  manner  which  transfers  value  to  shareholders  as  ‘risk  shifting’.  They  criticised  the  corporate  governance  bias  towards  shareholders  over  other  debt  holders  observing  that  where  a  company  relies  on  debt,  shareholders  stand  to  gain  far  more  than  debt-­‐holders  by  the  company  pursuing  high  risk  strategies  because  they  have  zero  downside  risk  whilst  having  potentially  unlimited  upside  gains  (Jensen  et  al,  1976).  In  other  words,  shareholders  have  more  to  win  from  successful  risk-­‐taking  and  less  to  lose  from  unsuccessful  risk-­‐taking  encouraging  companies  to  become  what  Haldane  later  called  ‘volatility  junkies’  (Haldane,  2011).    

Others  have  criticized  shareholder  value  governance  for  providing  incentives  for  management  to  not  only  cut  costs  but  to  perform  macquillage,  to  make  companies  look  a  lot  more  attractive  than  they  really  are  by  constructing  exaggerated  narratives  to  manipulate  investor  perceptions  to  keep  share  value  high  (Kelly,  2003).    Shareholder  value  governance  is  also  criticised  for  enhancing  inequalities.  There  is  a  significant  body  of  recent  literature  documenting  the  contribution  of  shareholder  value  governance  towards  inequality.  Saez  (2003,  p32)  for  example  argues  that  the  ‘working  rich’  have  now  replaced  individual  investors  at  the  top  of  the  income  distribution  chain  in  the  United  States  getting  richer  whilst  other  labour  is  becoming  more  impoverished  –  a  trend  which  Piketty  (2014)  agrees  manifests  itself  across  capitalist  democracies  (Piketty,  2014).  The  proceeds  of  commerce,  it  is  suggested,  are  being  redistributed  away  from  labour  and  into  financial  capital  causing  increasing  inequalities  in  income  (Ireland,  2009;  Piketty,  2014).    

Shareholders  have  benefited  from  this  new  class  of  elite  ‘working  rich’,  who  also  reap  the  rewards  of  helping  shareholders  in  what  has  been  called  an  ‘unholy  alliance’  of  interests  between  the  working  rich  and  the  ‘rentier’  class  or  owners  (Ha  Joon  Chang,  2011,  pp11-­‐23)  which  favours  capital  over  labour  and  exacerbates  income  inequalities  (Piketty,  2014;  Dumeril  and  Levy,  2004).  In  Marxist  terms,  ‘the  capitalist  class’  has  expanded  to  include  elite  management  or  it  has  formed  an  alliance  with  it  and  the  elite  management  no  longer  represent  the  workers  but  have  betrayed  the  ‘labour  class’  ;  provided  management  continues  the  extraction  of  value  for  owners,  this  class  of  ‘working  rich’  are  welcome  to  join  in  the  riches  of  the  capitalist  classes  (Ireland,  2009).      

Ireland  (2009)  argues  that  it  is  no  accident  that  the  shareholder  value  model  has  come  to  serve  the  interests  of  a  new  wealthy  elite.  He  argues  that  the  shareholder  value  model  ‘is  not  an  efficient  arrangement,  but  rather  a  power  relationship  that  is  a  particular  (societal)  way  to  design  a  corporation’  (Ireland:  2009,  p.4).  Whilst  shareholder  value  governance  is  dressed  up  as  an  obvious,  

Page 48: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  48  

logical,  even  an  inevitable  arrangement,  it  is,  says  Ireland  a  political  compromise  which  favours  the  investor  and  his  agent:  ‘Elite  power  has  been  dressed  up  as  efficiency’  (2009,  p.28).  The  shareholder  value  model  is  a  product,  not  of  intelligent  design,  but  of  economic  power  (Ireland,  2009,  p.4).  Haldane  (2015)  seemed  to  agree  with  that  analysis  by  recognising  that  companies  are  mere  ‘social  constructs’  and  how  they  are  owned  and  run  is  not  inevitable,  but  a  political  decision,  and  one  which  can  be  changed.    

The  shareholder  value  model  has  also  been  critiqued  for  being  based  on  false  principles.  As  Haldane  observed  in  the  opening  passage  at  the  start  of  this  chapter,  the  belief  that  companies  are  ‘owned’  by  their  shareholders  is  not  correct.  It  is  not  possible  for  anybody  to  own  a  company,  which  is  its  own  person  (Kelly,  2003).  The  question  which  instead  needs  to  be  asked  is  what  do  shareholders  deserve,  bearing  in  mind  the  amount  of  their  contribution  and  the  risks  they  take.    As  Haldane  (2011)  and  Kelly  (2003)  point  out  the  contribution  made  by  shareholders  can  be  extremely  limited  whilst  their  right  to  have  companies  run  for  their  benefit  can  be  unlimited.  Shareholders  also  have  diversifiable  risk,  which  calls  into  question  the  logic  of  rewarding  shareholders  above  all  others,  especially  those  who  cannot  diversify  their  risk:  unlike  employees  whose  contribution  is  tied  to  the  company,  shareholders  can  diversify  their  risk  by  investing  elsewhere  (Haldane,  2015).      

That  is  not  to  say  that  shareholders  do  not  make  any  contribution.  They  undoubtedly  bear  considerable  risks:  as  Ferguson  points  out,  one  in  ten  publicly  traded  companies  in  the  USA  disappears  each  year,  and  most  firms  eventually  fail:  of  the  100  largest  companies  trading  in  1912,  29  were  bankrupt  by  1995,  48  had  disappeared  and  only  19  were  still  in  the  top  100  and  in  the  UK,  30%  of  tax  registered  businesses  disappear  after  three  years  (2008,  p350).  Clearly  shareholders  risk  their  investment,  and  provide  direct  investment  upon  subscribing  their  shares.    

In  many  industries,  however,  shareholders  are  not  the  main  risk-­‐takers  and  they  contribute  far  less  in  terms  of  risk  and  even  financial  investment  than  others.  It  is  argued  therefore,  for  example  by  Blair  (1995),  that  the  contribution  made  by  shareholders  does  not  justify  companies  being  run  exclusively  in  their  interests,  often  at  the  expense  of  other  (sometimes  more  significant)  contributors  and  risk-­‐takers.  Shareholders  are  not  the  only  parties  with  firm-­‐specific  contributions  and  which  stand  to  lose  in  the  event  of  failure;  at  any  one  time,  there  will  be  a  number  of  employees,  suppliers,  and  customers  who  have  all  contributed  to  a  company’s  success  and  who  will  stand  to  lose  in  the  event  of  failure.  If  shareholders  do  not  stand  to  lose  the  most  if  the  company  fails,  why  is  it,  Blair  asks  rhetorically,  are  they  entitled  to  have  the  company  run  almost  exclusively  in  their  interests?    

Shares  furthermore  retain  potentially  perpetual  (and  unlimited)  rights  to  extract  profits  from  the  company  in  the  future.  The  time  horizons  for  those  privileges  may  bear  no  correlation  at  all  to  the  direct  contribution  initially  made  to  the  company.  A  shareholder’s  right  to  extract  wealth  from  a  company  lasts  forever,  whereas  their  contribution  is  often  limited  in  both  time  and  amount.  According  to  Veblen  (1923,  republished  1945)  and  Tawney  (1921),  share  ownership  does  not  lead  to  productivity.  It  contributes  little,  if  anything,  to  the  actual  assets  of  the  company.  The  vast  majority  of  shares  are  generally  bought  in  the  stock  market  from  other  shareholders,  and  not  upon  company  offering.  They  

Page 49: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  49  

are  second  hand,  third  hand  or  might  be  ten-­‐thousandth  hand  and  any  investment  made  by  later  shareholders  goes  to  the  benefit  of  previous  owners  and  is  not  any  direct  contribution  made  towards  the  company.    

Whilst  the  trading  in  shares  might  have  indirect  benefits  for  a  company  such  as  maintaining  a  high  share  price,  thus  promoting  its  brand  and  reputation,  and  enabling  it  to  raise  other  finance,  after  the  initial  subscription,  secondary  trading  in  shares  provides  no  direct  contributions,  leading  some  to  suggest  it  is  analogous  to  the  contribution  a  man  makes  to  a  motor  company  by  buying  a  twenty  year  old  car  from  a  second  hand  car  dealer  (Kelly,  2003).    

Kelly  (2003)  compares  the  unlimited  extractive  rights  to  the  rights  of  the  aristocracy  under  a  feudal  system.  Aristocrats  generally  inherit  all  of  their  privileges  as  a  result  of  some  ancient  predecessor  having  made  a  contribution  to  the  Crown  in  centuries  gone  by.  Their  contribution  is  historical  whilst  their  extractive  rights  are  perpetual.  Keynes  (1936)  described  this  historical  contribution  as  being  ‘functionless’  (Ireland,  2009,  p.9),  and  Tawney  (1921)  goes  so  far  as  to  call  it  positively  ‘parasitic’:  future  shareholders  take  all  of  the  profits  without  providing  any  contribution;  they  retain  rights  of  extraction  despite  owing  no  responsibilities  to  the  company  and  making  no  on-­‐going  contributions.  After  their  initial  offering,  they  are  simply  takers.  Similarly,  for  Tawney  (1921)  shareholders  ought  instead  to  be  treated  like  secured  creditors,  rather  than  proprietors.      

3.4   Part  3:  the  emerging  shareholder  value  paradigm      

Notwithstanding  the  body  of  intellectuals  who  argued  for  a  stakeholder  conception  of  corporate  purpose,  the  political-­‐economic  consensus  which  emerged  at  the  end  of  the  20th  century  very  much  supported  the  agency  view  of  the  company,  that  is  to  say  that  the  company  is  owned  by  its  shareholder;  and  the  obvious  corollary  was  that  the  company  should  be  run  in  the  interest  of  such  ‘owners’  (Friedman,  1970,  p54;  Hansmann  et  al,  2001).  Indeed,  this  conception  of  corporate  purpose  has  not  only  become  most  popular  but  has  become  enshrined  legally,  and  subsequently  reinforced  by  economic  forces  and  political  trends,  particularly  those  emerging  from  the  1960s  onwards,  as  neoliberalism  came  to  dominate  political  and  economic  life  (Ireland,  2009).  In  1962,  when  Friedman  argued  that  the  company  was  an  ‘instrument  of  the  shareholders  who  own  it’  (the  agency  theory)  (Friedman,  1962,  p.135)  and  that  the  role  of  the  company’s  management  was  to  keep  the  share  price  high  for  the  shareholder  (the  shareholder  value  theory)  (Friedman,  1962,  p133)  he  did  so  against  a  body  of  academics  who  favoured  the  stakeholder  conceptions  of  corporate  purpose  (Ireland,  2009).      

Nevertheless,  the  agency  theory  and  the  shareholder  value  theory  soon  became  mainstream  orthodoxy,  encouraged  by  advocates  of  the  efficient  market  theory  who  sought  to  justify  shareholder  value  governance  not  as  a  matter  of  ownership  rights  and  property  law,  but  as  a  matter  of  economic  efficiency.  The  efficient  market  or  efficient  allocation  theory  of  finance  posited  that  in  perfect  financial  markets,  the  share  price  of  a  company  would  reflect  its  underlying  profitability,  leading  to  an  efficient  allocation  of  society's  resources  through  the  instrument  of  financial  markets  (Turner,  2016,  pp37-­‐38).  In  efficient  markets,  

Page 50: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  50  

companies  need  not  worry  about  how  to  serve  their  multiple  stakeholders,  and  can  instead  focus  exclusively  on  maximising  returns  for  their  owners.  Indeed,  in  order  to  help  make  markets  efficient  to  gain  access  to  the  capital  they  need  to  survive  and  thrive,  it  was  argued  that,  companies  should  focus  only  on  their  owners.  As  Friedman  famously  put  it:  

 [T]here  is  one  and  only  one  social  responsibility  of  business  -­‐-­‐  to  use  its  resources  and  engage  in  activities  designed  to  increase  its  profits  so  long  as  it  stays  within  the  rules  of  the  game,  which  is  to  say,  engages  in  open  and  free  competition  without  deception  or  fraud.    (Friedman,  1970,  p54)      

Provided  that  markets  within  which  companies  operate  are  themselves  competitive  and  companies  governed  to  perform  optimally  for  the  benefit  of  their  owners,  the  value  of  their  shareholding  should  reflect  the  soundness  of  the  business  and  capital  markets  could  efficiently  allocate  resources  where  justified  (Turner,  2016,  pp37-­‐38).  

   This  ideology  provided  businessmen,  economists  and  politicians  with  a  complete  scheme  with  which  they  could  view,  debate  and  plan  the  political  economy.  Owing  to  economic  successes  in  the  UK  and  USA  particularly  in  the  early  1990s,  the  agency  and  shareholder  value  conceptions  of  corporate  purpose,  which  were  central  to  this  efficient  market  hypothesis,  were  increasingly  viewed  as  inevitable  or  logical  or  even  productively  superior  (Hansmann  et  al,  2002;  Haldane,  2015).    

This  hypothesis  quickly  became  widespread  not  only  within  neoliberal  political  orders  in  the  west  but  also  within  economies  touched  and  concerned  by  them,  because  the  World  Bank,  the  Organisation  for  Economic  Cooperation  and  Development,  the  European  Union  and  the  Washington  Consensus  all  tended  to  advocate  for  the  expansion  of  capital  markets  with  competition  policy  as  a  means  of  encouraging  efficient  markets  and  companies  having  access  to  capital  and  governed  by  shareholder  value  (Turner,  2016,  pp136,  141,  143,  150).    

A  wider  ideological  consensus  began  to  emerge  particularly  in  countries  dominated  by  neo-­‐liberalism  supportive  of  the  idea  that  companies  should  be  run  for  their  owners  (Ireland,  2009).  Proponents  of  stakeholder  governance  were  increasingly  marginalised,  in  the  face  of  an  increasingly  popular  shareholder  value  ideology.  Jenson,  who  had  previously  criticised  the  corporate  governance  bias  towards  shareholders  (1976),  began  to  advocate  for  a  longer  term  form  of  shareholder  governance,  arguing  that  it  was  impossibly  difficult  for  management  to  maximize  returns  in  more  than  one  dimension,  and  that  purposeful  behaviour  required  them  to  pursue  a  single-­‐valued  objective,  which  stakeholder  governance  failed  to  provide  (2001).    Even  Hansmann,  who  had  been  a  strong  advocate  for  non-­‐profits  in  particular  (1980,  1981,  1988)  famously  declared  that  it  was  ‘The  end  of  history  for  corporate  law’  (Kraakman  et  al,  2000).  Just  a  few  years  before  the  financial  crisis,  Hansmann  and  Kraakman  argued  not  only  that  that  the  shareholder  value  model  of  corporate  governance  had  won  out  over  any  other  model  but  also  that  it  was  productively  superior.    

Other  economic  forces,  and  particularly  the  growing  market  for  corporate  control,  reinforced  shareholder  value  governance.  Since  share  value  can  directly  affect  a  company’s  ability  to  raise  capital  in  financial  markets,  there  are  incentives  for  management  to  enhance  its  value.  If  share  value  is  not  as  high  as  it  

Page 51: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  51  

can  be,  a  company  prejudices  its  ability  not  only  to  raise  finance  but  also  risks  being  taken  over  by  outsiders  who  can  promise  shareholders  they  will  make  them  more  money.    

The  rise  of  the  takeover  and  leveraged  buyout  market  inevitably  have  added  pressures  on  management  to  cut  costs,  to  undertake  restructuring  and  to  take  other,  sometimes  radical,  measures  to  sustain  and  improve  share  value  (Glynn,  2006,  p.58).    Since  the  early  1980s,  the  number  of  hostile  takeovers,  particularly  in  the  US  and  the  UK,  has  risen  dramatically.  In  1990,  for  example,  in  the  US,  one  third  of  the  Fortune  500  companies  were  targeted  for  hostile  takeovers  (Kelly,  2001,  p.55  citing  Whitman,  1999).  And  in  the  UK,  some  four-­‐fifths  of  equity  capital  is  thought  to  be  directed  not  to  new  investment  in  companies  but  into  taking  over  existing  companies  (Mayer,  2012,  p138).    

Whereas  subscribing  shares  was  initially  concerned  with  providing  capital  for  a  company,  the  trend  in  the  last  century  has  been  to  shift  focus  away  from  productivity  and  towards  buy-­‐outs.  Mayer  cites  a  prime  example  (2013,  pp132-­‐135).  The  company  that  was  to  become  3i  namely  the  Industrial  and  Commercial  Financial  Corporation  (ICFC)  was  set  up  following  the  war  in  1945  as  ‘a  company  to  devote  itself  particularly  to  the  smaller  industrial  and  commercial  issue’  namely  to  plug  the  ‘Macmillan  gap’  and  shortfall  in  investment  from  banks  and  the  stock  market  (Mayer,  2013,  p133).  The  Bank  of  England  and  the  main  clearing  banks  subscribed  capital  and  became  its  shareholders.  The  capital  was  to  be  used  to  provide  productive  investment.  Whilst  it  was  successful  in  discharging  its  aims  and  investing  in  small  businesses,  it  was  nevertheless  floated  in  1994.  The  BoE  and  clearing  banks  sold  their  shares  on  the  stock  market  and  with  new  ownership,  it  subsequently  changed  its  operations  from  investing  in  SMEs  into  buying  out  other  companies.  To  satisfy  the  extractive  demands  of  its  owners,  3i  subverted  its  productive  investment  function  and  like  most  private  equity  businesses,  focused  instead  not  on  starting  up  new  businesses  but  funding  the  hostile  takeover  of  existing  business,  which  encouraged  management  to  commit  themselves  to  enhancing  share  value,  or  risk  compromising  their  ability  to  raise  finance,  or  being  taken  over  by  others.        

Rightly  or  wrongly  (and  many  commentators,  such  as  Attenborough  (2009),  argue  wrongly)  the  law  in  England  and  Wales  also  developed  to  explicitly  support  the  agency  and  shareholder  value  conceptions  of  corporate  governance.  Directors  of  a  company  are  now  under  a  legal  duty  to  act  in  the  interests  of  the  shareholders.  Indeed  section  172  of  the  Companies  Act  2006  provides  shareholders  with  a  right  to  take  directors  to  court  if  they  fail  to  so  act.  Whilst  directors  can  take  into  account  other  considerations  such  as  the  long  term  interests  of  the  company,  the  effect  of  any  decision  on  employees,  or  creditors  or  the  local  communities,  those  other  considerations  are  secondary  and  subsidiary  to  shareholder  interests:  insofar  as  they  conflict,  the  duties  owed  to  shareholders  should  prevail.  As  well  as  being  able  to  take  directors  to  court  shareholders  have  other  rights  to  ensure  their  interests  are  prioritised:  they  can  appoint  and  remove  directors  (see  ss154-­‐169,  Companies  Act  2006),  change  the  company  objects  and  decide  what  business  the  company  will  transact  (s21a,  Companies  Act  2006),  or  adjust  the  company's  capital  structure  (ss641  and  716,  Companies  Act  2006),  or  agree  to  a  management  takeover  or  even  to  dissolve  the  company  (see  ss21a,  154-­‐169,  641,  716  of  the  Companies  Act  2006,  and  the  EU  Directive  on  Takeovers  (2004/25/EC).  Thus  the  law,  and  not  only  economic  forces  and  

Page 52: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  52  

political  trends  have  all  lent  support  to  the  shareholder  value  conception  of  corporate  purpose.  It  is  not  entirely  surprising  therefore  that  the  government’s  response  to  the  GFC  did  not  begin  by  questioning  whether  the  orthodox  position  was  problematic.    

3.4.1   Entrenching  the  paradigm    The  entire  debate  about  whether  banks  should  be  run  in  the  interest  of  

their  shareholder  ‘owners’  was  avoided  by  the  ‘official  response’  which  as  we  saw  in  chapter  2,  was  concerned  to  preserve  the  status  quo  by  making  ameliorative,  rather  than  radical,  proposals  for  reforming  how  banks  are  owned  and  ran.  The  official  response  essentially  called  for  more  ‘corporate  governance’  rather  than  to  question  the  paradigm,  which  thus  re-­‐asserted  the  ownership  claims  of  shareholders  and  sought  to  further  empower  shareholders  as  stewards  (Talbot,  2013;  Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p129).    

The  official  response,  epitomized  by  the  Walker  Review,  blamed  inadequate  corporate  governance,  and  in  particular  an  agency  gap,  whilst  advocating  for  more  of  the  same  soft  law  governance  regime  aimed  at  narrowing  the  agency  gap  that  had  already  failed.  Although  Walker  sought  to  differentiate  between  ‘Banks  and  Other  Financial  Intermediaries’  and  other  listed  companies  by  seeking  to  add  to  the  body  of  soft  law  regulating  financial  institutions  (Walker,  2009),  such  differentiation  should  not  be  over-­‐stated.  The  UK  Combined  Corporate  Governance  Code  after  all  is  still  essentially  an  advisory  regime,  and  one  which  still  expects  all  companies  in  the  UK  to  act  primarily  in  the  interests  of  their  shareholders,  whose  interests  are  often  prone  to  being  short-­‐sighted.    Banks  may  well  be  subject  to  additional  corporate  governance  requirements,  as  well  as  other  forms  of  regulation  imposed  either  domestically  by  legislation  such  as  the  Financial  Services  and  Markets  Act  2000  or  by  international  treaty  such  as  Basel  III,  which  regulates  capital  quality  and  adequacy.    Nevertheless,  like  any  publicly  limited  companies  in  any  other  sector,  in  the  UK,  banks  are  all  expected  to  deliver  shareholder  value.  As  Froud  et  al  (2009,  p40)  observe,  the  stockmarket  does  not  differentiate  between  companies  acting  in  different  sectors.  They  are  all  on  the  stockmarket  and  subject  to  meeting  its  demands.  If  they  cannot  meet  the  stockmarket’s  demands  for  shareholder  value,  they  should  leave  (2009,  p40).    

Furthermore,  as  has  been  widely  observed  banking  regulation,  like  the  regulation  of  other  sectors,  also  subscribed  to  the  ideology  of  efficient  markets  believing  that  being  efficient  financial  markets  would  correct  themselves  and  could  be  governed  adequately  by  competition  law  without  the  need  for  significant  state  regulation  and  supervision  of  economic  activity  (Engelen  et  al.  2011;  Bowman  et  al  2014,  ch.1;  Turner,  2016,  ch.2;  King  2016,  ch.1).  

The  official  response  thus  did  not  mark  out  banks  for  a  different  type  of  corporate  governance  treatment.  As  was  clarified  by  Walker  it  wholeheartedly  embraced  the  agency  and  shareholder  value  models  of  corporate  governance  (Walker,  2009,  p23,  para.1.1).  It  simply  sought  to  narrow  the  agency  gap  and  to  broader  shareholders’  time  horizons.  Institutional  shareholders  were  encouraged  to  engage  more  actively  as  stewards  (Kay,  2012)  and  modest  steps  were  taken  to  ensure  banks  vet  the  competence  of  senior  management  and  

Page 53: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  53  

further  checks  were  proposed  for  approving  the  ‘compensation’  of  senior  management  (PCBS,  2013a,  ‘conclusions  and  recommendations’;  PCBS,  2013b,  p155).  In  short,  these  reforms  overlooked  and  ignored  the  ‘communitarian’  and  ‘stakeholder’  ideas  about  governance  and  pre-­‐supposed  that  banks  should  continue  to  be  run  in  the  interest  of  shareholders.      

3.5     Part  4:  the  back-­‐lash,  and  rise  of  stakeholder  theory        

More  recently,  a  growing  body  of  intellectuals  have  become  highly  critical  of  shareholder  value  governance  in  the  context  of  banking  and  more  willing  to  question  the  sense  in  having  banks  owned  for  shareholder  value,  arguing  that  this  ownership  model  negatively  affects  how  banks  behave,  making  them  more  prone  to  misbehave  and  to  adopt  excessive  risks,  to  pump  out  too  much  credit  and  to  become  difficult  for  society  to  trust  (Haldane  2012,  2015;  Brummer,  2015,  p144;  Wolf,  2014c,  chs6-­‐7;  Black  et  al,  2015;  Turner,  2016,  pp172-­‐174,  245-­‐246).    

Before  the  crisis,  commentators  on  corporate  governance  tended  to  view  corporate  purpose  and  governance  issues  on  an  abstract  plain  removed  from  the  specific  nature,  and  context  of  the  banking  market.  They  tended  to  advocate  for  a  universal  system  of  governance  applicable  across  all  sectors  and  activities  (Mayer  2013,  p190).  There  were  a  few  exceptions.  Adams  and  Mehran  (2003)  for  example  argued  that  there  was  a  difference  between  the  governance  of  banks  and  non-­‐financial  firms  and  Macey  et  al  (2003)  observed  how  the  state  is  a  large  stakeholder  in  the  governance  of  banks  by  virtue  of  subsidising  banks.  They  suggested  that  the  directors  of  banks  should  be  subject  to  special  fiduciary  duties  to  ensure  the  on-­‐going  soundness  and  solvency  of  their  business  and  not  merely  that  things  are  run  for  the  shareholders  (Macey  et  al,  2003).  These  critiques  were  however  in  the  minority  and  the  majority  of  corporate  governance  commentators  treated  all  sectors  the  same.    

There  are  however  a  number  of  obvious  differences  between  banks  and  non-­‐financial  firms  which  are  relevant  to  the  issue  about  how  they  are  owned  and  in  whose  interests  they  should  be  ran.    The  biggest  difference  is  perhaps  that  banks  are  granted  privileges  by  the  state  to  perform  functions  which  are  at  least  partly  public  in  nature.  As  is  explored  in  the  next  chapter  at  4.2.1,  banks  do  not  merely  redistribute  the  existing  money  supply,  but  in  fact  create  colossal  amounts  of  credit.  By  doing  so  they  extend  the  existing  money  supply.  The  state’s  ability  to  honour  its  promise  to  pay  the  bearer  of  any  bank  note  a  certain  sum  in  value  is  thus  directly  affected  and  can  be  undermined  by  banks  extending  the  supply  of  money.  Since  they  are  bestowed  with  such  privilege  and  perform  functions  which  are  public  in  nature,  there  is  reason  to  question  whether  banks  should  be  run  entirely  along  private  lines.    

Another  big  difference  is  that  banks  are  leveraged  in  a  different  order  of  magnitude  to  non-­‐financial  firms.  Whereas  non-­‐financial  firms  tend  to  be  debt-­‐financed  in  the  order  of  around  40%  of  their  balance  sheet,  banks  tend  to  be  leveraged  to  the  tune  of  90%  or  more  (Haldane,  2011,  citing  the  Federal  Reserve  Bank  of  New  York  Staff  Report,  June  2011,  p3).  The  injustice  which  Blair  eloquently  complained  of,  relating  to  shareholders  having  all  the  control  whilst  contributing  only  a  fraction  towards  the  success  of  the  company,  is  magnified  acutely  in  the  context  of  the  banking  firm.  As  Haldane  (2011)  observed,  

Page 54: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  54  

shareholder  capital  constitutes  a  ‘vanishingly  small  fraction’  of  a  bank’s  total  assets  and  typically  less  than  5%  in  most  countries,  and  in  the  UK  as  little  as  2.5%.  Jensen  and  Meckling’s  argument  (1976)  that  shareholder  value  governance  can  unfairly  privilege  shareholders  at  the  expense  of  debt  holders  and  other  contributors,  has  special  significance  in  the  context  of  banking,  where  shareholders  contribute  as  little  as  2.5%.  In  that  context,  shareholders  enjoy  what  Haldane  called  an  ‘equity  dictatorship’  (Haldane,  2011).    

It  has  also  been  observed  how  shareholder  value  governance  has  led  to  disinvestment  in  banking.  Since  the  1980s  there  has  been  a  ‘one  way  street’  in  terms  of  dividend  payouts.  Whereas  previously  payouts  would  fluctuate  up  and  down  depending  on  profitability,  dividends  have  generally  only  increased  and  so  too  has  the  practice  of  buying  back  shares  (Haldane,  2011;  Haldane,  2015).  The  predisposition  of  banks  to  debt-­‐finance  is  not  incidental  to  their  business  models  but  an  essential  ingredient.  Whereas  firms  in  other  sectors  might  occasionally  leverage  to  raise  needed  finance,  leveraging  for  banks  is  an  intrinsic  part  of  their  functioning:  their  legal  status  and  definition  as  a  ‘bank’,  depends  upon  them  taking  deposits,  and  usually  other  subordinated  debt,  in  reserve  for  their  lending.  Leveraging  is  not  so  much  optional,  as  a  necessary  component  of  their  business.          

Banks  in  the  UK  are  also  publicly  subsidised.  The  government,  the  taxpayer,  and  thus  society  at  large,  are  all  stakeholders  in  the  banking  business.  The  government  not  only  provides  insurance  for  depositors,  which  is  paid  for  by  tax  payers,  but  it  has  an  interest  in  ensuring  the  integrity  of  the  payment  system  and  the  general  health  of  the  economy  and  consequently  will  not  let  banks  fail  in  any  way  which  jeopardises  such  public  interests.  Even  if  a  government  is  not  legally  bound  to  bail  out  a  bank  in  the  event  of  insolvency,  in  reality,  for  economic  reasons,  it  has  little  choice.  This  too  big  to  fail  (“TBTF”)  subsidy  is  not  merely  theoretical  but  as  was  proven  by  the  various  rescues,  and  bailouts  as  well  as  the  Government’s  programme  of  quantitative  easing  is  very  real  problem.  The  TBTF  subsidy  also  makes  lending  to  banks  more  attractive  for  other  institutions  as  they  are  unlikely  to  default  which  in  turn  reduces  the  cost  of  inter-­‐bank  lending  and  helps  to  contribute  towards  bank  leveraging.    

The  implicit  TBTF  subsidy  also  encourages  banks  to  take  on  risks.  With  the  ability  to  privatise  gains  and  socialise  their  losses,  banks  can  afford  to  take  risks  they  might  not  otherwise  contemplate.  As  Haldane  (2011)  puts  it,  the  state  subsidy,  combined  with  cheaply  leveraged  capital,  turns  banks  into  ‘volatility  junkies’  Shareholder-­‐centric  governance  leads  to  a  transfer  of  risk  to  wider  society  and  can  be  what  Haldane  considered  a  recipe  for  ‘super-­‐charged  risk-­‐shifting’  (Haldane,  2011).  The  TBTF  subsidy  makes  it  difficult  to  price  risk  and  can  lead  to  excessive  risk-­‐taking  and  credit  creation  during  upswings,  whilst  also  contributing  to  excessive  caution  and  a  credit  crunch  during  the  downswing  (Haldane,  2015).  Risk-­‐shifting  results  in  two-­‐sided  deadweight  costs,  for  creditors  and  for  the  macro-­‐economy  (Haldane  et  al,  2015).  Shareholder  primacy  has  led  to  frictions  between  the  company  and  other  stakeholders  which  need  to  be  managed  (Haldane  2015).      

Banks  have  also  become  incredibly  large,  complex  and  opaque  institutions  making  it  difficult  for  directors  to  comprehend  or  control  what  is  going  on.  The  opacity  of  their  business  poses  implications  for  governance.  Banks  may  become  too  big  to  manage  along  private  lines  as  private  companies.    

Page 55: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  55  

As  a  result  of  these  differences,  it  appears  that  the  realisation  is  now  dawning  that  shareholder  value  governance  is  posing  particular  problems  for  banking  (Mayer,  2012;  Haldane,  2011;  Haldane,  2015;  Black  et  al,  2015).  Whilst  this  represents  a  significant  development  within  the  shareholder  versus  stakeholder  debate,  as  we  saw  in  the  last  chapter,  the  ‘official  response’  and  reform  agenda  overlooked  this  issue  –  an  omission  which  is  startling  given  that  banks  perform  functions  of  significant  public  importance,  and  their  ownership  models  are  ultimately  only  ‘social  constructs’  which  we  have  the  power  to  change  (Haldane,  2015).      

3.6   Conclusion      It  seems  that  several  key  figures  in  the  banking  reform  debate  accept  that  

shareholder  value  governance  can  cause  particular  acute  problems  in  banking  (Haldane,  2011,  2015;  Turner,  2016,  pp173-­‐174,  245-­‐264;  PCBS,  2013b,  paras.666-­‐708).  Save  for  the  few  studies  referred  to  in  chapter  1  (Ferri  et  al  2010,  2012;  Bøhren  et  al,  2012,  2013),  there  is  still  very  little  inquiry  into  whether  banks  would  behave  better  if  they  were  capitalised  without  any  shareholder  funds  or  governed  not  for  the  benefit  of  their  ‘owners’  (or  shareholders).  There  appears  to  be  greater  scope  now  than  before  the  crisis  to  contemplate  governance-­‐related  reforms  requiring  banks  to  act  in  the  interests  of  other  company  stakeholders  such  as  bondholders,  depositors,  borrowers,  and  employees  and  external  stakeholders,  such  as  the  government  as  lender  of  last  resort  and  society  at  large.    

The  PCBS’s  recommendation  (2013b,  para.708)  for  a  Government  consultation  about  amending  s172  of  the  Companies  Act  2006  ‘to  prioritise  financial  safety  over  shareholder  interests  in  the  case  of  banks’  was  a  step,  albeit  a  small  one,  in  the  right  direction.  However,  it  came  too  late  in  the  day,  when  the  impetus  for  reform  had  waned,  and  it  was  easily  overlooked  by  Government.  The  main  issues  this  thesis  seeks  to  explore  –  namely,  how  ownership  affects  behaviour,  and  what  the  implications  are  for  reforming  the  way  banks  are  owned  -­‐  have  still  not  been  given  the  treatment  they  deserve  by  the  ‘official  response’  or  within  the  wider  banking  reform  debate,  which  has  only  recently  opened  up  and  been  more  admitting  of  stakeholder  arguments.    

The  behavioural  implications  of  ownership  will  be  studied  more  closely  in  chapters  6,  and  7  before  discussing  their  implications  in  chapter  8.  Before  doing  that,  it  is  necessary  first  to  consider  in  the  next  chapter  what  other  factors,  unrelated  to  the  way  banks  are  owned,  also  influence  and  impact  upon  behaviour  and  strategy.  

     

   

Page 56: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  56  

Chapter  4. ‘Structural  pressures’  and  coping  with  them:  surviving  in  the  ‘wild  west’  following  the  

‘Big  Bang’      

4.1   Introduction      The  political  and  economic  experiment  commonly  referred  to  as  

‘neoliberalism’  changed  the  frame  within  which  banks  operate.  It  affected  what  they  could  do  and  how  they  could  do  it.  De-­‐regulation  became  a  key  policy  plank  of  this  experiment  as  minimal  state  intervention  was  seen  as  a  way  of  attracting  foreign  investment  and  pushing  for  growth  of  the  City  of  London  as  a  global  financial  centre  (Turner,  2016,  pp88-­‐93).  The  corollary  for  the  wider  real  economy  was  a  process  of  de-­‐industrialisation,  which  combined  with  a  reduction  in  real  interest  rates,  resulted  in  reduced  margins  for  banks  to  make  profits  from  traditional  intermediation  between  household  savings  into  business  lending  (CRESC,  2009,  p40;  Turner  et  al,  2010,  p50).    

As  well  as  re-­‐shaping  the  structure  of  the  wider  economy  and  space  within  which  banks  function,  the  state  also  exercised  direct  ‘structural  power’  by  altering  the  structure,  rules  and  regulation  of  the  banking  market  itself  in  a  series  of  the  changes  which  came  to  be  known  as  the  ‘Big  Bang’  (Strange  1988,  p131).  The  removal  of  restrictions  on  credit  and  the  introduction  of  a  new  light-­‐touch  regulatory  regime  made  way  for  the  radical  growth  of  universal  banking  and  the  drastic  expansion  of  credit-­‐creation,  particularly  in  property  lending  and  riskier,  wholesale,  IB  and  speculative  activities  (Turner  2016,  pp88-­‐90).  There  was  an  homogenization  of  the  ownership  landscape  across  the  banking  sector  as  all  manner  of  business  assimilated  one  another  adopting  the  PLC  form  and  becoming  increasingly  mimetic  in  ramping  up  the  volume  of  their  borrowing  and  lending,  and  seeking  to  recover  their  costs  from  sales  to  customer  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  pp90-­‐94).    

The  net  effect  of  the  changes  brought  about  in  the  Big  Bang  was  that  banking  organisations  becoming  increasingly  responsible  for  serving  their  private  interests  and  responsibility  for  acting  in  the  public  interest  was  externalized  to  the  regulators,  whose  job  it  became  to  police  against  bad  behaviour.  This  predicament  resulted  in  what  Luyendijk  called  a  culture  of  ‘amorality’  as  bankers  felt  no  moral  compunction  for  their  behaviour  and  how  it  affected  others  provided  it  was  not  illegal,  or  liable  to  being  caught  (Luyendijk,  2015).    It  inevitably  also  led  to  failure,  as  regulators  having  limited  manpower  and  resources  and  being  in  many  ways  removed  from  the  internal  dealings  of  banks,  were  unable  to  police  banks  perfectly  to  ensure  good  behaviour  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p129).  Their  own  responsibility  for  determining  what  banks  did  and  how  they  did  it  was  limited  both  directly  by  the  specific  changes  made  in  the  Big  

Page 57: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  57  

Bang,  and  indirectly  by  the  increasing  faith  being  placed  by  the  state  in  free  market  forces  (Turner,  2016,  ch.6).  The  spread  of  free  market  ideology  resulted  in  less  attention  being  paid  by  regulators  in  to  how  much  credit  was  being  created  by  banks  and  where  it  was  being  allocated  to  (King,  2016,  ch.2-­‐4;  Turner,  2016,  ch.6).    

Ultimately  how  much  credit  is  created  and  where  it  is  directed  to,  are  questions  which  fall  to  be  determined  by  political  decision  and  can  be  influenced  by  the  exercise  of  state  power  (Strange  1988,  pp24-­‐25).  Credit  can  be  directed  in  ways  which  help  society  or  which  are  useless  or  even  harmful  to  it.    As  we  saw  in  chapter  2,  the  big  political  questions  about  what  we  want  banks  to  do  and  what  reforms  are  required  to  ensure  they  deliver  on  those  expectations  were  largely  avoided  by  the  elite-­‐driven  banking  reform  debate.  The  official  response  did  not  contemplate  revisiting  the  settlement  reached  in  the  Big  Bang,  for  example  by  questioning  what  activities  we  need  banks  to  finance  more  generously  or  to  finance  less,  and  whether,  to  that  end,  the  current  relationship  between  the  state,  market  and  financial  sector  needs  to  be  re-­‐addressed  and  re-­‐balanced  .    

However,  as  on  the  micro-­‐level,  where  the  lesson  being  learnt  seems  to  be  that  it  is  unwise  to  treat  a  banking  organisation  like  any  other  capitalist  enterprise  and  to  have  it  owned  in  the  same  manner,  so  too  on  the  macro-­‐level  it  seems  that  the  realization  is  dawning  that  it  is  unwise  to  treat  the  banking  market  like  any  other  market  and  to  leave  the  fate  of  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  to  unbridled  market  forces  (CRESC,  2009;  King  2016;  Turner  2016).  It  is  now  increasingly  argued  that  left  to  their  own  devices,  banks  will  create  too  much  of  the  wrong  sort  of  credit,  financing  debt-­‐fuelled  consumption,  or  competition  for  locationally  scarce  property  resources,  thus  causing  property  price  inflation  and  instability;  rather  than  allocating  credit  to  useful  investment  which  generate  the  additional  wealth  needed  by  society  to  repay  its  debts,  banks  instead  tend  to  finance  unproductive  activities,  particularly  property  which  fuel  dangerously  unstable  economic  cycles  and  pose  a  burden  to  society  (CRESC,  2009,  pp40,  44;  Turner,  2016,  pp172-­‐174,  245-­‐246).      

This  chapter  explores  the  structural  pressures  which  have  been  exerted  on  banks  by  the  market  and  regulatory  environment  within  which  they  operate.  It  does  this  by  exploring  the  main  changes  in  the  banking  business  model  over  the  past  40  years  and  considering  how  structural  pressures  influenced  such  changes.  The  chapter  is  broken  up  broadly  into  four  parts,  each  looking  at  a  significant  shift  within  the  banking  business.  The  first  part  considers  how  the  Big  Bang  ushered  in  a  permissive  regulatory  regime  which  encouraged  banks  to  leverage  to  gargantuan  sizes  and  to  move  away  from  traditional  intermediation.    The  second  part  then  considers  the  increased  allocation  of  credit  to  property-­‐lending.  It  describes  how  the  regulations  restricting  property  lending  were  removed  in  the  Big  Bang  and  how  at  the  same  time  changes  in  the  wider  market  economy  reduced  the  scope  for  making  profits  in  traditional  intermediation.  It  describes  how,  in  this  environment,  banks  inevitably  sought  out  other  sources  of  profit,  and  exploited  new  opportunities  which  were  made  possible  in  the  Big  Bang  chiefly  in  property  speculation  (CRESC,  2009,  p40).    

The  third  part  then  considers  the  shift  towards  universal  banking  and  its  increasing  dependence  on  risky  IB  operations.  Having  de-­‐compartmentalised  the  financial  market  and  liberalized  trading  rules,  the  state  cleared  the  path  for  banks  to  adopt  a  universal  model  and  to  engage  in  large-­‐scale  wholesale  and  IB  

Page 58: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  58  

operations.  The  growth  of  universal  banking,  also  gave  rise  to  another  structural  pressure,  at  least  for  smaller  banks.    It  describes  how  the  dynamics  of  an  increasingly  oligopolistic  banking  market  put  pressures  on  smaller  banks  to  act  mimetically  or  take  risky  steps  to  gain  market  access  and  to  compete.  A  fourth  trend  concerns  the  emergence  of  a  selling  culture  within  retail  banking.  This  part  describes  how  banks  were  subject  to  pressures  to  exploit  their  customers  and  to  make  money  out  of  them  in  order  to  recover  the  costs  of  their  branch  networks  and  maintain  expensive  free-­‐whilst-­‐in-­‐credit  services  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p104).  These  dynamics  encouraged  banks  to  shift  away  from  being  servant  and  intermediary  and  witnessed  banks  becoming  increasingly  independent  and  in  it  ‘for  themselves’  (CRESC,  2009,  p42).      

4.2   Part  1:  The  shift  from  intermediation  to  credit-­‐creation      

4.2.1   The  explosion  of  credit-­‐creation    The  standard  text-­‐book  definition  of  what  banks  do  tends  to  overlook  

their  function  in  creating  credit,  suggesting  instead  that  their  main  function  is  to  act  as  intermediaries  allocating  redundant  capital  from  existing  savers  into  productive  investment  by  lending  to  borrowers  (Jakab  et  al,  2015;  Turner,  2016,  pp57-­‐60).  This  narrative  suggests  that  banks  merely  redistribute  a  money  supply  which  already  exists,  and  implies  that  they  perform  some  form  of  social  good  by  allocating  existing  un-­‐used  capital  to  needed  investments,  leading  to  growth  and  increase  of  commercial  activities.  But  that  description  fails  to  explain  how  banks  by  lending  more  than  they  have,  in  fact  create  credit  and  extend  the  money  supply.  Since  banks  are  required  to  keep  in  reserve  only  a  tiny  fraction  of  the  amounts  they  lend,  and  since  they  have  an  almost  unlimited  capacity  to  borrow  and  to  lend  more,  they  play  a  leading  role  in  creating  credit.  Whilst  they  are  no  longer  able  to  print  their  own  money  in  this  country,  they  create  it  electronically,  which  has  the  same  effect  in  extending  the  money  supply;  and  indeed  the  vast  majority  of  money  in  circulation  is  created  electronically  in  this  way  (Turner,  2016,  p58).    

In  the  last  half  century,  the  amount  of  credit  created  by  banks  has  increased  in  staggering  quantities.  In  the  10  years  between  1997  and  2007,  there  was  an  increase  in  the  money  supply  from  £750  billion  to  £1700  billion,  most  of  which  is  thought  to  have  been  caused  by  bank  lending  (New  Economics  Foundation,  2012,  p47).  In  the  decade  which  led  up  to  the  global  financial  crisis  of  2007-­‐2008,  private  credit  grew  at  a  rate  of  roughly  10%  per  year  resulting  in  Britain’s  banks  lending  so  much  that  their  balance  sheets  eventually  exceeded  the  nation’s  GDP  by  more  than  five  times  (Turner,  2016,  p51).  This  increase  in  credit  contrasts  markedly  with  half  a  century  ago.  Back  in  1964,  the  balance  sheets  of  UK  banks  constituted  only  35%  of  GDP  and  Government  debt  was  only  39%  of  GDP  (Turner,  2016,  p51).  As  can  be  seen  from  Charts  4.1  and  4.2  below,  households  tended  to  deposit  a  lot  more  than  they  borrowed,  typically  depositing  as  much  as  40%  of  GDP  and  borrowing  as  little  as  14%,  whereas  the  corporate  sector  borrowed  slightly  more  than  it  deposited  –  borrowing  13%,  and  depositing  8%.    

Page 59: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  59  

     

   Chart 4.1: Household deposits and loans in % of GDP (1964-2009)

(Source:  Turner  et  al,  2010,  p56,  citing  Bank  of  England  as  the  source  of  data)      

 

 Chart 4.2: Business deposits and loans in % of GDP (1964-2009)

 (Turner  et  al,  2010,  p57,  citing  Bank  of  England  as  the  source  of  data)    

Page 60: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  60  

   By  2007,  there  is  a  very  different  picture.  Whilst  bank  balance  sheets  

tower  over  GDP,  being  500%  bigger,  households  borrow  more  than  they  deposit,  typically  borrowing  76%  of  GDP  and  up  to  95%  of  GDP  if  secured  lending  is  taken  into  account,  which  is  not  otherwise  shown  on  bank  balance-­‐sheets  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  p17),  a  significant  increase  from  the  14%  borrowed  in  1964.  And  in  2007,  they  deposited  72%  of  GDP  which  whilst  more  than  the  35%  deposited  in  1964  is  less  than  the  amount  (76%  or  95%)  which  households  borrowed  (see  Charts  4.1  and  4.2  above).  In  other  words,  whilst  in  1964  there  was  a  surplus  of  capital  which  could  be  allocated  to  borrowers,  which  came  from  households  depositing  more  than  they  borrowed,  by  2007  there  was  no  such  surplus.  Instead,  where  there  used  to  be  funding  for  traditional  intermediation  a  funding  gap  has  emerged.  Clearly,  the  modern  banking  business  model  is  thus  no  longer  rooted  in  intermediating  between  household  deposits  and  business  borrowing,  and  textbook  suggestions  to  the  contrary  are  misleading  (Jakab  et  al,  2015;  Turner,  2016,  pp57-­‐60).    

Instead  of  sourcing  funding  from  household  deposits,  banks  now  fund  their  lending,  or  rather  the  fraction  of  their  lending  which  they  are  required  to  keep  in  reserves,  from  wholesale,  and  typically  inter-­‐bank,  borrowing.    This  shift  has  been  underscored  by  an  increase  in  often  complex  securitisation.  Banks  have  moved  away  from  retaining  loans  on  their  balance  sheets,  as  assets,  in  favour  of  adopting  an  ‘originate  and  distribute’  model  whereby  securitisation  provides  the  mechanism  to  bundle  up  their  loans  and  sell  them  on  typically  to  those  that  were  able  to  secure  cheap  finance,  often  secured  against  the  securities  being  purchased.  By  clearing  these  assets  off  their  balance  sheets  in  this  way,  banks  have  been  able  to  grow  their  fee  income  and  interest  income  whilst  enhancing  their  capitalised  balance  sheets,  thus  generating  additional  funds  which  banks  can  also  re-­‐lend.    

To  appreciate  just  how  much  money  banks  borrowed  in  wholesale  markets,  it  is  useful  to  put  the  UK’s  £1,200  billion  bailout  into  perspective:  the  entire  bail  out  in  2009  represented  just  75%  of  what  UK  banks  lent  to  finance  in  the  very  same  year  (CRESC,  2009,  p45).    Thus,  at  the  aggregate  level,  we  can  see  a  shift  from  a  business  model  grounded  in  the  relationship  between  households  and  companies,  and  in  its  place  an  increase  in  credit  creation  dependent  upon  increased  amounts  of  wholesale  borrowing  and  securitisation  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  p17).    

The  structural  pressures  encouraging  this  radical  change  in  activity  were  brought  about  by  a  deregulation  on  bank  lending.  The  banking  sector’s  capacity  to  create  credit  is  limited  first  by  the  rules  which  regulate  how  much  banks  have  to  keep  in  reserves,  second  by  the  rules  which  place  restrictions  on  the  quantity  and  type  of  credit  which  banks  can  create,  and  third  by  the  lending  opportunities  available  to  banks.  In  terms  of  the  first  two  types  of  restrictions,  as  we  shall  explore  below  the  last  fifty  years  have  seen  significant  reductions  on  constraints  and  a  general  de-­‐regulation  of  limits  on  the  type  and  amount  of  credit  banks  can  create.  At  the  same  time,  there  has  also  been  a  broader  change  in  the  structure  of  the  wider  economy,  which  has  undergone  a  process  of  de-­‐industrialization,  whilst  the  state  pushed  for  growth  of  the  City  of  London  and  foreign  investment.    

Page 61: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  61  

As  a  result  of  these  changes,  banks  have  been  able  to  lend  a  lot  more  and  they  have  been  less  restricted  in  what  types  of  credit  they  can  create.  At  the  same  time  however  they  have  had  fewer  opportunities  to  make  profits  from  productive  investment  and  they  have  thus  had  to  look  elsewhere  to  make  profits  from  other  areas  of  activity  favoured  by  state  policy,  and  in  particular  two  areas  considered  below:  the  state’s  encouragement  of  home  ownership,  which  found  expression  through  increased  property  lending,  and  the  state’s  ambitions  to  cultivate  a  thriving  internationally  competitive  financial  centre  in  the  City,  which  was  translated  through  into  greater  wholesale  and  IB  activities  (Moran,  1991,  p124).      

4.2.2     Removing  constraints  on  credit-­‐creation    In  the  first  half  of  the  20th  century,  the  UK  like  most  other  developed  

western  political  economies  restricted  credit-­‐creation  and  compartmentalized  finance  into  different  regulated  activities.  Before  the  big  Bang,  real  estate  lending  was  heavily  regulated,  and  pre-­‐dominantly  performed  by  building  society  lenders  (Moran,  1991,  p16).  The  Competition  and  Credit  Control  Act  1971  abandoned  any  quantitative  constraints  on  credit  creation,  removing  any  restrictions  on  the  amount  of  lending  banks  perform.  In  the  Big  Bang  in  the  1980s  the  constraints  on  bank  mortgage  lending  were  removed  entirely  and  the  different  types  of  finance  were  de-­‐compartmentalised,  with  banks  and  financial  service  providers  being  encouraged  to  compete  in  one  another’s  field  to  undertake  previously  protected  and  separately  regulated  domains  of  activity.  These  changes  essentially  permitted  banks  to  engage  in  all  manner  of  activity,  to  create  as  much  credit,  of  whatever  type,  they  wanted.  It  also  led  to  the  creation  of  ever  more  complex  and  sophisticated  IB  instruments,  operations  and  markets  and  the  growth  of  increasingly  lengthy  and  complex  chains  of  activity  (Turner  et  al,  2010,  p14).  

At  the  same  time,  the  requirements  for  banks  to  hold  capital  in  reserve  were  weakened.  Historically,  the  Bank  of  England  –  the  lender  of  last  resort,  ultimately  responsible  for  paying  out  in  the  event  of  bank  failure  –  kept  a  cautious  eye  on  bank  behaviour  to  ensure  that  they  had  adequate  reserves  to  prevent  bank  runs  and  to  mitigate  damage  in  the  event  of  bankruptcy.  It  had  power  to  insist  upon  minimal  capital  requirements,  and  to  call  in  and  itself  hold  bank  capital  in  reserves  to  cope  with  any  failure.      In  the  last  half  century  however,  the  Bank  of  England  has  abrogated  this  function  of  taxing  banks  for  rainy  days  in  favour  of  minimal  international  standards  set  by  Basel  and  in  doing  so  it  has  become  less  concerned  by  domestic  balance  sheets  and  the  credit  being  created  by  UK  banks,  and  instead  of  paying  keen  attention  to  how  much  credit  was  being  created  and  what  it  was  being  applied  to  the  Bank  of  England  has  instead  focused  predominantly  on  monetarism  and  the  control  of  inflation  (King,  2016,  ch.5;  Turner,  2016,  ch.6).    

This  diversion  of  focus  and  abrogation  of  responsibility  for  credit-­‐creation  marked  a  shift  away  from  the  previous  political-­‐economic  order,  which  was  noticeably  more  cautious  about  how  credit  was  being  created  and  allocated.  After  the  last  depression,  economists  and  academics  had  widely  warned  about  the  dangers  posed  by  banks  pumping  out  too  much  credit  and  fuelling  

Page 62: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  62  

unsustainable  asset  price  bubbles,  which  were  liable  to  burst.  Between  1929  and  1933,  economists  of  the  Chicago  school,  including  Irving  Fisher,  Frank  Knight,  Henry  Simons,  even  called  for  an  end  to  fractional  reserve  banking,  or  rather  they  called  for  banks  to  hold  in  reserve  a  100%  fraction  of  their  lending  (Turner,  2016,  p188).  Frederick  Soddy  (1926)  argued  that  banks  should  not  be  freely  licenced  to  create  credit  because  by  doing  so  they  extend  the  money  supply  and  thus  affect  society’s  purchasing  power.  Soddy  argued  that  the  state  needed  to  reclaim  and  control  this  function,  and  constitutionalise  how  it  was  to  be  exercised  –  arguments  which  have  been  given  renewed  force  by  movements  such  as  Positive  Money  (Douglas,  2015)  and  by  economists  and  even  mainstream  financial  commentators  such  as  Turner  (2016)  and  Wolf  (2014c).    

  The  Chicago  economists  not  only  advocated  in  favour  of  abolishing  fractional  reserve  banking  insisting  that  the  government  should  direct  credit-­‐creation  but  also  argued  that  state  printed  fiat  money  or  helicopter  money  was  preferable  to  letting  fractional  reserve  banking  create  purchasing  power  in  ways  which  were  controlled  by  the  free  market  (Turner,  2016,  p188).  Whilst  these  post-­‐depression  economists  did  not  succeed  in  abolishing  fractional  reserve  banking  or  getting  states  to  control  or  constitutionalise  such  functions,  there  was  a  lot  more  caution  and  concern,  before  the  Big  Bang,  about  how  much  credit  banks  were  creating.    Even  the  economists  who  were  relied  upon  by  the  proponents  of  neoliberalism,  such  as  Milton  Friedman,  Wicksell,  and  Hayek  warned  of  the  threats  posed  to  financial  stability  by  banks  creating  too  much  credit  (Turner,  2016,  p189).  Friedman  in  particular  had  argued  that  in  deflationary  times  it  was  desirable  for  the  state  to  create  credit  (Turner,  p188;  Friedman,  1948,  pp245-­‐246).  Wicksell  also  argued  that  credit  needed  to  be  constrained.  As  well  as  setting  the  rate  of  interest  in  line  with  the  natural  rate  of  interest,  Wicksell  prescribed  government  control  of  credit  creation  arguing  that  banks  should  be  required  to  hold  a  substantial  fixed  proportion  of  their  money  liabilities  as  liquid  reserves  at  the  central  bank,  a  requirement  which  central  bankers,  in  their  pursuit  of  free  market  thinking,  since  ignored    (Turner,  p59).      

And  more  recently,  economists  such  as  Minsky  (1991)  warned  vociferously  about  the  dangers  posed  by  banks  pumping  out  too  much  credit  and  engaging  in  ‘speculative’  and  ‘ponzi  lending’.  Stability  was  undermined,  he  warned,  by  having  a  monetary  economy  run  by  financial  institutions  whose  capitalistic  aims  were  liable  to  cause  markets  to  be  flooded  with  credit  (Minsky,  1991).        

Instead  of  keeping  an  eye  on  credit  creation  and  bank  reserves,  the  Bank  of  England  transferred  its  banking  oversight  functions  to  the  Securities  and  Investment  Board,  an  early  incarnation  of  the  FSA,  or  today’s  PRA  and  FCA  –  an  institution  which  was  not  expected  to  act  as  lender  of  last  resort  and  thus  arguably  never  had  the  right  incentives  to  guard  vigilantly  against  over-­‐extension  of  credit.  Having  transferred  its  oversight  functions  to  another  regulator  and  placed  its  faith  in  Basel  to  set  international  standards  to  regulate  capital  reserves,  the  Bank  of  England  prioritised  its  focus  on  monetarism,  concerning  itself  more  with  inflation  than  bank  balance  sheets  (Turner,  2016,  p242).  Whilst  the  Basel  framework  attempts  to  regulate  the  quantity  and  quality  of  capital  retained  by  banks,  and  thus  to  put  some  limits  on  the  amount  of  credit  which  banks  can  create  relative  to  their  capital,  and  to  do  so  in  a  clear  and  universal  way,  the  amount  of  capital  required  to  be  kept  in  reserve  under  Basel  

Page 63: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  63  

has  been  widely  and  heavily  criticized  as  being  too  little,  and  governed  by  the  principle  of  the  lowest  common  denominator  (Admati  et  al,  2013,  ch.11).      

The  Basel  regime  also  places  no  constrains  whatsoever  on  bank  size.  Provided  banks  keep  sufficient  risk  weighted  capital,  there  are  no  limits  on  the  scale  and  scope  of  banking.    To  reign  in  their  capacity  for  credit-­‐creation,  many  economists  argue  that  banks  should  hold  two  or  three  times  as  much  as  at  present  and  at  least  20%  or  30%  capital  in  total  against  their  liabilities  (Admati  et  al,  2013,  ch.13)  –  far  short  of  the  100%  called  for  by  the  Chicago  school  after  the  last  depression.    

The  Basel  framework,  which  has  a  sophisticated  regime  of  risk  weighting  capital  and  liquidity  requirements,  can  furthermore  be  gamed  by  banks  able  to  shift  assets  and  liabilities  off  balance  sheet  (Ertürk,  2015).    Basel  II  for  example  allowed  credit  derivatives  to  reduce  balance  sheet  risk.  Banks  thus  bought  credit  default  swaps  to  shift  risks,  supposedly,  off  their  balance  sheets,  whilst  in  effect  taking  positions  which  overall  enhanced  volatility  across  the  sector.  And  banks  gamed  the  rules  in  other  ways.  With  many  transactions  classed  as  off-­‐balance-­‐sheet,  banks  had  every  incentive  to  develop  those  lines  of  business.  Lending  to  government  for  example  was  classed  as  risk  free  under  Basel  I  thus  requiring  no  capital  reserves  to  support  that  lending.  Lending  to  private  companies  on  the  other  hand  required  around  8%  capital  reserves  (Ertürk,  2015).    Lending  to  other  banks  was  classified  as  low  risk,  and  was  thus  encouraged.    Interbank  lending  thus  grew  exponentially,  and  by  2007  it  constituted  a  massive  25%  of  bank  lending.  

Without  high  capital  adequacy  standards,  banks  will  play  a  significant  role  in  creating  credit.  The  less  banks  have  to  keep  in  reserve  as  a  fraction  of  their  lending,  the  more  they  can  lend.  Able  to  hold  less  or  less  quality  capital  in  reserve,  banks  have  therefore  ramped  up  the  scale  and  scope  of  their  activities,  whilst  at  the  same  time  the  Bank  of  England  was  unconcerned  with  increasing  bank  balance  sheets.  According  to  Andy  Haldane,  before  the  crisis  less  than  2%  of  BoE  time  was  spent  discussing  the  activity  of  banks,  the  regulation  of  which  had  been  passed  over  to  the  FSA  (Turner,  2016,  p20).    Economists  even  removed  bank  balance  sheets  from  their  risk  models:  the  ‘Dynamic  Stochastic  General  Equilibrium  models’  employed  by  economists  completely  ignored  the  destabilizing  role  banks  played  acting  as  creators  of  credit  (Turner,  2016,  pp170,  246).    

 

4.3   Part  2:  the  shift  from  productive  investment  to  property-­‐lending    For  more  than  half  a  century,  private  credit  has  grown  at  a  faster  rate  

than  GDP  and  by  and  large  that  credit  has  been  pumped  not  into  productive  investment  but  mainly  into  real  estate  lending.  Most  of  the  lending  undertaken  by  banks  has  contributed  towards  either  debt-­‐funded  consumption  or  competition  between  borrowers  for  the  ownership  of  locationally  desirable,  already  existing,  real  estate  properties  (Jordà  et  al,  2014;  Turner,  2016,  p246).  In  complex  roundabout  ways,  banks  have  effectively  become  real-­‐estate  lenders  either  directly  through  retail  banking  or  in  circuitous  routes  through  wholesale  inter-­‐bank  lending  and  IB  operations  (Turner,  2016,  p66;  Jordà  et  al  2014).    

Page 64: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  64  

Between  the  mid-­‐1990s  to  2007,  the  share  of  bank  lending  which  was  allocated  to  manufacturing  fell,  in  relative  terms,  from  7.9%  to  1.6%  and  there  were  similar  trends  in  agriculture,  construction,  retail  and  distribution  (CRESC,  2009,  p44).  Since  the  mid-­‐1980s,  productive  investment  has  essentially  plateaued  and  lending  to  real  estate,  insurance  and  inter-­‐bank  lending  has  increased  (see  Chart  4.3  below).  By  2007,  25%  of  bank  lending  went  to  finance;  40%  was  comprised  of  real  estate  and  less  than  2%  went  to  manufacturing  (CRESC,  2009,  pp44-­‐45).  Before  the  last  depression,  in  the  1920s,  real  estate  lending  averaged  less  than  20%  of  bank  liabilities,  whereas  by  1970,  it  was  around  35%  and  by  2005,  it  was  nearly  60%  (Jordà  et  al,  2014;  Turner,  2016,  p67).        

   

Chart 4.3: UK banks lending by sector in £tr. (1986-2013)

(Source:  Turner  et  al,  2010,  p57,  citing  Bank  of  England  as  the  source)    In  1970,  the  value  of  the  nation’s  wealth,  which  is  mostly  attributable  to  

the  value  of  real  property,  was  approximately  three  times  the  nation’s  income  whereas  by  2010  it  was  nearly  six  times  the  nation’s  income  (Turner,  2016,  p67).  Housing  wealth  was  120  %  of  national  income  in  1970  and  371%  in  2010  (Turner,  2016,  p67).  In  mature,  developed  cities,  rising  property  prices  are  attributable  not  to  new  construction,  which  would  employ  and  reward  labour  and  the  human  endeavour  involved  in  selling  materials  for  construction,  but  increases  in  value  in  the  underlying  land.    80%  of  property  price  increases  in  the  UK  were  increases  in  the  value  of  the  land  and  only  20%  was  attributable  to  new  construction  and  developments  (Turner,  2016,  p68.).  Whereas  the  supply  of  land,  especially  in  good  locations,  is  scarce,  the  supply  of  credit  is  practically  unlimited.  In  other  words,  if  the  supply  of  credit  increases,  so  too  will  the  price  of  land.    Lending  against  real  estate  thus  creates  asset  price  inflation,  generating  a  

Page 65: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  65  

self-­‐reinforcing  cycles  of  credit  supply,  credit  demand  and  asset  prices  inflation  –  a  bubble  which  eventually  bursts.    

Changes  in  regulation,  chiefly  the  removal  of  the  restrictions  on  property  lending  and  credit  creation,  and  the  lowering  of  capital  adequacy  standards,  have  not  been  the  only  structural  pressures  driving  real-­‐estate  lending.  Property  lending  has  also  been  encouraged  by  political  attitudes  and  also  by  another  type  of  structural  pressure  emerging  from  the  real  economy.    As  we  have  explored  above,  back  in  the  mid-­‐1960s,  when  households  deposited  more  than  they  borrowed  and  businesses  borrowed  more  than  they  deposited,  there  was  a  place  for  high  street  and  commercial  banks  to  make  money  from  inter-­‐mediating  funds  between  household  deposits  and  lending  to  business.  In  this  environment,  typically  high  national  interest  rates  encouraged  household  savings  and  gave  scope  for  retail  and  commercial  banks  to  make  a  profit  on  the  spreads  between  savings  and  lending.  A  desire  to  lower  national  interest  rates  put  downward  pressure  on  the  high  street  banks’  ability  to  take  a  cut  from  intermediation.  

Selling  credit  secured  against  property  thus  became  the  basic,  low  cost,  low  risk  business  line  for  mainstream  banks.  Compared  to  lending  working  capital  to  manufacturing  firms,  property  lending  was  unproblematic  and  provided  security  which  in  a  period  of  rising  property  prices  offered  banks  the  appearance  of  safety  without  any  of  the  high  costs  and  due  diligence  involved  in  business  lending.  Mortgages  and  secured  lending  which  had  been  sold  to  customers,  could  also  be  repackaged  and  sold  again  on  wholesale  markets  fusing  wholesale  and  retail  banking  together  in  what  CRESC  described  as  ‘a  giant  transaction  generating  machine  with  mass  marketing  of  retail  products  providing  the  feedstock  for  proprietary  trading  in  wholesale’  (CRESC,  2009,  p40).  The  result  of  removing  restrictions  on  the  quantity  of  and  type  of  bank  lending,  and  eradicating  scope  for  margin  in  intermediation,  was  the  relentless  rise  of  real  estate  lending,  which  funded  unsustainable  property  prices,  and  ultimately  contributed  towards  unsustainable  asset  price  rises.    

Property  lending  was  also  encouraged  by  widespread  faith  in  free  market  forces.  As  the  external  structure  of  the  real  economy  witnessed  a  process  of  de-­‐industrialisation,  fewer  opportunities  for  productive  investment  were  presented.  The  secondary  banking  crisis  in  the  early  1970s  is  a  case  in  point.  As  Reid  (1988)  observed,  the  root  of  this  crisis  was  the  nation’s  bias  for  property  lending,  and  the  lack  of  productive  alternatives  in  the  real  economy.  In  a  de-­‐industrialised  and  globalized  economy,  where  manufactured  goods  are  more  cheaply  sourced  elsewhere,  property  speculation  was  an  easier  bet  for  banks  than  investment  in  the  real  economy.    

In  the  secondary  banking  crisis  in  the  early  1970s  small  lenders  bet  on  rising  property  prices  particularly  in  London.    A  large  number  of  smaller  ‘secondary’  banks  invested  heavily  in  property  lending  aiming  to  capitalize  on  rising  housing  prices  in  the  late  1960s  and  early  1970s.  These  banks  relied  heavily  on  borrowed  money,  and  engaged  in  what  Minsky  described  as  ‘Ponzi  lending’  -­‐  their  profits  were  dependent  on  continuing  house  price  rises,  which  in  turn  were  dependent  upon  more  lending  and  more  finance  being  available.  A  downturn  in  the  housing  market  together  with  interest  rate  rises,  and  other  economic  shocks  popped  the  bubble  and  left  many  ‘secondary  banks’  holding  security  worth  less  than  the  loans  which  were  supposedly  secured.    This  crisis  might  have  served  as  a  precursory  warning  to  the  global  financial  crisis,  warning  

Page 66: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  66  

about  how  gains  from  real  estate  lending  can  be  illusory,  and  unstable  and  how  real  estate  lending  can  pose  dangers  to  the  economy.  However  the  Bank  of  England  did  not  come  out  of  the  secondary  banking  crisis  being  distrustful  of  real  estate  lending  or  with  a  new  eagerness  to  help  direct  bank  credit  into  productive  investment.    

Instead,  the  Bank  of  England  fell  in  line  with  free-­‐market  thinking,  and  wanting  to  avoid  micro-­‐managing  bank  lending  it  developed  a  distrust  of  managing  small  banks  having  bailed  out  some  thirty  smaller  banks  in  that  crisis  (Reid,  1988).      Notwithstanding  the  persuasive  arguments  advanced  by  economists  throughout  the  20th  century  that  the  government  should  have  a  hand  in  guiding  and  constraining  credit-­‐creation,  the  state  instead  sought  to  create  a  more  unified  market  economy,  leaving  the  determination  and  allocation  of  credit-­‐creation  almost  entirely  to  free  market  forces.          

4.4   Part  3:  the  shift  into  riskier  business    

Almost  universally,  there  has  also  been  a  shift  in  the  banking  business  model  towards  increased  IB,  with  the  profitability  of  banks  becoming  increasingly  dependent  upon  their  engagement  in  wholesale  and  IB  operations  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  pp90-­‐94).  Of  the  Big  Five,  all  bar  Lloyds,  have  radically  grown    their  wholesale  and  IB  operations  following  the  Big  Bang  (Fallon,  2015,  p56).  The  universal  banking  model  that  emerged  involved  banks  engaging  in  a  wide  variety  of  operations,  not  least  mergers  and  acquisitions  (‘M&A’)  and  the  types  of  complex  property  instruments  which  underscored  banking’s  shift  into  property-­‐lending  described  above.  Having  generated  fees  on  retail  property  loans,  banks  then  repackaged  them  and  sold  them  on  in  wholesale  markets,  taking  a  ‘clip’  at  every  stage  of  the  chain  and  upon  each  transaction  (CRESC,  2009,  p44).  Since  the  Big  Bang  there  has  been  a  radical  growth  in  complex  securitization  and  a  proliferation  of  complicated  instruments  -­‐  such  as  mortgage  backed  securities,  interest  rate  derivatives,  foreign  exchange  swaps  and  commodities  futures  and  oil  futures.    In  terms  of  M&A,  banks  not  only  financed  M&A  in  other  sectors  but  also  engaged  in  it  themselves,  and  in  the  process  they  accumulated  often  large  amounts  of  intangible  assets  onto  their  balance  sheets  in  the  form  of  goodwill,  which  can  be  terribly  difficult  to  value.  The  profitability  of  many  of  these  operations,  like  with  competition  for  locationally  scarce  properties,  depended  upon  continued,  and  ultimately  unsustainable  levels  of,  liquidity  and  demand  for  credit,  as  well  as  consistent  valuations.  When  demand,  asset  prices,  or  liquidity  fell,  those  operations  became  less  sustainable.          

In  the  decades  leading  up  to  the  GFC,  inter-­‐bank  lending  significantly  increased.  It  largely  financed  IB  operations  and  contributed  to  the  growth  of  a  complex  inter-­‐dependent  global  credit-­‐intermediation  system.    At  the  same  time,  the  treasury  departments  of  banks  grew  exponentially.  Whereas  these  used  to  be  small,  service  departments,  very  much  reactive  in  nature,  responding  to  bank  deficits  or  surfeits  by  borrowing  or  lending  on  the  inter-­‐bank  markets,  they  turned  into  large  profit  centres  in  their  own  rights  (Turner,  2016,  p96).  These  departments  did  not  previously  require  large  numbers  of  highly  paid  traders  to  undertake  their  book-­‐balancing.  By  the  1990s,  however,  these  departments  had  become  pro-­‐active  in  their  approach  to  making  profits  and  they  were  manned  by  

Page 67: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  67  

armies  of  dealers  who  were  invariably  sited  on  the  same  floors  of  banks  as  traders,  and  they  were  paid  handsomely  to  transact  in  all  manner  of  financial  instruments  giving  rise  to  a  complex  mesh  of  intra  financial  system  claims  and  obligations  (Turner,  2016,  p96).      

There  were  various  structural  pressures  contributing  towards  this  shift  into  IB  operations.  The  Big  Bang  essentially  let  loose  a  lot  of  non-­‐British  actors  and  significant  foreign  capital  hungrily  searching  for  yield  (Moran,  1991).      In  1979  exchange  controls  were  abolished  and  foreign  investment  and  participation  was  encouraged  through  the  progressive  dismantling  of  foreign  exchange  controls  after  1979  (Moran,  1991,  p10).  Fixed  commissions  and  interest  rates  were  abolished,  exposing  traders  and  lenders  to  competitive  pricing  and  selling  practices  by  new  entrants  (Moran  1991,  p10).  A  process  of  de-­‐compartmentalising  finance  followed,  as  regulatory  burdens  were  removed  and  barriers  opened  up.  In  the  early  to  mid  1980s  there  was  a  wholesale  dismantling  of  protectionist  measures.  The  state  removed:  restrictions  on  price  competition,  fixed  interest  rates,  fixed  commissions  on  the  sale  of  securities,  the  prohibition  on  foreign  enterprise  participating  in  securities,  and  the  restrictions  on  domestic  businesses  operating  in  other  types  of  business  (Moran  1991,  p10).    

After  1983  there  was  also  a  phasing  out  of  price  competition  on  the  stock  exchange,  the  prohibitions  on  firms  acting  as  principles  and  brokers  were  abolished  and  the  restrictions  on  stock  market  companies  being  owned  by  foreigners  was  abolished  (Moran,  1991,  p10).    There  was  also  a  radical  change  in  the  way  firms  could  be  owned.  Foreigners  were  permitted  to  own  shares,  to  trade  on  the  stock  exchange  and  to  take  over  British  companies  (Moran,  1991,  p10).    

The  British  securities  industry  thus  became  increasingly  exposed  to  competition  and  was  no  longer  a  protected  domestic  arena.  The  signal  went  out  that  all  were  welcome  to  compete  in  IB  and  London  was  open  for  business.    The  state  broke  down  the  compartments  between  finance,  and  retail  banks  moved  not  only  into  mortgage-­‐lending  which  was  formerly  the  domain  of  building  societies  but  also  into  securities  and  IB.  The  former  cartel,  operating  around  the  stock  market  which  had  been  insulated  from  competition,  was  broken  up  and  what  was  largely  an  inward-­‐looking  merchant  banking  sector  was  exposed  to  new  competition    (Moran,  1991).    

Prior  to  the  Big  Bang  takeover  by  foreign  enterprise  was  prohibited,  the  ownership  of  shares  by  foreigners  was  constrained,  there  were  high  barriers  to  entry  to  the  securities  and  banking  markets  by  both  foreign  and  domestic  enterprises  and  domestic  competition  was  also  constrained  by  restrictions  on  price  competition,  such  as  minimum  commissions,  and  with  fixed  interest  rates  set  on  loans  and  deposits,  and  there  was  hostility  towards  new  products  and  innovation  (Moran  1991,  p9).  Before  the  1980s  the  elite  finance  capitalists  had  thus  developed  their  own  operations  and  regulation  largely  removed  from  the  attentions  of  the  state  (Moran,  1991,  p9).  These  elite  interests  were  largely  insulated  from  intervention  by  the  state  which  viewed  the  task  of  understanding,  let  alone  regulating,  these  activities  as  mystifying  and  best  left  to  those  whose  familiarity  and  expertise  lent  themselves  to  understanding  complexity  (Moran  1991  p18).  New  technological  advances  and  regulatory  reforms  in  other  countries  also  opened  the  way  for  more  global  operations  and  gave  way  to  new  trading  behaviours,  even  creating  new  markets  (Moran  1991,  p12).  New  

Page 68: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  68  

competition  brought  about  innovation,  which  led  to  the  creation  of  new  products  and  markets:  

 ‘There  is  in  turn  an  intimate  connection  between  intensified  competition  and  the  drive  for  innovation,  because  the  creation  of  new  financial  instruments  or  trading  practices  is  one  of  the  most  effective  ways  of  securing  a  competitive  advantage…  In  recent  decades  this  ingenuity  has  stretched  beyond  the  invention  of  particular  contracts  to  the  creation  of  whole  markets.  Two  of  the  most  dynamic  are  in  financial  derivatives  and  Eurocurrencies….’  (Moran  1991,  10-­‐11)    The  Big  Bang  also  gave  banks  incentives  to  incorporate  as  PLCs,  which  in  

turn  encouraged  risky  behaviour.  National  championing  of  the  City  as  the  destination  for  foreign  investment  opened  up  new  access  to  capital  for  banks.  By  permitting  foreign  ownership  of  shares  and  breaking  up  the  old  stock  market  oligopoly,  causing  an  explosion  of  investment  in  the  stock  market,  the  PLC  –  able  to  quickly  raise  equity  –  became  the  main  ownership  structure  for  banking  businesses  (Moran  1991,  p12).  Formerly  closely  owned  private  companies  and  partnerships,  which  used  to  risk  their  own  funds  gave  way  to  ever-­‐larger  PLCs    (Moran  1991,  pp12,  68-­‐69),  whose  traders  could  gamble  with  other  peoples’  money.        

As  we  explored  in  chapter  2,  since  increased  borrowing  does  not  prejudice  a  bank’s  ability  to  return  value  to  shareholders,  banks  were  encouraged  to  increase  their  asset  base  thus  increasing  their  scope  for  lending  and  fee  generation.  Even  only  marginal  or  nominal  returns  made  on  increased  lending,  enabled  banks  to  boost  the  returns  on  the  tiny  amounts  of  equity  they  retained.  Banks  were  thus  encouraged  not  only  to  leverage  to  great  heights  but  also  to  take  large  risks  for  small  returns  on  their  assets  (CRESC,  2009,  p44)  becoming  what  Haldane  (2011)  called  ‘volatility  junkies’.  This  propensity  for  both  growth  and  risk  was  also  encouraged  by  the  implicit  state  subsidy  underpinning  banks  solvency:  whilst  the  state  becomes  a  significant  stakeholder  in  banks,  their  implicit  subsidy  all  the  while  encouraged  banks  to  take  risks  which  imperilled  that  stake-­‐holding,  engaging  in  risky  operations  for  relatively  low  returns  on  assets,  in  order  to  return  value  to  shareholders  knowing  the  state  would  not  allow  bank  losses  to  result  in  insolvency  (Haldane,  2015).    

Political  championing  of  banking  giants  and  a  big  city  also  encouraged  the  growth  in  IB  operations.  The  state,  whose  central  bankers  were  already  distrustful  of  smaller  banks  (Reid,  1988),  cheered  on  the  growth  of  financial  giants  by  pushing  for  foreign  investment  and  growth  of  the  City  (Moran,  1991,  p124).  The  state’s  experimentation  with  free  market  ideology  undermined  its  incentives  and  capacity  to  monitor  and  control  IB  operations.  Believing  that  financial  and  macroeconomic  stability  flowed  from  low  and  stable  inflation,  policy  makers  and  central  bankers  encouraged  the  deepening  of  financial  markets,  leaving  bank  activity  to  free  market  forces.  The  International  Monetary  Fund’s  (IMF)  Chief  Economist  assumed  risk  had  been  more  safely  dispersed  through  the  system  and  that  the  IMF  could  ignore  much  of  the  details  of  the  financial  system  (IMF,  2006;  Turner,  2016,  p170).  Innovations  which  increased  liquidity  or  made  it  easier  to  hedge  against  risks,  were  deemed  desirable  –  despite  the  fact  that  they  made  it  simultaneously  easier  for  economic  agents  to  take  positions  in  other  words  to  place  bets  which  could  radically  increase  the  

Page 69: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  69  

volatility  against  which  such  innovations  were  attempting  to  hedge  (Turner,  2016,  p194).    

Rising  economic  wellbeing,  albeit  illusory  and  founded  upon  unsustainable  conjunctural  upswing,  confounded  the  delusion  that  markets  could  be  left  to  run  free,  and  that  the  banking  market  did  not  require  careful  oversight.  The  President  of  the  American  Economic  Association,  Robert  Lucas  in  2003  declared:  ‘the  central  problem  of  depression  prevention  has  been  solved’.  In  2006,  like  Gordon  Brown  who  famously  later  declared  there  would  be  no  return  to  boom  and  bust  (Summers,  2008),  the  IMF  declared  that  free  financial  markets  had  brought  about  ‘increased  resilience  of  the  financial  system’  and  considered  that  ‘banks  may  be  less  vulnerable  today  to  credit  or  economic  shocks’  (IMF,  2006).      

4.4.1     Lax  competition  control    As  was  observed  by  the  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  

Standards,  the  state’s  minimally  interventionist  and  light-­‐touch  regulatory  approach  was  not  only  concerned  with  direct  regulation,  but  also  influenced  competition  policy  (2013b,p160).  Provided  the  banks  did  not  collude,  the  state  was  happy  for  banks  to  grow  to  dominant  sizes  and  the  market  to  concentrate  into  an  oligopoly  without  much  competition  control  (PCBS,  2013,  p160,  paras152,  167,  309-­‐313,  and  334).  These  banking  giants  became  increasingly  insulated  from  competition  by  challenger  banks  as  the  banking  market  consolidated  resulting  in  significant  barriers  to  entry  and  creating  an  effective  oligopoly  with  significant  competitive  advantages  for  the  big  dominant  banks  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras.167,  309-­‐313,  334).    

Benefitting  from  their  more  lucrative  IB  operations,  the  biggest  banks  could  afford  to  keep  large  and  costly  branch  networks  and  could  afford  to  maintain  free-­‐whilst-­‐in-­‐credit  banking  services.  The  high  operating  costs  and  need  for  a  branch  network  disadvantaged  smaller  banks  forming  something  of  a  barrier  to  entry  which  insulated  the  bigger  players  from  retail  competition  (CRESC,  2009,  p51).  These  dynamics  inadvertently  discriminated  against  smaller  more  conservative  banks  such  as  the  Co-­‐op,  which  lacked  the  branches  to  compete  against  the  Big  Four  in  the  domestic  retail  market  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p94).    The  smaller  banks  that  depended  on  others  for  clearing  services  were  put  to  further  disadvantages  by  having  to  pay  high  costs  for  such  clearing  services  and  by  the  relatively  higher  cost  of  deposit  insurance  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras.309-­‐314,  334).    

Mutuals  and  building  societies  operating  not  in  pursuit  of  high  shareholder  value  thus  found  it  more  difficult  to  do  well  because  they  lacked  the  crossover  subsidy  from  wholesale  and  IB  and  they  did  not  enjoy  the  incumbent  positions  of  having  large  branch  networks.  They  tended  to  make  lower  net  interest  margins  (CRESC,  2009,  p52)  and  being  building  societies  were  limited  in  how  they  could  grow  their  assets  and  what  new  business  they  could  transact.  They  consequently  found  it  more  difficult  to  grow  their  assets  and  branches  on  the  scale  required  to  compete  with  bigger  retail  banks.  The  growth  of  banking  conglomerates  thus  created:  

‘an  unlevel  playing  field  which  systematically  disadvantaged  mutual  and  smaller  firms  [who  also]  pay  higher  costs  of  deposit  insurance  and  all  smaller  banks  are  handicapped  by  the  requirement  to  buy  clearing  services  from  an  existing  clearing  bank.  The  

Page 70: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  70  

incumbent  major  PLC  banks  are  protected  by  their  branch  systems  which  are  both  barrier  to  entry  and  a  basis  for  cross  selling  to  a  customer  base  which  is  still  more  likely  to  divorce  than  to  switch  current  account  provider’    (CRESC,  2009,  pp7-­‐8).    The  consequences  of  this  oligopoly  are  that  the  Big  Four  were  able  to  

restrain  competition  by  smaller  competitors,  who  were  forced,  by  these  diverse  structural  pressures,  to  follow  their  lead  by  adopting  the  same  behaviours  and  business  practices  in  order  to  survive.      

To  make  matters  worse,  the  competition  authorities  have  allowed  many  large-­‐scale  mergers  within  the  banking  market.  Since  the  1990s  there  has  been  a  significant  consolidation  and  increase  in  size  of  banking  companies.  Indeed,  the  EU  second  banking  directive  1989  encouraged  universal  banking  and  was  permissive  of  growing  national  banking  champions  to  compete  on  the  global  scale.  Whilst  the  CMA  2016  report  recognises  the  stranglehold  enjoyed  by  large  banks  on  the  retail  market,  it  has  not  made  any  inroads  into  breaking  up  this  oligopoly.  Competition  law  is  supposed  to  police  not  only  against  anti-­‐competitive  agreements  between  firms  and  abuses  of  dominant  positions,  but  also  to  encourage  competition  between  competitors,  and  to  protect  smaller  firms  from  unfair  competition.  As  Craig  and  Duburca  put  it:    

 ‘efficiency  is  not  the  only  goal  of  competition  policy.  A  second  objective  [is]  to  protect…  smaller  firms  from  large  aggregations  of  economic  power,  whether  in  the  form  of  the  monopolistic  dominance  by  a  single  firm  or  through  agreements  whereby  rival  firms  coordinate  their  activity  so  as  to  act  as  one  unit’    (2008,  p951).    In  a  banking  market  which  is  highly  concentrated  where  the  dominant  

players  are  over-­‐leveraged  and  better-­‐subsidized  by  dint  of  being  too  big  to  fail,  pressures  are  brought  to  bear  on  smaller  peers,  and  new  entrants,  who  have  incentives  to  mimic  the  behaviours  of  the  less  ethical  banks,  becoming  exploitative  and  adopting  excessive  risks  in  pursuit  of  growth  and  market  access.        

 

4.5   Part  4:  the  shift  towards  exploiting  retail  customers        Whilst  the  Big  Bang  de-­‐compartmentalised  finance,  it  did  not  break  up  the  

oligopoly  of  the  large  high  street  banks,  and  it  did  not  regulate  how  retail  banks  served  their  customers.  At  one  and  the  same  time  the  Big  Bang  permitted  high  street  banks  to  engage  in  new  and  other  areas  of  banking,  but  also  exposed  them  to  new  risks  and  potentially  new  competition  thus  incentivizing  them  to  generate  income  from  less  traditional  lines  of  business.  Retail  banks  found  themselves  pitched  side  by  side  with  all  manner  of  other  financial  businesses  in  essentially  the  same  race  and  prone  to  the  same  urgent  need  to  re-­‐think  how  to  exploit  new  opportunities  to  cover  their  costs  and  keep  ahead  of  the  competition.      For  retail  banks,  these  costs  were  particularly  high,  and  necessarily  so.    

In  retail  banking,  market  share  very  closely  correlates  with  the  size  of  a  bank’s  branch  network.  To  retain  and  increase  market  share,  retail  banks  are  forced  to  retain  and  even  grow  their  costly  branch  network  (Bowman  et  al  2014).  Although  most  banks  tried  to  move  away  from  branch  banking  and  to  usher  in  a  new  system  of  internet  banking,  those  endeavours  largely  failed  and  

Page 71: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  71  

still  today  the  extent  of  a  bank’s  branch  network  largely  determines  their  market  share.  For  example  the  big  four  retail  banks–  Lloyds,  the  Royal  Bank  of  Scotland,  HSBC  and  Barclays  –  now  control,  as  a  result  of  their  effective  strangle-­‐hold  on  retail  branches,  more  than  three-­‐quarters  of  Britain’s  personal  current  accounts  (Competition  and  Markets  Authority,  2016).    

Retaining  this  branch  network  is  all  the  more  costly  for  retail  banks  when  the  current  paradigm  retains  expectations  for  free-­‐whilst-­‐in-­‐credit  banking  services.  The  delivery  of  these  two  costly  products  –branches  and  core  banking  services  –  if  they  are  to  be  delivered  free  of  charge,  place  considerable  strain  on  retail  banks  to  cover  costs  in  other  ways  (Competition  and  Markets  Authority,  2016;  Bowman  et  al  2014,  p94).  Along  with  secular  low  interest  rates  ultimately  destroying  margins  in  traditional  intermediation  (CRESC,  2009,  p40),  these  pressures  have  forced  banks  to  exploit  their  branch  networks  as  sales-­‐points  for  selling  other  services  (CRESC,  2009,  pp40-­‐42).    

Universally  and  regardless  of  their  ownership  model,  retail  banks  have  responded  to  these  pressures  by  aggressively  selling,  even  mis-­‐selling  products  to  their  customers  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p11;  CRESC,  2009,  pp50-­‐52).    Branches  have  become  selling  points  not  only  for  mortgages  and  property-­‐backed  loans,  but  also  for  other  products  which  can  be  sold  profitably  to  customers  including  pensions,  and  insurance  products,  and  not  least  PPI,  and  interest  rates  swaps  –  often  products  which  customers  have  no  need  for.  In  turning  banks  into  selling  points,  a  deal-­‐making  and  sales-­‐oriented  culture  has  emerged  in  retail  banking,  adopting  the  same  incentives  more  typically  found  in  IB  such  as  incentivized  targets,  and  bonus  and  commission  schemes  (CRESC,  2009,  p51;  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards,  2013b,  paras.116,  119,  519,  and  536).      

This  shift  into  sales-­‐dominated  retail  behaviour  is  a  part  of  what  CRESC  (2009,  p42)  characterised  as  the  shift  into  becoming  ‘giant  transaction  making  machines’  where  banks  take  fees  on  a  large  volume  of  transactions,  ramping  up  the  scale  and  scope  of  their  retail  activities  often  to  feed  wholesale  lending  and  borrowing  (CRESC,  2009,  p42).  Retail  banks  have  thus  shifted  away  from  being  cautious  intermediaries  serving  the  interests  of  their  customers,  and  have  increasingly  become  self-­‐serving,  often  exploitative,  in  it  ‘for  themselves’  (CRESC,  2009,  p42;  Engelen  et  al,  2011,  p159).    

In  addition  to  the  pressures  arising  from  needing  to  recover  high  branch  costs  in  a  low  interest  environment,  there  is  another  structural  pressure  incentivizing  this  shift  in  business  model.  Fee-­‐generating  products  are  generally  not  risk-­‐weighted  under  the  Basel  regime  and  they  can  therefore  be  sold  in  large  volumes  without  requiring  capital  reserves  and  they  thus  do  not  disturb  bank  equity,  meaning  that  their  sales  enhance  returns  on  equity  (Ertürk,  2015).    

   

4.6   Conclusions      The  main  structural  pressures  considered  in  this  chapter  have  arisen  as  a  

result  of  the  changes  brought  about  in  the  Big  Bang.  With  the  onset  of  neoliberalism,  responsibility  for  industrial  policy  and  planning  was  increasingly  abrogated  in  favour  of  free  market  forces,  and  the  real  economy  underwent  a  process  of  de-­‐industrialization.  We  witnessed  how  within  that  climate  banks  

Page 72: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  72  

were  forced  to  seek  out  profits  from  new  and  untraditional  sources.    So  long  as  the  broader  structure  and  regulation  of  the  economy  remain  unchanged,  the  structural  pressures  considered  in  this  chapter  are  liable  to  remain  in  play.  

It  was  observed  in  this  chapter  that  an  increasing  number  of  academics  and  policymakers  have  argued  for  radical  change,  seeking  to  revisit  the  relationship  struck  between  finance,  market  and  state  in  the  Big  Bang.  Many  have  argued  that  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  cannot  sensibly  be  left  to  be  determined  by  free  market  forces,  and  that  the  state  needs  to  exert  greater  control  over  these  functions  (Wolf,  2014b,  2014c;  Turner,  2016,  p109).  It  is  increasingly  also  argued  that  we  need  to  decide  what  activities  we  want  banks  to  finance  more  generously,  or  not  to  finance,  and  to  adjust  regulation  to  achieve  such  ends  (Bower  et  al,  2014,  p6;  Turner,  2016,  pp193-­‐195).  Some  have  argued  that  regulation  needs  to  ensure  that  credit  is  directed  to  finance  more  useful  capital  investments  capable  of  producing  the  additional  wealth  required  by  society  to  repay  our  debts  (Turner  20156,  pp61-­‐63;  Kay  2015,  pp428,  299).    

Whilst  calls  for  greater  productive  investment  have  found  favour  amongst  some  in  the  Labour  Party,  resulting  in  a  recent  manifesto  pledge  to  capitalise  a  large  National  Investment  Bank  (Labour  Party,  2017),  they  have  not  impacted  upon  the  government  reform  agenda,  which  remains  stubbornly  committed  to  the  same  political-­‐economic  experiment  the  state  has  been  invested  in  since  the  1980s  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  p13;  PCBS,  2013b,  paras.190,  237,  247).  Still  captivated  by  free-­‐market  ideology  and  lacking  any  alternative  vision  in  a  productive  economy,  the  state  seems  to  suffer  from  something  of  an    ‘inertia  of  faith’,  held  captive  by  delusional  beliefs  that  credit-­‐creation  can  be  best  determined  by  private  competition  and  that  any  economic  failure  is  merely  a  result  of  inadequate  execution  of  that  policy  (Bowman  et  al,  2014,  ch.5;  Turner,  2016,  p100).    As  we  observed  in  chapter  2,  the  reform  agenda  has  completely  ignored  calls  which  challenge  the  ideological  status  quo.  The  official  response  was  explicitly  committed  to  making  London  the  epi-­‐centre  of  global  finance  (PCBS,  2013b,  para.237)  and  did  not  consider  what  types  of  activities  the  UK  needed  to  be  more  generously  financed  by  banking.  It  went  about  implementing  reforms  which  minimally  disrupt  the  banking  sector’s  free  scope  for  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation.      

Consequently,  without  changing  the  structure  and  regulation  of  the  broader  economy,  the  same  structural  pressures  are  likely  to  encourage  banks  to  engage  in  the  same  dangerous  activities  which  led  to  the  financial  crisis  and  which  are  likely  to  lead  to  further  crises  (Wolf,  2014a,  2014b,  2014c,  chs8-­‐9;  Brummer,  2015,  pp299-­‐301;  King,  2016,  ch.9;  Turner,  2016,  ch.12).  The  main  drivers  which  encouraged  the  global  financial  crisis  in  the  first  place  remain  in  play  :  banks  are  still  too  big,  their  remuneration  system  and  shareholder  value  governance  continue  to  provide  incentives  to  leverage,  engage  in  excessively  risky  business,  they  consequently  have  every  incentive  to  exploit  their  customers,  and  to  pump  out  too  much  credit  and  to  allocate  it  in  unproductive  ways  and  ways  which  are  liable  to  cause  unstable  cycles  (Turner  2016,  pp173-­‐175,  245-­‐246).    

A  lot  of  the  structural  pressures  considered  in  this  chapter  are  indiscriminate  to  ownership  forms  –  they  encourage  bad  banking  regardless  of  how  banks  are  owned.    Before  exploring  in  more  depth  how  ownership  pressures  influence  behaviour  in  the  context  of  the  case  studies  performed  by  

Page 73: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  73  

this  thesis,  the  next  chapter  will  consider  more  carefully  how  ownership  pressures  can  be  distinguished  from  structural  pressures  so  that  the  former  can  be  more  closely  analysed.        

 

   

 

 

   

Page 74: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  74  

 

Chapter  5. Methodology      5.1     Introduction    

This  chapter  aims  to  clarify  how  the  thesis  has  addressed  the  overarching  thesis  inquiry,  namely  how  ownership  affects  behaviour.  It  is  clear  from  the  preceding  chapter,  that  ‘ownership’  is  not  the  only  phenomenon  influencing  bank  behaviour  and  that  there  are  all  sorts  of  ‘structural  pressures’  arising  from  the  market  and  regulatory  conditions  within  which  banks  operate  which  also  affect  their  behaviour.  Differentiating  these  different  behavioural  drivers  and  distinguishing  their  various  effects  presents  some  significant  methodological  challenges.  The  purpose  of  this  chapter  is  to  clarify  and  justify  what  methodology  will  be  adopted  in  this  thesis  and  particularly  in  the  following  empirical  research  chapters  to  explore  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour  in  banks.        

The  chapter  is  broken  down  into  five  parts.  The  first  part  begins  with  a  reflection  on  epistemology  and  ontology,  and  clarifies  what  epistemological  and  ontological  stance  is  adopted  by  the  thesis.  The  second  part  then  clarifies  what  inquiry  is  being  made  by  the  thesis  and  what  the  main  thesis  questions  are.  A  third  part  then  explains  what  methodological  framework  is  being  adopted  in  order  to  perform  such  inquiry,  clarifying  what  conceptual  structure  will  be  used  to  gather  and  analyse  the  data  and  materials.  This  part  also  discusses  why  such  methods  are  considered  appropriate.  A  fourth  part  then  contains  a  more  specific  discussion  about  how  the  research  is  designed,  discussing  in  particular  what  cases  have  been  chosen,  what  sources  and  data  will  be  explored  and  why.  This  part  also  clarifies  the  lexicon  and  terminology  employed  throughout  the  thesis.  Finally,  the  fifth,  concluding  part  summarises  the  research  strategy  adopted  and  it  justifies  the  choices  made  in  the  research  depicting  the  same  diagrammatically  in  a  ‘research  onion’  made  popular  by  Saunders  et  al  (2007).  This  part  thus  summarises  why  the  thesis  has  adopted  a  social  ontology  and  critical-­‐realist  epistemology,  and  chosen  to  perform  an  exploratory  case  study  using  quantitative  and  qualitative  data  of  a  primary  and  secondary  nature.        

5.2     Part  1:  The  ontological  and  epistemological  framework      The  way  we  think  of  the  world  (ontology)  influences:  what  we  think  can  be  known  about  it  (epistemology):  how  we  think  it  can  be  investigated  (methodology)  and  the  kind  of  theories  and  knowledge  claims  we  think  can  be  constructed  about  it  (Fleetwood  and  Ackroyd,  2005)  

 As  Fleetwood  and  Ackroyd  (2005)  observe,  how  we  think  about  reality  

affects  what  we  can  understand  about  it,  and  how  we  can  go  about  investigating  it.    Ontology,  that  is  the  philosophical  study  of  the  nature  of  reality,  beings  and  their  relationship,  is  regularly  concerned  with  questions  about  what  entities  or  systems  exist  or  can  be  said  to  exist  and  how  such  entities  or  systems  may  be  grouped,  and  related  within  an  hierarchy,  and  subdivided  according  to  their  similarities  and  differences  (Fleetwood  and  Ackroyd,  2005).  This  thesis  adopts  a  

Page 75: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  75  

‘social  ontology’  (Archer  et  al,  1998).  It  recognizes  that  banks  are  social  constructs  (Haldane,  2015),  and  the  form  that  they  take  and  how  they  are  regulated,  are  not  inevitable  arrangements  but  rather  settled  upon  through  the  exercise  of  state  power.    What  society  can  create,  can  also  be  changed,  and  in  ways  which  aim  to  obtain  behaviours  more  beneficial  for  society  (Bourdieu,  1977;  Hurrelmann,  1988;  Hurrelmann,  2009;  Haldane  2014).      

Within  that  framework  of  beliefs  or  ‘social  ontology’,  the  thesis  then  adopts  an  epistemological  approach  of  ‘critical  realism’  (Bhaskar,  1978).  Bhaskar’s  ‘critical  realism’  explores  the  interface  between  the  ‘natural’  and  ‘social’  worlds,  by  combining  a  transcendental  realist  theory  of  science  with  a  critical  naturalist  social  philosophy  of  social  sciences  (Bhaskar,  1986).  Whereas  the  essential  premise  of  ‘realism’  maintains  that  there  is  an  independent  reality  of  being  which  transcends  the  relative  bounds  of  human  knowledge  and  interaction,  ‘critical’  natural  philosophy  recognizes  that  studying  the  human  world  is  fundamentally  different  from  studying  the  natural  world  and  calls  for  the  adaptation  of  different  strategies  (Bhaskar,  1979).    

Critical  realism  does  not  require  a  constant  conjunctive  relationship  between  events  in  order  to  establish  causal  relationships,  but  seeks  instead  to  identify  causalities  at  the  level  of  generative  mechanisms,  recognizing  that  there  is  or  may  be  greater  flux  in  the  social  world  than  in  the  physical  one,  and  that  individuals  who  inhabit  social  structures  can  themselves  reflect  upon  and  change  their  behaviour  (Bhaskar,  1979).  The  Bhaskarian  approach  is  essentially  non-­‐reductivist.  It  acknowledges  the  enormous  complexity  of  the  world,  and  rather  than  seeking  to  reduce  any  exploration  into  a  single  hermeneutic,  it  combines  together  different  ways  of  looking  at  things,  providing  a  variable  appreciation  of  both  ‘realism’  and  ‘critical’  inquiry  (Bhaskar,  1986).      

This  epistemology  is  particularly  appropriate  for  approaching  an  inquiry  into  the  different  drivers  affecting  bank  behaviour  and  the  particular  relevance  of  ‘ownership’  related  drivers.  Any  inquiry  into  bank  behaviour  is  necessarily  complicated  by  the  highly  structured  and  stratified  nature  of  banking,  which  involves  huge  social  constructs  organizing  vast  numbers  of  human  agencies,  run  and  regulated  according  to  different  and  differing  aims,  values  and  rules.  Critical  realism  is  commonly  considered  to  be  apt  for  performing  inquiring  into  events  and  circumstances  which  are  themselves  the  result  of  multiple  generative  mechanisms  (Denmark  et  al,  1997).    Not  only  are  banks  large  and  complex,  but  the  object  this  thesis  wishes  to  study  namely  ‘behaviour’  or  rather  ‘mis-­‐behaviour’  is  itself  largely  irreducible,  as  it  arises  out  of  the  relationship  and  interplay  between  various  conditions,  structures  and  generative  mechanisms,  and  not  merely  the  condition  of  ‘ownership’.    

Adopting  a  social  ontological  belief  and  an  approach  of  critical  realism  provides  the  thesis  with  the  best  tools  to  explore  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  misbehaviour.  Such  ontology  and  epistemology  allow  this  subject  to  be  approached  holistically  without  calling  for  the  arbitrary  application  of  singular  hermeneutics  to  define  the  transcendental  reality  of  social  structures,  our  experience  of  them  and  the  empirical  layer  of  perceived  reality.    

Page 76: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  76  

 

 

5.3     Part  2:  The  essential  inquiry    

Before  considering  and  justifying  the  choice  of  methodology,  it  is  necessary  first  to  clarify  why  such  inquiry  is  being  performed  and  what  specific  questions  will  be  asked.  As  was  touched  upon  in  chapter  1,  the  motivation  for  writing  this  thesis  stems  from  an  interest  in  stakeholder  governance  and  more  particularly  the  type  of  social  purpose  not-­‐for-­‐profit  which  Hansmann  considered  back  in  the  1980s  (1980,  1981,  1988)  and  which  more  recently  Bøhren  et  al  described  as  ‘ownerless’  organisations  (2013).  Hansmann  claimed  that  organizations  which  were  not  ‘owned’  and  which  did  not  distribute  their  proceeds  to  outsiders  or  to  members  but  which  recycled  such  proceeds  by  continually  applying  and  re-­‐applying  them  to  meet  the  organizations’  aims,  behaved  more  responsibly  than  organizations  which  were  owned  by  outsiders  as  their  interest  in  extracting  profits  provided  incentives  for  them  to  compromise  their  behaviour  in  the  pursuit  of  profits  (Hansmann,  1980,  1981,  1988).    

Hansmann  considered  also  a  particular  type  of  stakeholder  model  which  was  not  owned  by  and  for  the  benefit  of  its  members,  but  which  was  run  for  the  benefit  of  its  social  purposes,  and  he  argued  that  social  purpose  non-­‐profits  were  better  placed  to  operate  in  sectors  where  there  is  scope  for  the  pursuit  of  profit  to  otherwise  lead  to  exploitation  for  example  where  customers  are  in  a  position  of  vulnerability  or  where  the  trader  enjoys  a  disparity  of  power  because  of  informational  asymmetries  relating  to  their  products  or  services  (Hansmann,  1980,  1981,  1988).  He  argued  that  such  organizations  are  apt  to  perform  social  purposes  and  can  make  a  better  and  more  efficient  allocation  of  resources  towards  meeting  such  aims  because  they  prevent  profits  being  distributed  to  owners  and  require  them  instead  to  be  dedicated  to  meeting  the  organizations’  aims.  Hansmann’s  claims  (1980,  1981,  1988)  became  all  the  more  topical  in  the  wake  of  banking  failures  and  the  global  financial  crisis  when  regulators,  politicians  and  commentators  increasingly  began  to  observe  that  banks  had  behaved  badly  (PCBS,  2013a,  2013b;  Brummer,  2015).  This  behavioural  deficit  was  not  simply  about  the  ways  they  had  treated  their  customers,  but  also  involved  a  departure  away  from  the  role  many  expect  banks  to  perform  in  providing  productive  investment  and  into  unproductive  and  harmful  investments  which  have  helped  to  cause  or  contribute  towards  economic  problems  and  ultimately  posed  costs  for  the  tax-­‐payer  (Turner,  2016,  pp172-­‐174,  193-­‐199,  245-­‐246).  

The  inquiry  motivating  this  thesis  was  thus  concerned  with  whether  banks  would  behave  better  if  they  were  not  shareholder-­‐owned  but  were  more  like  the  social  purpose  not-­‐for-­‐profits  Hansmann  considered,  or  what  Bøhren  et  al  (2013)  more  recently  called  ‘ownerless’  organizations.  The  need  for  such  inquiry  was  made  greater  by  the  absence  of  any  serious  attempt  in  the  banking  reform  debate  to  think  about  ownership  issues.  As  we  explored  in  chapter  2,  the  banking  reform  debate,  which  was  largely  an  elite-­‐driven  affair,  was  seemingly  intent  on  preserving  the  status  quo  and  the  power  of  the  City,  and  it  tended  to  avoid  the  subject  of  ‘ownership’  altogether.  This  omission  was  somewhat  startling,  especially  since,  as  we  have  learned  in  chapters  1  and  3,  it  is  now  

Page 77: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  77  

increasingly  recognized  that  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  tend  to  pose  serious  problems  in  terms  of  behaviour  and  performance.    In  the  UK,  the  mainstream  banks  are  all  shareholder-­‐owned  and  in  other  words  their  shares  are  publicly  traded.  There  are  no  examples  on  the  high  street  of  any  ownerless  banks  or  what  might  otherwise  be  referred  to  as  ‘social  purpose,  not-­‐for-­‐profit’  banks.  It  would  be  extremely  difficult  therefore  to  perform  an  inquiry  into  whether  such  model  would  behave  better  than  differently  owned  banks  because  there  are  no  subjects  to  study,  or  at  least  not  in  this  country,  and  it  is  difficult  to  consider  how  an  ownerless  bank  might  behave  in  a  vacuum.    

In  banking,  there  are  what  Bhaskar  referred  to  as  many  other  ‘generative  mechanisms’  which  also  influence  behaviour.  Indeed,  what  emerged  from  the  literature  reviewed  in  chapter  4  was  the  clear  realization  that  structural  pressures  arising  from  the  market  and  regulatory  environment  within  which  banks  operate  can  also  have  a  strong  bearing  and  influence  on  bank  conduct.  Recent  history  has  shown  that  serious  behavioural  issues  have  arisen  in  stakeholder  banks  which  are  apparently  free  from  the  types  of  ownership  pressures  explored  in  chapter  3.  It  is  necessarily  difficult  to  differentiate  these  different  drivers  influencing  behaviour  and  to  consider  their  various  affects.      Nevertheless,  stakeholder  banks  which  encountered  or  avoided  behavioural  problems  and  which  were  apparently  free  from  ownership  pressures  presented  obvious  opportunities  to  inquire  into  how  ‘structural  pressures’  as  distinct  from  ‘ownership  pressures’  affected  behaviour.      

Because  there  are  no  ownerless  banks  in  the  UK,  the  thesis  inquiry  has  necessarily  been  broadened  to  consider  the  relevance  of  ownership  in  stakeholder-­‐owned  and  shareholder-­‐owned  banks.    This  thesis  seeks  in  general  terms  to  explore  the  relationship  between  the  ownership  of  banks  and  their  behaviour.  It  questions  whether  other  ownership  models  other  than  the  shareholder-­‐ownership  can  encourage  more  desirable  behaviours  in  banks,  and  it  inquires  into  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour  whilst  considering  how  conduct  is  also  influenced  by  other  drivers  or  ‘generative  mechanisms’,  and  in  particular  the  sorts  of  structural  pressures  identified  in  chapter  4.  The  thesis  tries  to  look  at  how  bank  behaviour  is  affected  by  pressures  arising  from  the  way  banks  are  owned  (which  are  referred  to  as  ‘ownership  pressures’)  whilst  also  bearing  in  mind  how  such  actions  can  be  affected  by  pressures  which  arise  in  other  ways  unrelated  to  how  banks  are  owned  out  of  the  structure  of  the  market  and  regulatory  environment  within  which  banks  operate  (which  are  called  ‘structural  pressures’).    

The  thesis  therefore  addresses  three  questions.  The  first  two  are  primary  questions  concerned  with  exploring  the  drivers  of  mis-­‐behaviour,  while  the  third  question  is  a  reflective  follow-­‐up  question  intended  to  explore  the  implications  of  the  earlier  analysis:    (1)     how  does  the  way  banks  are  owned  affect  their  behaviour?    (2)     how  do  other  pressures  arising  out  of  the  market  and  regulatory  

environments  within  which  banks  operate  affect  behaviour?      (3)     what  are  the  implications  for  banking  reform,  in  particular  in  terms  of  

ownership?          

Page 78: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  78  

5.4     Part  3:  The  methodological  framework    This  thesis  adopts  a  case  study  methodology  to  inquire  empirically  into  

behavioural  phenomena  within  a  number  of  existing  mainstream  UK  banks.  It  seeks  to  explore  how  behaviour  is  affected  by  ownership  pressures  arising  from  a  bank’s  ownership  model  and  how  behaviour  is  affected  by  other  structural  pressures  unrelated  to  ownership.  It  tries  to  do  this  by  studying  a  selection  of  banks  which  can  be  described  as  having  different  ownership  models,  and  whose  behaviour  has  been  remarkable  in  different  ways.    

It  is  considered  that  a  case  study  methodology  is  particularly  apt  for  exploring  the  issues  in  this  thesis  for  three  reasons.  First,  how  ‘behaviour’  is  affected  by  different  influences  is  largely  irreducible  phenomenon.  The  extent  to  which  different  drivers  cause  different  behaviours  cannot  readily  be  separated  out  from  one  another,  and  measured  in  isolation.  The  case  study  methodology  permits  an  holistic  approach  where  multiple  different  generative  mechanisms  need  to  be  considered.  Case  studies  are  generally  considered  to  be  useful  for  conducting  empirical  inquiries  into  phenomena  within  a  real-­‐life  context  where  it  is  difficult  to  separate  out  certain  phenomena  or  to  distinguish  what  causes  such  phenomena  from  other  causes  (Yin  et  al,  1984,  p23).    For  example,  they  are  a  useful  way  of  studying  phenomena  and  their  causes  within  social  constructs  (Yin,  2014).  Whereas  experiments  call  for  phenomena  to  be  isolated  from  the  context  within  which  they  arise  and  can  focus  on  only  a  limited  number  of  variables,  a  case  study  allows  an  inquiry  into  phenomena  within  a  real  life  context  where  it  is  not  possible  or  easy  to  isolate  the  same  from  their  context  (Yin  et  al,1984,  p23).        

Second,  this  methodology  permits  a  theory-­‐exploring  framework,  and  is  not  limited  to  testing  a  singular  proposition.  Whereas  quantitative  research  methods  are  limited  in  how  they  can  provide  holistic  and  in-­‐depth  explanations  for  behavioural  problems,  case  studies  permit  greater  flexibility  in  how  data  and  sources  can  be  evaluated  against  different  claims  and  theorems  (McDonough  et  al,  1997).  The  case  study  methodology  is  extremely  flexible  in  the  way  cases  can  be  structured  to  develop,  explore  and  build  theories  (Yin,  2014).  Case-­‐study  research  can  involve  multiple  case  studies,  and  importantly  it  can  benefit  from  the  prior  development  of  theoretical  propositions    (Yin,  2014).  In  other  words,  case  studies  need  not  be  limited  to  testing  fixed  propositions  but  can  be  useful  for  exploring  and  building  on  existing  theories  and  narratives,  and  developing  new  theories  or  narratives  alongside  existing  ones.    

This  method  thus  appears  apt  for  the  inquiries  made  in  this  thesis,  whose  questions  cannot  be  precisely  answered  in  quantifiable  terms  but  call  more  generally  for  discursive  and  qualitative  explanation.    The  underlying  claims  which  the  inquiry  seeks  to  test  –  how  the  shareholder-­‐ownership  model  drives  behaviour,  and  how  stakeholder-­‐ownership  models  might  encourage  better  behaviours  –  have  already  been  made  by  others,  and  are  incapable  of  being  proven  or  disproven  in  absolute  terms.  Rather  they  call  to  be  explored  within  an  holistic  approach  alongside  other  and  conflicting  claims  and  ideas.  The  case  study  allows  these  questions  to  be  explored  alongside  other  claims  and  ideas  including  the  claim  that  shareholder-­‐owned  models  provide  more  effective  governance  regimes  than  stakeholder-­‐owned  models,  or  indeed  Hansmann’s  

Page 79: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  79  

claim  (1980,  1981,  1988)  that  a  social-­‐purpose  not-­‐for-­‐profit  which  does  not  have  owners  is  better  at  encouraging  sustainable  behaviours.    

The  case  study  methodology  thus  allows  this  thesis  not  only  to  bear  in  mind  Hansmann’s  claims  about  social  purpose  not-­‐for-­‐profits  being  more  responsible  in  sectors  of  activity  where  customers  might  otherwise  be  vulnerable  to  being  exploited  by  profit-­‐maximising  incentives  (1980,  1981,  1988),  but  also  to  considers  the  claims  made  by  Kay  (2015,  pp248,  299)  and  Turner  (2016,  pp61-­‐63)  about  banks  failing  to  perform  the  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  functions  we  should  expect  of  them.  As  well  as  considering  the  effects  of  ownership  on  behaviour,  the  thesis  can  thus  contemplate  the  broader  philosophical  questions  about  what  role  we  want  banks  to  play  in  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  and  to  consider  whether  the  shareholder-­‐ownership  model  is  consistent  with  such  aims.  It  permits  an  inquiry  into  how  the  ownership  model  of  banks  affects  and  influences  their  behaviour  both  in  actual  terms,  and  in  terms  of  the  behaviour  and  functions  we  might  wish  banks  to  perform.  

Third,  the  case  study  methodology  is  flexible  in  how  it  allows  use  of  data  from  disparate  and  overlapping  sources.  This  flexible  framework  allows  different  data  to  be  accumulated  around  different  complex  issues;  this  also  makes  triangulation  possible  from  different  sources.  By  including  both  quantitative  and  qualitative  data,  case  studies  allow  behavioural  phenomenon  to  be  observed  more  closely  to  their  context  and  more  completely  (Tellis,  1997).    

In  summary,  this  methodology  permits  an  in-­‐depth  insight  into  the  relationship  between  ‘ownership’  and  behaviour.  It  considers  different  types  of  ownership  models  which  exist,  or  could  be  created,  and  how  ownership  affects  behaviour  both  in  practice  and  in  terms  of  the  behaviour  and  functions  we  might  wish  banks  to  perform.  At  the  same  time,  the  limits  of  the  case  study  methodology  need  to  be  acknowledged.  Such  methodology  is  commonly  criticized  for  lacking  rigour  and  giving  way  to  biased  views  which  influence  the  direction  of  findings  and  conclusions  (Yin  et  al,  1984,  p21).  It  is  also  often  criticized  for  considering  too  small  a  pool  of  subjects  (Tellis,  1997).  As  Yin  put  it:  ‘How  can  you  generalize  from  a  single  case?’  (Yin  et  al,  1984,  p21).  Many  case  studies  also  suffer  from  being  long-­‐winded  and  produce  massive  amounts  of  documentation,  especially  when  they  are  conducted  in  fields  where  there  is  a  danger  of  data  not  being  managed  or  organized  systematically  (Yin,  1993).      

Nevertheless,  the  advantages  far  outweigh  the  disadvantages  so  far  as  this  thesis  is  concerned,  especially  since  many  of  the  problems  with  case  studies  can  be  overcome  in  the  way  that  the  research  is  designed  (Yin  et  al  1984;  Yin,  1993,  1994).  As  Hamel  et  al  (1993)  observe  the    problem  of  bias  can  be  guarded  against  by  setting  suitable  parameters,  picking  an  appropriate  selection  of  cases  and  establishing  an  objective  research  framework  within  which  to  analyse  findings.      

 

5.4.1   Why  not  other  methodologies?    An  alternative  to  performing  case  study  research,  which  was  considered  

but  dismissed,  was  to  undertake  statistical  analysis  of  financial  data  relating  to  bank  performance  in  order  to  compare  how  banks  with  different  ownership  models  have  performed  over  time.  Another  approach  might  have  been  to  

Page 80: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  80  

imaginatively  model  data  based  upon  how  banks  would  be  expected  to  perform  and  behave  if  they  had  different  ownership  models.  Yet  another,  very  different,  approach  might  have  been  to  engage  in  a  more  abstract  political-­‐economic  and  philosophical  inquiry  into  corporate  governance  and  the  shareholder  versus  stakeholder  debate.      

Of  these  alternative  methodologies  statistical  analysis  and  comparison  was  the  most  attractive  alternative.  The  other  method,  data-­‐modelling,  necessarily  entailed  levels  of  speculation  and  guesswork  which  risks  detracting  from  the  meaningfulness  of  the  research.  And  research  into  the  field  of  corporate  governance  and  the  stakeholder  debate  has  already  been  undertaken  at  great  lengths  by  a  great  number  of  scholars,  and  is  likely  to  harden  into  more  claims  or  counter-­‐claims  than  uncover  any  meaningful  data.  On  the  other  hand,  a  statistical  analysis  and  comparison  of  financial  and  performance  data  from  across  a  range  of  banks  with  different  ownership  models  could  possibly  yield  a  lot  of  meaningful  data,  and  it  might  also  permit  investigation  into  other  types  of  ownership  models,  not  existing  in  the  UK,  including  the  types  of  ‘ownerless’  model  discussed  by  Hansmann  (1980,  1981,  1988)  and  Bøhren  et  al  (2012,  2013)  such  as  the  Spanish  Cajas  or  the  Norwegian  Sparkassen.      

As  was  identified  in  Chapter  1  however,  such  research  has  already  been  performed  by  others,  and  not  least  Ferri  et  al  (2010,  2012).  It  also  poses  its  own  methodological  complications  involving  as  it  does  the  performance  of  banks  across  different  markets,  countries,  and  regions  with  different  regulatory,  economic,  linguistic,  legal  and  political  environments.  Such  a  comparison  would  also  be  limited  to  considering  the  ownership  models  which  actually  exist,  whereas  a  case  study  methodology  allows  the  flexibility  to  contemplate  other  ways  of  owning  banks  and  even  to  conceive  of  legislating  new  models  into  creation.    It  is  possible  for  example  to  conceive  of  a  bank  that  does  not  distribute  its  profits  to  its  owners  or  indeed  its  members,  but  which  applies  its  profits  to  continually  perform  its  investment  aims  and  purposes.    Whilst  the  Spanish  Cajas,  and  the  Norwegian  Sparkassen,  are  manifestations  of  such  ownerless  banks  (Crespí  et  al,  2004;  Bøhren  et  al,  2013),  they  are  limited  in  scale  and  the  area  of  their  activities  and  there  are  many  conceivable  variants  for  creating  other  ownerless  models  to  perform  different  banking  functions.      

The  case  study  approach  was  thus  preferred  over  a  statistical  comparison  not  merely  because  the  former  avoids  the  difficulties  involved  in  comparing  data  from  banks  across  different  markets,  jurisdictions  and  regulatory  environments  but  also  because  that  methodology  is  flexible  and  pragmatic  and  allows  for  in  depth  analysis  whilst  permitting  theory  exploration  and  development.  In  short,  it  permits  the  thesis  to  inquire  concretely  into  how  certain  banks  have  performed  whilst  allowing  it  also  to  contemplate  how  other  ownership  models  might  be  created  to  overcome  problems  encountered  by  the  banks  which  it  explores.    

5.4.2   Limits  of  the  inquiry  and  methodology    The  line  of  march  taken  by  this  thesis  is  concerned  first  and  foremost  with  

the  effects  of  ownership,  and  hence  its  focus  is  on  how  banks  with  different  ownership  models  have  actually  performed  and  behaved.  Whilst  the  thesis  bears  in  mind  ownerless  forms  of  organisation  (Hansmann  1980,  1981,  1988;  Bøhren  

Page 81: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  81  

et  al,  2012,  2013),  it  does  not  seek  to  consider  the  array  of  ownerless  banks  currently  in  existence,  such  as  the  Spanish  Cajas,  whose  failures  tell  a  wholly  different  story  to  the  UK  banks  (Trenlet,  2012),  which  would  call  for  another  type  of  inquiry.    Instead,  the  thesis  recognizes  that  the  task  of  re-­‐engineering  how  banks  are  owned  is  open-­‐ended  and  that  changing  the  current  ownership  model  is  possible,  but  it  does  not  seek  to  tackle  questions  about  how  a  new  ownership  model  should  be  designed  or  how  such  bank  would  be  created  and  capitalized.  Its  focus  is  on  how  ownership  pressures  affect  behaviour  and  how  they  can  be  addressed,  rather  than  on  how  banking  organisations  should  necessarily  be  designed.      

Further  this  thesis  does  not  pretend  that  it  is  capable  of  proving  in  absolute  terms  that  misbehaviour  is  in  fact  caused  by  the  way  banks  are  owned  or  that  any  one  ownership  model  is  behaviourally  superior  to  another.  It  would  not  be  possible,  even  by  increasing  the  number  of  case  studies  to  prove  behavioural  causalities  conclusively  because  an  exploratory  case  study  cannot  be  used  to  prove  or  disprove.  Moreover,  there  are  obvious  limits  to  how  far  generalizations  can  be  made  from  only  a  limited  sample  of  cases.  Causalities  are  necessarily  complex  and  the  methodology  adopted  by  this  thesis  is  unlikely  to  prove  in  absolute  terms  that  mis-­‐behaviour  is  necessarily  caused  by  ownership  pressures  as  opposed  to  other  factors.  Banks  are  huge  organisations  involving  vast  number  of  human  agencies,  pursuing  many  different  aims  and  interests  within  complex  hierarchical,  management  and  regulatory  environments;  relationships  are  partly  about  perception  and  politics  and  they  often  have  to  be  observed  through  proxies,  not  directly.  Rather,  having  identified  ownership  pressures  and  structural  pressures  as  drivers  which  can  influence  behaviour  the  thesis  instead  seeks  to  explore  how  they  do  so,  by  considering  relevant  evidence  which  tends  to  suggest  that  behaviour  is  or  is  not  affected  by  such  influences.    

The  focus  of  the  thesis  is  also  directed  on  the  importance  of  ‘ownership’  on  behaviour,  rather  than  other  factors.  Whilst  it  is  necessary  to  distinguish  other  structural  pressures  which  also  influence  behaviour,  these  are  secondary  concerns,  arising  necessarily  in  order  to  explore  the  relationship  between  ownership  and  behaviour.  Therefore,  the  thesis  does  not  set  about  cataloguing,  exploring  and  attempting  to  measure  all  of  the  possible  structural  pressures.  Had  the  thesis  been  interested  in  exploring  the  impact  and  behavioural  affects  of  monetary  policy,  or  regulatory  reform,  or  capital  adequacy  requirements,  the  research  would  have  been  designed  in  different  ways.    Furthermore,  the  thesis  is  not  concerned  with  the  adequacy  of  the  various  reform  measures  which  have  been  taken,  particularly  relating  to  capital  reserves  and  capital  adequacy,  which  have  been  the  subject  of  other  inquiries.  As  such,  it  does  not  apply  statistical  analysis  or  modelling  which  would  be  required  to  stress  test  the  lending  and  borrowing  platforms  of  differently  capitalized  banks.    

The  case  study  methodology  is  also  necessarily  limited  by  the  types  of  sources  of  data  available.    The  different  sources  each  have  their  limitations.  In  the  cases  studied  in  this  thesis,  a  variety  of  sources  will  be  called  upon  including  academic  publications,  official  inquiries,  commentary  from  financial  commentators  and  journalists,  and  statistical  data  collected  from  third  party  analysts,  official  sources  as  well  as  from  banks,  and  from  popular  business  books.  The  limits  and  advantages  of  such  sources  shall  be  discussed  in  more  detail  below.    

Page 82: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  82  

 

5.5     Part  4:  Designing  the  case  study  research      

5.5.1   Theory    According  to  Yin  (1994,  p20),  the  main  components  for  designing  case  

study  research  involve  clarifying  what  questions  are  being  asked,  what  propositions  or  theories  (if  any)  are  being  advanced,  what  materials  or  units  are  being  analysed  and  why,  and  how  such  materials  should  be  interpreted  and  analysed  to  connect  with  those  questions  and  propositions.      In  short,  the  research  needs  to  be  designed  so  that  the  questions  being  asked  can  be  appropriately  explored  within  a  framework,  which  considers  relevant  materials  and  allows  for  the  materials  to  be  analysed  in  a  way  which  connects  with  the  questions.  As  Thomas  (2011)  puts  it,  the  ‘case’  is  the  ‘subject’  of  inquiry  and  a  class  of  phenomena  which  provides  the  frame  for  the  inquiry  or  ‘object’  within  which  the  study  is  conducted  and  which  helps  to  illuminate  and  elucidate  matters.    

To  adopt  Thomas’  terminology,  the  ‘subject’  of  inquiry  in  this  thesis  will  be  the  banks  which  are  chosen  to  illustrate  a  range  of  different  ownership  models  and  behavioural  phenomenon.  The  cases  have  been  chosen  as  instances  of  what  Thomas  calls  a  class  of  phenomena  to  provide  an  analytical  frame  or  ‘object’.  Each  of  the  cases  involve  instances  of  identifiable  behaviour  which  is  the  ‘object’  being  studied.  In  other  words,  the  ‘subject’  is  the  different  types  of  bank  with  their  different  ownership  models,  whilst  the  ‘object’  or  ‘analytical  frame’  within  which  the  study  will  be  conducted  and  the  questions  asked  is  the  instances  of  different  types  of  behaviour  which,  as  we  shall  see,  appear  more  broadly  to  represent  examples  of  ‘good  behaviour’  or  ‘bad  behaviour’.    

 Chapters  6  and  7  provide  an  analysis  of  four  different  banks:  three  examples  of  banks  which  have  ‘misbehaved’  or  demonstrated  some  notable  form  of  ‘bad  behaviour’  and  one  bank,  or  more  accurately  a  building  society,  which  has  apparently  behaved  better  than  its  peers  and  which  cannot  fairly  be  characterized  as  behaving  badly.  These  four  cases  are  coupled  in  pairs  and  considered  together  over  two  chapters,  each  chapter  considering  two  banks  whose  ownership  models  closely  resemble  one  another.    So,  Barclays  Bank  PLC  forms  one  case,  and  is  paired  with  the  Lloyds  Banking  Group  PLC  in  chapter  6,  which  is  concerned  with  shareholder  banks  and  how  ownership  pressures  affected  behaviour  in  those  cases.  Chapter  7,  then  considers  two  banks  which  can  be  classified  as  ‘stakeholder  banks’  The  first  is  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC,  which  before  the  majority  of  its  shares  were  sold  to  third  parties  in  2013  was  entirely  owned  by  the  Co-­‐operative  Group,  which  is  a  co-­‐operative  society  or  specific  type  of  mutual  organisation.  And  the  Co-­‐op  Bank  is  paired  with  the  Nationwide  Building  Society,  which  is  still  a  mutually  owned  building  society,  owned  by  and  run  for  the  benefit  of  its  members.        

Page 83: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  83  

5.5.2   Choice  of  cases      Barclays  and  Lloyds  were  chosen  not  because  they  are  outlier  examples  of  

shareholder-­‐owned  banks  but  rather  because  they  are  illustrative  more  generally  of  the  big  banks  in  the  UK  whose  shares  are  publicly  traded  and  whose  behaviour  has  been  criticized  in  recent  times.  Both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  failed  in  different  ways,  but  both  told  a  variant  on  the  same  story  that  is  shared  by  many  mainstream  banks,  about  management  being  encouraged  to  adopt  risky  strategies  and  (explicitly  or  implicitly)  to  tolerate  mis-­‐behaviour  in  order  to  meet  objectives.    

Both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  are  historically  and  economically  significant  institutions  and  both  are  thoroughbred  examples  of  shareholder-­‐owned  banks.  Each  developed  risky  business  strategies  and  has  been  found  to  have  misbehaved  in  other  ways.  Barclays,  for  example,  courted  widespread  public  controversy  not  only  for  isolated  incidents  of  misbehaviour,  such  as  LIBOR  and  other  market-­‐rigging,  but  was  also  criticized  for  developing  a  highly  leveraged  investment  banking  business  model,  which  risked  failing  in  economic  terms,  as  it  was  overly-­‐dependent  upon  non-­‐traditional  and  unsustainable  sources  of  income,  and  was  thus  badly  suited  to  cope  with  the  global  financial  crisis  and  also  with  the  subsequent  and  still  prevailing  environment  of  low  interest  rates.  Lloyds  was  also  criticised  not  only  for  specific  instances  of  misbehaviour,  in  its  case  embarking  upon  industrial  scale  mis-­‐selling  of  products  to  its  customers  as  well  as  market-­‐rigging,  but  also  by  developing  a  business  model  which  was  dependent  on  making  large  acquisitions  and  which  ultimately  had  to  be  bailed  out  by  the  Treasury  in  the  banking  crisis.        

As  for  the  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks,  the  Co-­‐op  and  the  Nationwide  were  chosen  as  cases  because  they  were  obviously  relevant  to  the  inquiry  both  because  they  had  different  ownership  models  and  because  they  each  behaved  in  ways  which  called  out  for  further  investigation.    The  Co-­‐op  bank  was  not  owned  by  shareholders  seeking  to  capture  and  extract  value  by  trading  shares  in  capital  markets.  It  was  owned  by  the  Co-­‐op  Group  which  had  no  interest  in  trading  shares  for  capital  gains.  Nevertheless  it  still  developed  a  very  risky  business  model,  pursuing  an  unrealistically  acquisitive  strategy,  similar  to  that  witnessed  in  the  case  of  Lloyds,  albeit  on  a  much  smaller  scale.  This  strategy  ultimately  caused  its  ‘failure’  and  its  need  for  third  party  bail  out.      As  for  the  Nationwide,  whilst  not  technically  a  bank,  the  Nationwide  has  performed  the  functions  more  typically  associated  with  retail  banking,  and  presents  itself  as  a  worthy  case  for  exploring  in  this  thesis  not  only  because  it  has  a  stakeholder-­‐owned  model  and  operates  in  an  environment  where  there  are  no  other  banks  with  such  model,  but  also  because,  perhaps  uniquely,  the  Nationwide  performed  well  following  on  from  the  crisis,  avoiding  much  of  the  allegations  of  ‘failure’  and  ‘misbehaviour’  which  were  levelled  at  other  banks.  It  thus  presents  an  interesting  outlier  choice  of  case  and  useful  comparator.  

The  cases  were  chosen,  at  least  in  part,  with  a  view  to  guarding  against  pre-­‐conceptions  and  bias.  The  shareholder-­‐owned  models  were  not  radical  examples  of  failure,  such  as  the  Northern  Rock,  or  RBS,  but  were  more  representative  of  the  experience  had  by  the  big  banks  in  the  UK.  Similarly,  the  choice  of  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  included  an  obvious  case  of  failure  namely  the  Co-­‐op  Bank,  which  could  have  been  overlooked  had  the  thesis  been  intent  on  

Page 84: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  84  

arguing  that  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks  are  behaviourally  superior  to  shareholder-­‐owned  banks.  Instead,  it  was  chosen  with  a  view  to  exploring  the  reasons  for  failure  in  a  case  where  ownership  pressures  were  apparently  absent.      

5.5.3   Time  frame  for  study    The  empirical  research  into  these  four  cases  considers  them  over  

different  time  spans.  It  would  be  arbitrary  and  unrealistic  to  consider  them  all  over  the  exact  same  period,  as  their  different  notable  incidents  of  ‘behaviour’  or  ‘misbehaviour’  developed  in  different  ways  and  at  different  times.  The  time-­‐spans  adopted  have  been  chosen  to  provide  sufficient  insight  into  the  incidents  of  ‘behaviour’  which  are  studied.  In  the  case  of  Barclays  and  Lloyds,  for  example,  these  cases  have  been  considered  in  the  period  leading  up  to  and  following  on  from  the  banking  crisis  and  following  on  from  the  crisis  until  there  was  regime  change  amongst  senior  management.    

These  cases  are  considered  for  a  period  of  some  decades  leading  up  to  the  crisis  during  which  time  their  individual  business  models  were  developed.  Since  most  of  the  revelations  relating  to  misbehaviour  for  both  of  these  banks  followed  the  crisis,  such  as  market  rigging  and  mis-­‐selling,  they  have  been  studied  right  up  until  relatively  recently  when  there  was  a  change  of  top  management.    It  has  also  been  appropriate  to  study  these  banks  for  some  time  following  the  crisis  as  their  failing  behaviour  continued  and  was  compounded  by  their  inability  to  recover.  The  behavioural  and  performance  problems  which  were  remarkable  for  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  consisted  both  of  the  difficulties  they  encountered  during  the  crisis  and  their  inability  to  recover  from  the  crisis  in  a  low  interest  or  no  interest  conjuncture.      

As  such,  Barclays  is  studied  during  the  period  between  1992  and  2013  and  Lloyds  between  1988  and  2013.  Since  the  development  of  the  respective  business  models  within  these  banks  revolved  significantly  around  one  central  personality  -­‐  Bob  Diamond  in  the  case  of  Barclays  and  Brian  Pitman  for  Lloyds  –  it  has  been  appropriate  to  study  these  cases  over  the  course  of  their  careers.  Heavyweights  in  their  own  rights,  these  individuals  are  commonly  considered  to  have  delivered  transformative  success  and  defined  the  strategy  and  business  models  for  which  their  banks  became  known  (Fallon,  2015).  They  not  only  created  huge  reputational  success  for  themselves  but  also  came  to  characterise  or  personify  the  dominant  force  for  their  bank’s  business  strategy.  The  research  into  Barclays  and  Lloyds  thus  aims  to  chart  the  transformation  of  the  business  models  within  those  firms  essentially  by  following  the  careers  of  those  individuals.    It  is  also  appropriate  to  consider  Barclays  and  Lloyds  alongside  one  another  to  make  comparisons  with  how  their  strategy  was  being  perceived  by  analysts  and  translating  through  into  share  price.    

In  the  case  of  Lloyds,  it  was  appropriate  to  extend  the  period  of  inquiry  beyond  Pitman’s  retirement  right  up  until  the  crisis  when  Lloyds  failed  most  significantly,  and  still  further  beyond  the  crisis  because  of  the  incidents  of  misbehaviour  and  scandals  which  emerged  in  2012  and  2013,  and  not  least  in  connection  with  market-­‐rigging  and  PPI  and  other  mis-­‐selling  sagas.  For  Barclays,  the  behavioural  issues  were  primarily  concerned  with  the  bad  strategy  involved  in  building  up  a  business  model  which  was  too  dependent  upon  

Page 85: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  85  

unsustainable  sources  of  liquidity  and  funding,  and  which  resulted  in  Barclays  having  a  significant  capital  deficit,  which  in  turn  meant  that  Barclays  had  to  be  rescued  in  its  own  way  by  hurriedly  raising  unorthodox  funding.  The  behavioural  issues  of  interest  also  included  miscellaneous  incidents  of  misbehaviour  throughout  the  bank,  such  as  :  the  questionable  way  in  which  Barclays  raised  funds  to  plug  its  capital  shortfall,  particularly  from  Qatar;  its  involvement  in  rigging  markets  such  as  LIBOR;  the  part  it  played  in  mis-­‐selling  products  to  its  customers  which  they  had  little  or  no  need  for;  as  well  as  incidents  of  money  laundering  (Mollenkamp,  2010)  and  allegations  of  tax  evasion,  or  unethical  attempts  to  avoid  tax  (Leigh  et  al,  2012).    

For  Lloyds  the  behavioural  issues  of  interest  mainly  also  revolved  around  its  risky  strategy  in  diverting  business  away  from  traditional  retail  banking  functions  and  becoming  aggressively  acquisitive,  resulting  in  Lloyds  taking  on  bad  assets,  including  HBOS’  bad  loans,  which  eventually  required  the  state  to  bail  it  out;  as  well  as  other  incidents  of  miscellaneous  misbehaviour  including  :  rigging  markets;  engaging  heavily  in  mis-­‐selling;  and  also  engaging  in  money  laundering  (Mollenkamp,  2010).    

Unlike  Barclays  and  Lloyds,  the  strategies  and  business  models  for  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank  and  Nationwide  Building  Society  revolved  less  evidently  around  any  one  central  figure.  The  Co-­‐op  suffered  a  collective  failure  of  governance,  and  so  the  relevant  period  of  study  cannot  chart  the  career  of  any  one  individual.  Its  failure  also  came  much  later  than  the  crisis,  unfolding  in  2012  and  2013,  with  reports  and  inquiries  being  produced  afterwards.  Similarly  the  successes  of  the  Nationwide  are  not  attributable  to  one  dominant  personality,  but  to  organic  growth  and  traditional  prudent  business  whose  management  was  not  in  the  hands  of  one  figure  but  a  collective  with  multiple,  changing  personalities.      

It  was  appropriate  to  study  the  Co-­‐op  therefore  in  a  more  recent  period,  from  the  2000s  onwards  and  to  go  beyond  the  crisis,  in  order  to  take  into  account  the  reports  and  inquiries  published  after  its  failure  in  2012  and  2013.  The  Co-­‐op  was  thus  studied  from  the  start  of  the  millennium  up  until  2016,  which  is  when  the  inquiries  were  published.    As  for  the  Nationwide,  its  resilience  and  stability  has  been  proven  over  a  longer  period  of  time.  Since  the  Nationwide’s  growth  and  success  has  been  organic,  it  has  been  appropriate  to  study  it  over  a  longer  period  of  time,  namely  since  the  late  1990s  until  2014.    Unlike  for  Barclays  and  Lloyds  which  were  considered  alongside  one  another  to  make  appropriate  comparisons,  the  behavioural  problems  in  the  Co-­‐op  and  the  success  of  the  Nationwide  are  quite  distinctive  and  these  cases  are  therefore  presented  in  turn.  

 

5.5.4   Data  and  sources      

The  research  questions  call  for  a  wide  variety  of  data  to  be  consulted.  Set  out  below  in  table  5.1  is  a  table  showing  the  different  types  of  data  consulted  as  a  part  of  the  empirical  research.  The  table  identifies  what  each  source  was  consulted  for,  where  it  was  found,  what  typical  types  of  data  were  consulted,  and  also  comments  upon  why  such  data  was  considered  to  be  beneficial  for  the  inquiries  being  made,  and  conversely  how  the  same  was  considered  to  have  draw-­‐backs.    

Page 86: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  86  

Table 5.1: data, sources, advantages and disadvantages

 

Page 87: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  87  

What  data?   What  relevant  for?    

Where  sourced?    

What  typical  sources?  

Advantages    Disadvantages    

1.  Sales-­‐side  analyst  reports  

-­‐Ch.6:  the  inquiry  into  ownership  pressures  for  shareholder    banks  

-­‐management  communications  to  investors  

 

 

-­‐Thomson  One  Banker    

-­‐Online  

See  references  in  chapter  6  for  fuller  details;  typically  consulted  large  IB  reports,  for  example:  

-­‐Deutsche  Bank  

-­‐Morgan  Stanley  

-­‐Société  Générale  

-­‐Bear  Sterns  

-­‐Credit  Suisse  

-­‐JP  Morgan  

 

-­‐good  for  figures,  graphs  and  tables    

-­‐source  of  investor  relations  data  and  communications    

-­‐way  of  gaging  investor  attitudes  to  management  

-­‐enables  comparison  to  be  made  with  business  model  changes  to  gage  how  investor  demands  were  received  

-­‐unavailable  for  stakeholder-­‐owned  banks    

-­‐irrelevant  therefore  to  the  structural  pressures  inquiry  

-­‐potentially  biased  as  IB’s  disclaim  opinions  and  state  may  have  vested  interests  

2.  Broadsheet  financial  commentary  and  banking  journalism  

-­‐chs.6-­‐7:  ownership  and  structural  pressures  inquiries  

 

-­‐Thomson  Reuters  

-­‐In  print    

-­‐Online    

See  references  in  chapters  6,  7  for  fuller  details;  commonly:  

-­‐The  Financial  Times  

-­‐The  Times    

-­‐The  Telegraph  

-­‐The  Mail  

-­‐The  Guardian  

-­‐The  Independent  

 

-­‐Easily  accessible  and  readily  searchable  

-­‐Good  coverage  of  banking  scandals    and  behavioural  issues    

–good  coverage  of  shareholder  owned  banks  

-­‐sometimes  a  source  of  insider  insights  

-­‐sometimes  shallow  reporting,  sensationalising  scandals,  and  lacking  analysis    

-­‐coverage  of  stakeholder  banks  particularly  lacking  in  analysis  

 

3.  Official  and  semi-­‐official  reports  and  inquiries  into  the  banking  crisis  and  certain  banks  

-­‐Both  pressures  inquiries  

-­‐Bank  misbehaviour  generally  

-­‐The  failure  of  the  Co-­‐op  

-­‐Misbehaviour  in  Barclays  and  Lloyds  

-­‐Parliament  

-­‐HM  Treasury  

-­‐The  different  government  departments  or  agencies  

-­‐Online  

 

See  references  in  chapter  2  for  more  details;  main  examples:  

-­‐IBC  (2012)  

-­‐PCBS  (2013)  

-­‐CMA  (2016)  

-­‐Turner  review  (2010)  

-­‐Kay  Review  (2012)  

-­‐Salz  review  (2013)  

-­‐Kelly  (2014)  

 

-­‐often  analytically  rigorous  and  detailed  

-­‐good  source  of  figures  tables  and  graphs  

-­‐easily  accessible  and  searchable  

 

-­‐Potential  for  bias  in  appointments  

-­‐Potential  for  bias  in  terms  of  reference  

-­‐Potentially  supporting  existing  elite  agenda  

-­‐Haphazard  and  idiosyncratic  in  coverage  of  only  some  issues  and  some  of  the  cases    

4.  Academic   -­‐inquiry  into   -­‐Online   See  references  in   -­‐often  analytically   -­‐Often  providing  an  

Page 88: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  88  

   

journals  and  commentary  

ownership  pressures    

-­‐inquiry  into  structural  pressures  

-­‐all  of  the  cases  

-­‐Thomson  Reuters  

-­‐Library  

 

chapters  1,  2,  3  and  4  for  more  details;  examples:    

-­‐Moran  (1991)  

-­‐Ireland  (2009)  

-­‐CRESC  (2009,  2011)  

rigorous  

-­‐more  comprehensive  coverage  of  ownership  and  corporate  governance  issues  

-­‐easily  accessible  and  searchable  

-­‐good  source  of  figures,  tables  and  graphs  

outsider  perspective,  lacking  insider  insight  

5.  Bank  performance  data,  annual  reports  and  annual  or  quarterly  accounts  

-­‐All  four  banks  studied  

-­‐ownership  pressures:  source  of  investor  relations  data  and  communications  

-­‐checking  for  asset  growth,  M&A,  RoE,  RoA,  earnings  ratios  

-­‐Bankscope  

-­‐Online  

-­‐The  websites  for  all  four  cases  

-­‐Their  annual  reports    

 

-­‐Good  source  of  figures,  tables  and  graphs  

-­‐data  from  audited  accounts    

-­‐Not  specific  to  any  of  the  inquiries    

6.  Popular  business  and  finance  books    

-­‐ownership  pressures  inquiry  

-­‐structural  pressures  inquiry  

-­‐all  four  cases  

-­‐Amazon  

-­‐libraries  

-­‐book  stores  

 

See  references  for  chapters  3  and  4  for  fuller  details;  examples:    

-­‐Admati  et  al  (2011)  

-­‐Mayer  (2013)  

-­‐Brummer  (2015)  

-­‐Wolf  (2014c)  

-­‐King  (2016)  

-­‐Turner  (2016)  

-­‐Kay  (2015)  

   

 

 

 

 

 

-­‐Good  source  of  insider  insight  

-­‐potentially  unbiased,  lacking  apparent  agenda  (unlike  analyst  reports)  

-­‐coverage  haphazard  and  not  comprehensive  

-­‐data  sometimes  highly  subjective  and  lacking  analytical  rigour  

 

Page 89: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  89  

 Although  there  were  three  thesis  questions  (see  5.3  above),  the  third  

question  was  evaluative  in  nature,  and  consequently  it  was  really  the  first  two  questions  which  called  for  primary  empirical  research.  The  sources  and  data  available  for  those  two  inquiries  varied  considerably.      

5.5.4.1  …  for  the  ownership  pressures  inquiry  

 The  empirical  research  into  ownership  pressures  in  shareholder  banks  had  two  slightly  different  aspects.  It  considered  how  the  business  model  and  strategy  employed  by  Barclays  and  Lloyds  was  fashioned  by  investor  demands,  and  how  such  pressures  more  generally  influenced  other  incidents  of  misbehaviour.  The  main  empirical  research  focused  more  upon  the  strategy  and  business  models  that  developed  within  the  cases  studied,  rather  than  on  the  multiple  and  miscellaneous  incidents  of  misbehaviour  that  emerged.    Strategy  is  an  ordinary  every  day  work  connoting  high  level  decision-­‐making  made  for  long  term  or  overall  gain.  Whilst  there  are  different  definitions  for  a  ‘business  model’,  at  its  most  basic,  it  describes  how  an  organisation  recovers  its  operating  costs  and  makes  profit  and  in  other  words  how  it  creates  value  and  makes  money  (Osterwalder  et  al,  2009).  The  research  aims  to  consider  how  changes  in  strategy  and  the  business  model  were  influenced  by  ownership  pressures.  These  strategic  changes  at  the  level  of  the  firm  are  often  easier  to  study  than  specific  incidents  of  bad  behaviour  occurring  within  firms,  as  there  is  typically  more  data  readily  available.    Specific  incidents  of  misbehaviour  can  be  difficult  to  investigate  because  of  a  lack  of  evidence.  Such  incidents  are  often  not  detected  or  proven  by  regulators.  Accordingly,  the  research  into  incidents  of  misbehaviour  more  generally  relied  heavily  upon  the  official  and  semi-­‐official  reports  and  inquiries  and  their  findings,  including  the  Salz  report  (2013)  or  the  FCA  report  on  Libor-­‐rigging  or  the  PCBS  report  into  banking  standards.  As  for  the  research  into  strategy  and  business  models  particular  attention  was  paid  to  growth  in  bank  size,  M&A  activity,  RoE,  and  RoA  during  the  relevant  time  periods  (identified  in  5.1(c)  above).    

Using  the  bank  performance  data  identified  in  row  5  of  table  5.1,  which  was  typically  taken  from  Bankscope  or  from  the  bank’s  annual  or  quarterly  reports,  the  empirical  research  focused  particularly  on  the  two  things  typically  called  for  by  investors,  namely  increased  earnings  and  growth.  Special  attention  was  paid  to  how  banks  sought  to  deliver  high  returns  on  equity  and  also  greater  profits  by  asset-­‐growth  and  increasing  the  volume  of  the  underlying  business  transacted.  

RoA  and  RoE  were  considered  to  be  useful  ratios  because  they  often  provide  an  indication  about  how  well  management  is  using,  respectively,  total  assets  or  equity  to  generate  profits.  In  other  words,  they  can  reveal  something  about  how  efficiently  profits  are  being  generated  relative  to  the  total  assets  available  to  a  bank  or  relative  to  the  amount  of  money  shareholders  have  invested.      

As  is  identified  in  row  1  of  table  5.1,  to  inquire  into  how  ownership  pressures  caused  changes  in  strategy,  sales-­‐side  analyst  reports  were  consulted  for  Lloyds  and  Barclays,  and  in  particular  those  produced  by  the  main  

Page 90: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  90  

investment  banks  such  as  JP  Morgan,  Credit  Suisse,  Deutsche  Bank,  and  the  others  set  out  also  in  row  1  or  referred  to  in  chapter  6.  This  data  was  checked  for  investor  communications  or  demands  made  on  management,  and  also  compared  with  the  performance  data,  which  had  been  analysed  to  consider  the  changing  business  models  in  Barclays  and  Lloyds.  Such  comparison  was  made  as  a  way  of  assessing  whether  and  how  far  investors  were  receptive  to  the  strategy  and  business  models  being  developed  in  Lloyds  and  Barclays  and  reflexively  how  their  demands  were  being  accommodated  by  those  banks  and  their  changing  strategies  and  business  models.    

Other  data  was  consulted  to  explore  statements  made  by  the  banks  relevant  to  shareholder  pressures  and  in  relation  to  wider  instances  of  misbehaviour.  Journalism  and  financial  commentary  as  well  as  popular  business  books  (rows  2,  and  6  of  table  5.1)  were  a  good  source  of  information  about  how  management  both  in  Lloyds  and  Barclays  felt  the  need  to  satisfy  investor  demands,  and  about  how  they  variously  misbehaved.  The  two  popular  books  written  on  Barclays  and  Lloyds  provided  good  ‘insider’  insight  into  management  decisions  and  the  affects  of  investor  demands.  Banking  journalism  and  official  reports  proved  to  be  a  useful  source  for  types  of  misbehaviour  such  as  PPI  selling  or  LIBOR-­‐rigging.        

 5.5.4.2  ….for  the  structural  pressures  inquiry  

 Since  the  inquiry  into  structural  pressures  was  confined  to  looking  at  the  

two  stakeholder  banks,  the  sources  of  data  available  for  shareholder  banks  were  of  limited  or  no  use.  There  were  no  sales-­‐side  analyst  reports.  The  data  and  sources  identified  in  rows  2  to  4  were  the  main  sources  consulted  for  the  research  into  structural  inquiries.  Performance  data,  banking  journalism,  official  reports  and  academic  commentary  were  analysed  for  information  about  bank  strategy  and  business  models,  again  with  particular  attention  being  paid  to  performance  indicators  such  as  assets  growth,  M&A,  RoE,  and  RoA.  These  sources  of  data  (rows  2  to  4  of  table  5.1)  were  checked  also  for  information  about  other  behavioural  issues  beyond  the  strategy  and  business  models.        

These  sources  were  also  analysed  with  a  particular  view  to  considering  the  types  of  structural  pressures  identified  in  chapter  4,  and  in  particular  what  might  be  described  as  the  ‘scale  requirement’,  ‘obesity  problems’  and  ‘peer  pressure  problems’  which  are  driven  by  high  operating  costs  in  retail  banking,  an  effective  oligopoly  in  the  retail  banking  market,  and  the  TBTF  state  subsidy.      

The  official  and  semi  official  reports,  and  academic  commentary  (rows  3  and  4  of  table  5.1)  were  particularly  relevant  sources  for  the  structural  pressures  inquiry  in  considering  both  the  failure  of  the  Co-­‐op  (Kelly,  2014),  and  issues  of  competition  in  retail  banking  (Competitions  and  Markets  Authority,  2015).  As  is  explained  in  row  3  (table  5.1),  there  were  no  official  reports  into  the  Nationwide,  and  accordingly  performance  data  and  the  Nationwide’s  own  publications,  particularly  reports,  as  well  as  banking  journalism,  were  consulted  for  information  about  strategy  and  business  model.      

Page 91: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  91  

5.5.4.3  The  benefits  and  limitations    

     The  limitations,  drawbacks  and  benefits  posed  by  each  source  of  data,  

varied  widely  from  source  to  source.  Table  5.1  identifies  more  fully  what  were  considered  to  be  the  main  benefits  and  draw-­‐backs  for  each  source  of  data.  The  sales-­‐side  analyst  reports  (row  1)  were  a  useful  source  for  quantitative  data,  figures,  tables  and  charts.  They  were  also  a  good  source  of  information  for  investor-­‐management  communications,  clarifying  what  targets  had  been  set,  delivered  upon  or  missed.  Whilst  lacking  ‘insider’  information,  they  were  much  closer  to  the  proverbial  action  than  academic  commentary,  and  benefited  from  extensive  and  up  close  performance  analysis.  The  qualitative  opinions  expressed  in  those  reports  were  perhaps  less  reliable  as  each  report  explicitly  disclaimed  liability  for  opinions  and  explained  they  might  have  vested  interests  which  would  conflict  with  objective  analysis.      

The  financial  commentary  and  banking  journalism  (row  2)  was  also  more  proximate  to  the  business  and  less  removed  than  academic  commentary.  It  thus  benefitted  from  anecdotes  about  internal  goings-­‐on  within  the  organisations.  The  banking  media  provided  good  coverage  of  failures  and  scandals,  such  as  the  problems  arising  in  the  Co-­‐op  or  the  market-­‐rigging  for  Lloyds  and  Barclays  or  PPI  mis-­‐selling  sagas  for  all  of  the  banks.    

The  official  reports  (row  3)  responding  to  the  banking  crisis  and  different  incidents  of  misbehaviour  also  proved  to  be  a  good  sources  of  information  for  misbehaviour  particularly  for  the  Co-­‐op  (Kelly,  2014;  FCA,  2016),  and  Barclays  (Salz,  2013).  The  inquiry  performed  by  these  different  reports  was  limited  however  in  how  far  it  connected  with  the  ownership  and  structural  pressures  inquires  performed  by  this  thesis.      

Whilst  the  academic  commentary  (considered  in  row  4)  connected  more  with  the  ownership  and  structural  pressures  inquiries,  this  source  of  data  was  distanced  from  the  internal  culture  within  organisations.  The  performance  data  (row  5)  was  also  largely  numerical  in  nature,  and  did  not  explain  the  personalities,  and  sense  of  association  or  even  mission  within  the  culture  of  each  bank.    

There  was  something  of  a  perceived  gap  in  the  data  therefore  in  terms  of  insider  insight.  This  was  not  necessarily  overcome  by  the  official  inquiries,  banking  journalism  or  analyst  reports,  but  it  was  compensated  for  by  some  of  the  popular  business  and  finance  books  consulted.  These  sources  (row  6)  provided  insights  into  Barclays  (Weyer,  2000)  and  Lloyds  (Fallen,  2016)  and  the  Co-­‐op  (Brummer,  2015)  as  well  as  perspectives  from  central  bankers  (King,  2016),  regulators  (Turner,  2016)  and  other  policymakers,  involved  in  formulating  banking  reform  agenda  (Wolf,  2014c).  Whilst  this  source  of  data  was  haphazard  as  regards  which  cases  it  spoke  to  and  about  what  issues,  it  was  advantageous  in  that  books  were  apparently  written  without  any  obvious  motive  or  agenda  –  something  which  cannot  necessarily  be  said  for  the  analyst  reports  (row  1).    

5.5.5   Terminology    Finally,  this  thesis  has  chosen  to  explore  the  above  questions  in  the  

manner  described  above,  whilst  employing  the  terminology  of  ‘ownership’  

Page 92: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  92  

rather  than  ‘governance’.  It  refers  to  the  ‘ownership  model’  rather  than  the  ‘governance  regime’  and  to  ‘ownership  pressures’  as  opposed  to  describing  the  incentives  driven  by  ‘shareholder  sovereignty’  or  ‘shareholder  primacy’  or  ‘shareholder  value  maximisation’.  The  reason  it  has  chosen  to  adopt  such  terminology  is  twofold.  First,  ‘ownership’  is  useful  shorthand  for  describing  governance  phenomena  which  can  be  cumbersome  to  explain.  ‘Ownership  pressures’  is  a  more  pithy  way  of  describing  the  corporate  governance  relationship  whereby  businesses  are  expected  to  act  in  the  interests  of  their  shareholders  typically  by  paying  down  dividends  or  being  run  with  a  view  to  making  capital  gains  in  financial  markets.  

Second,  such  terminology,  whilst  technically  inexact,  is  in  common  usage  within  the  corporate  governance  literature  and  it  helps  to  emphasise  the  thinking  bias  and  conceptual  errors  made  by  treating  shareholders  as  analogous  to  owners.  Whilst  banks  or  companies  are  not  technically  owned  by  anybody,  it  is  common  in  political  and  economic  thinking  to  conceive  of  and  treat  shareholders  as  ‘owners’  (Haldane,  2015,  p13;  Mayer,  2013,  pp26-­‐31;  Eccles,  2015)  –  a  misconception  which  is  reinforced  by  the  extensive  rights  shareholders  are  given  to  control  companies.  By  employing  such  terminology  it  draws  attention  to  that  thinking  error  and  helps  to  emphasise  the  illogicality  in  treating  shareholders  like  owners  and  having  banks  run  entirely  in  their  interests.  By  adopting  such  terminology,  the  thesis  underlines  the  question  whether  shareholders  are  treated  like  owners,  and  whether  they  should  be  treated  in  that  way.    

 

5.6     Part  5:  Summary  and  conclusions         Saunders  et  al  (2007)  famously  depicted  a  ‘research  onion’  showing  diagrammatically  the  different  available  categories  of  research  philosophies,  strategies  and  methodologies.  That  research  onion  is  shown  in  chart  5.1  below.    

   

Page 93: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  93  

     Chart 5.1Chart 5. 1: A ‘research onion’

(Source:  Saunders  et  al  (2007),  p52)    

Of  the  available  categories,  the  table  below  clarifies  the  choices  of  philosophy,  approach,  strategy  and  methodology  adopted.      Table 5.2: The different levels of Saunders' research onion  Onion  layer  

Description  of  layer   Chosen  category  

1.   Research  philosophy  and  epistemology  

Social  ontology  and  a  critical  realist  epistemology    

2.   Research  approach   Inductive  3.   Method  of  research   Quantitative  and  qualitative  research    4.   Research  strategy   Case  study  (exploratory)  5.   Time  horizon   Longitudinal    6.   Types  of  data   Primary  and  secondary  data    It  is  clear  from  the  above  discussion  in  part  1  that  a  social  ontology  adopting  an  epistemological  approach  of  critical  realism  seems  apt  for  the  inquiry  made  by  this  thesis.  And  it  is  apparent  from  the  above  discussion  and  in  particular  that  contained  in  part3  that  a  case  study  methodology  seems  appropriate  for  studying  ownership  pressures  and  the  behaviour  they  encourage.  Such  phenomena  are  largely  irreducible  and  incapable  of  being  isolated  from  the  context  within  which  they  arise  where  multiple  other  generative  mechanisms  are  also  in  operation.  Whilst  this  methodology    has  well-­‐known  limits  being  concerned  with  only  a  limited  number  of  cases,  it  is  hoped  that  the  parameters  set  by  the  research  design  discussed  above,  and  the  selection  of  cases,  is  sufficiently  objective  and  robust  to  guard  against  bias.  It  is  also  hoped  that  the  wide  range  of  sources  used,  whilst  imperfect  each  on  their  own,  taken  together  provide  enough  data  to  undertake  meaningful  analysis  and  identify  useful  and  interesting  findings.      Following  the  empirical  research  into  shareholder  banks  and  their  behaviour  in  chapter  6  and  stakeholder  banks  and  their  behaviour  in  chapter  7,  the  findings  made  in  those  chapters  will  be  analysed  and  evaluated  in  chapter  8  in  which  the  discussion  about  the  importance  of  ownership  and  its  behavioural  implications  will  be  discussed  further.                  

Page 94: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  94  

     

Chapter  6.  ‘Ownership  pressures’  and  Barclays  and  Lloyds  

 

6.1     Introduction    As  we  saw  in  chapters  2  and  3,  in  the  wake  of  the  UK  banking  crisis,  it  

became  increasingly  apparent  that  banks  had  taken  on  too  many  risks,  and  had  misbehaved.  As  chapter  2  outlined,  there  was  no  shortage  of  journalistic  and  academic  commentary  covering  the  various  banking  scandals  and  incidents  and  allegations  of  misbehaviour  and  malfeasance,  and  there  has  been  no  shortage  of  proposals  for  reform.  What  was  surprisingly  absent  from  the  reform  debate  was  any  official  inquiry  into  whether  the  existing  ownership  model  drives  mis-­‐behaviour  –  an  omission  which  is  rather  astonishing  in  the  light  of  the  claims  made  by  advocates  of  stakeholder  governance,  namely  that  shareholder-­‐owned  banks  tend  to  encourage  strategies  which  prioritise  short  term  returns  at  the  expense  of  their  customers  and  long  term  stability.    This  chapter  looks  more  closely  at  how  the  shareholder  ownership  model,  that  is  to  say  the  PLC  whose  shares  are  publicly  traded  affects  the  strategy  and  conduct  of  banks.  In  doing  so,  it  explores  the  ‘ownership  pressures’  described  in  chapters  3  and  5,  and  explores  the  first  of  the  primary  research  questions,  namely:  how  bank  behaviour  is  affected  by  the  way  a  bank  is  owned.  The  following  chapter  will  then  inquire  into  behavioural  implications  of  the  ‘structural  pressures’  which  were  described  in  chapters  4  and  5  and  that  chapter  will  consider  the  second  of  the  primary  research  questions,  namely  how  far  behaviour  is  affected  by  structural  pressures  regardless  of  how  a  bank  is  owned.  

This  chapter  explores  how  ownership  pressures  make  demands  for  profits  in  the  two  ways  considered  in  chapter  3  and  5  namely  by  calling  for  high  returns  on  equity  and  greater  asset-­‐growth  by  increasing  the  volume  of  underlying  business  transacted.  It  considers  the  demands  placed  on  management  for  earnings  and  growth  and  how  they  were  responded  to,  and  it  considers  other  incidents  of  misbehaviour  and  whether  ownership  pressures  acted  as  drivers  or  restraints.      As  was  explained  the  last  chapter,  particularly  at  5.5,  it  seeks  to  explore  these  issues  by  considering  sales-­‐side  analyst  reports  produced  by  large  investment  banks,  and  accessed  through  Thomson  Reuters,  as  a  sort  of  proxy  for  gaging  investor  demands.  It  draws  upon  this  data  as  well  as  the  performance  data  gathered  from  Bankscope  and  annual  and  quarterly  reports,  and  the  financial  and  banking  media  to  consider  how  the  different  business  models  in  the  case  of  Lloyds  and  Barclays  were  developed  and  how  ownership  pressures  drive  behaviour.  The  chapter  charts  the  different  periods  when  the  respective  business  models  were  developed  within  the  two  banks,  following  the  career  rise  of  their  respective  chief  executives  Bob  Diamond  and  Brian  Pitman.    

Page 95: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  95  

The  chapter  is  broken  up  into  three  parts.  The  first  part  explores  how  both  Pitman  and  Diamond  sought  to  satisfy  market  demands  and  how  their  banks  developed  distinct  business  models  as  a  way  of  keeping  investors  happy.  The  second  part  then  explores  the  strains  which  developed  when  the  business  models  proved  unable  to  meet  the  market’s  demands,  which  in  the  case  of  Lloyds  arose  before  the  credit  crunch  and  banking  crisis.  For  Barclays,  these  strains  appeared  later  and  this  part  therefore  charts  Barclays  performance  for  some  years  after  the  crisis.    The  third  part  charts  how  banks  performed  and  how  analysts  perceived  them  right  up  until  the  period  when  there  was  effectively  a  ‘regime  change’  across  British  banks  following  the  LIBOR-­‐rigging  scandal  and  the  multiple  incidents  of  misbehaviour  and  banking  scandal  which  emerged  in  2011  and  the  years  which  followed.    

In  the  case  of  Lloyds,  the  chapter  looks  initially  at  the  strategy  developed  under  the  leadership  of  Brian  Pitman  whilst  he  was  CEO  between  1984  and  1997  and  later  chairman  of  Lloyds  between  1997  and  2001  and  it  continues  to  chart  ownership  pressures  on  Lloyds  and  resulting  strategy  following  Pitman’s  departure,  through  the  acquisition  of  HBOS  in  2008,  and  right  up  until  the  departure  of  Eric  Daniels  in  2011.    In  the  case  of  Barclays,  the  analysis  covers  the  business  model  developed  during  Bob  Diamond’s  rise  to  high  office  between  1997  until  his  resignation  from  Barclays  in  2012.        

6.2     Part  1:  delivering  shareholder  value        

6.2.1     Committing  to  the  market    Although  Pitman  and  Diamond  rose  to  prominence  in  Lloyds  and  Barclays  

in  different  decades,  they  had  one  thing  in  common.  Both  publicly  promised  to  deliver  what  the  market  called  for,  and  were  explicit  and  outspoken  about  their  commitment  to  delivering  ‘shareholder  value’.  In  his  17  years  as  CEO  of  Lloyds,  Pitman  made  repeated  reference  to  that  commitment,  insisting  that  his  priority  was  to  enhance  earnings  per  share,  to  deliver  returns  on  equity  significantly  higher  than  Lloyds’  cost  of  capital  and  to  double  the  share  price  every  three  years  (Preston,  2010;  Fallon,  2015,  pp8,  25).  In  2010,  almost  a  decade  after  leaving  high  office  in  Lloyds,  Pitman  re-­‐confirmed  this  article  of  faith:  ‘Well,  nobody  is  a  greater  believer  in  shareholder  value  than  me’  (Preston,  2010;  Future  of  Banking  Commission,  2010).    

Similarly,  Bob  Diamond  also  ran  Barclays  to  achieve  high  returns  for  shareholders  and  he  was  publicly  explicit  about  that  aim.  Those  companies  that  do  not  dedicate  themselves  to  maximising  shareholder  returns,  he  warned,  got  left  behind  and  risked  being  taken  over  (Baker  et  al,  2011).  Barclays’  annual  reports  regularly  pledged  to  deliver  high  shareholder  returns  and  even  in  2010,  after  a  year  of  very  poor  performance,  Barclays  promised  its  shareholders  in  its  annual  review  that  it  would  deliver  15%  RoE  (Barclays,  2010,  p12).  The  importance  of  RoE  was  reaffirmed  by  Diamond  in  2011:  

‘return  on  equity  is  the  financial  measure  that  correlates  most  closely  with  shareholder  value,  so  it’s  extremely  important  to  us  and  it’s  extremely  important  to  our  shareholders’    (Barclays,  2011,  p3).    

Page 96: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  96  

 

6.2.2     Exceeding  expectations  -­‐  Lloyds  In  the  1990s,  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  pursued  a  regime  of  cost-­‐cutting,  

and  retrenching  their  foreign  operations  –  a  strategy  which  worked  particularly  well  for  Lloyds,  which  was  keen  to  build  up  its  UK-­‐based  business.  In  the  late  1980s  and  1990s,  in  accordance  with  Pitman’s  stated  aims  Lloyds  trebled  in  market  value  approximately  every  three  years,  which  won  favour  for  Lloyds  amongst  analysts  and  investors  (Fallon  2015,  p14).  Barclays  did  not  prove  to  be  as  popular  in  the  same  period  (Weyer  2000).  Despite  delivering  routinely  high  returns  on  equity,  often  even  in  the  order  of  20%  (see  Chart  6.1  below),  analysts  commonly  complained  about  Barclays  being  capable  of  doing  more,  and  still  having  ‘cost-­‐cutting  potential’  (Collier,  1998,  p1).  Lloyds,  which  was  regularly  achieving  returns  on  equity  in  excess  of  30%,  and  rarely  dropping  below  20%  (see  Charts  6.1,  and  6.2)  and  which  was  also  making  marginally  higher  returns  on  its  assets  than  Barclays  (see  Chart  6.3)  won  greater  favour  with  the  analysts  in  this  period  than  Barclays.  By  the  mid  to  late-­‐1990s,  a  noticeable  consensus  had  emerged  amongst  analysts  who  warmed  to  Pitman’s  self-­‐styled  image  as  a  ruthless  cost-­‐cutting  capitalist  (Preston,  2001)  and  they  regularly  encouraged  investors  to  ‘Buy!’  Lloyds  stock  (see,  for  example  Collier  et  al,  1998),  some  reporting  Lloyds’  stock  as  ‘Best  in  market’  (see  Collier  et  al,  1999,  p1).    

     

   

Chart 6.1: Lloyds: returns on equity in % (1988-20013)

(Source:  Bankscope)      Key:  Lloyds  shown  in  blue  

   

 

-­‐30  

-­‐20  

-­‐10  

0  

10  

20  

30  

40  

1988  

1989  

1990  

1991  

1992  

1993  

1994  

1995  

1995  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

2004  

2005  

2006  

2007  

2008  

2009  

2010  

2011  

2012  

2013  

Lloyds'  return  on  equity  

Page 97: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  97  

 

   

Chart 6.2: Barclays and Lloyds: returns on equity in % (1992-2012)

(Source:  Bankscope)    Key:  Barclays  shown  in  blue;  Lloyds  shown  in  red.    

 

   

Chart 6.3: Barclays and Lloyds: return on assets (RoA) in % (1992-2012)

(Source:  Bankscope)  

-­‐30  -­‐20  -­‐10  0  10  20  30  40  

1992  

1993  

1994  

1995  

1996  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

2004  

2005  

2006  

2007  

2008  

2009  

2010  

2011  

2012  

Barclays  ROA  -­‐1  

-­‐0.5  

0  

0.5  

1  

1.5  

2  

Barclays  ROA  

Lloyds  ROA  

Page 98: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  98  

Key:  Barclays  shown  in  blue;  Lloyds  shown  in  red.    

Pitman  managed  to  deliver  high  returns  on  equity  whilst  retrenching  operations  and  focusing  on  building  up  UK  retail  banking,  whilst  also  eschewing  IB  and  wholesale  operations.    In  later  years,  Pitman  was  boastful  about  his  strategic  aversion  to  wholesale  and  IB  activities,  congratulating  himself  on  the  wisdom  of  his  caution  and  criticising  his  competitors  for  being  imprudent  by  engaging  so  heavily  in  speculative  lines  of  business  whose  success  depended  on  high  levels  of  liquidity  (Preston,  2010;  Future  of  Banking  Commission,  2010).  Before  the  Future  of  Banking  Commission,  Pitman  claimed  that  unlike  his  competitors,  he  had  not  been  motivated  by  short  term  rewards  but  had  tried  to  make  money  for  shareholders  ‘over  the  long  term’  and  out  of  ‘narrow  banking’  (Preston,  2010;  Future  of  Banking  Commission,  2010),  rather  than  out  of  wholesale  and  speculative  activities.    It  is  true  that  under  Pitman’s  leadership,  between  1984  and  1997,  Lloyds’  business  focus  narrowed  and  Pitman  was  openly  sceptical  of  the  exciting,  new-­‐fangled  derivatives  and  securitization  which  was  being  embraced  by  Lloyds’  competitors,  such  as  the  Midland,  Natwest,  and  Barclays  (Preston,  2001).  Pitman  focused  instead  on  building  up  domestic  retail  banking  services  –  pushing  for  more  market  share  locally  and  seeking  to  achieve  economies  of  scale  by  making  customer-­‐focused  efficiencies  (Fallon  2015,  pp9,  17).    

The  boasts  Pitman  made  to  the  Future  of  Banking  Commission  about  making  long-­‐term  strategic  decisions  and  wisely  avoiding  risky  activities  tell  only  part  of  the  story  inasmuch  as  they  suggest,  first,  that  Pitman  did  not  succumb  to  the  short  term  demands  of  the  stock-­‐market  and,  second,  that  his  cautious  conservatism  came  about  through  wise  long-­‐sighted  decision-­‐making.  Pitman’s  dislike  of  new  and  risky  banking  activities  was  not  arrived  at  through  far-­‐sighted  wisdom  or  indifference  to  stock  market  demands  but  rather  as  a  result  of  past  bitter  experience.  Pitman’s  distrust  of  new  risky  activities  came  about  as  a  direct  result  of  having  explored  other  unorthodox  banking  activities  in  the  past,  and  having  very  spectacularly  failed  (Preston  2012).  Lloyds  had  been  very  heavily  involved  in  sovereign  lending  in  the  late  1970s  –  loans  which  Pitman  had  personally  signed  off  (Preston  2012).    

The  South  American  banking  markets  massively  underperformed  and  those  loans  were  ultimately  defaulted  on.  Pitman  played  a  major  part  in  the  various  IMF  bail  out  deals  in  South  America,  particularly  for  the  Mexican  banks  and  was  personally  involved  in  cutting  their  losses  and  writing  off  loans  he  had  signed  off  (Preston  2012,  p16)  causing  huge  losses  for  Lloyds  and  its  shareholders,  the  effects  of  which  were  still  being  felt  in  the  1980s  (see  the  negative  returns  on  equity  in  the  1980s,  Chart  6.1  above).  Pitman  later  confessed  that  had  the  full  extent  of  those  losses  been  known  to  the  public,  Lloyds  would  almost  certainly  have  gone  bust,  but  as  it  happened  it  managed  to  avoid  that  fate  as  the  accountancy  standards  of  the  time  were  far  more  lax,  and  the  Bank  of  England  was  willing  to  give  Lloyds  a  chance  to  recover  (Preston  2012,  p16).    

Whilst  it  is  true  that  Pitman,  and  his  successors  eschewed  IB  and  avoided  engaging  in  derivatives  and  speculation  (Fallon  2015,  pp175,  179),  it  is  not  true  to  suggest  that  he,  and  his  successors,  did  not  take  huge  and  risky  gambles  with  Lloyds  in  other  ways.  Although  Lloyds  managed  to  deliver  extremely  high  returns  on  its  equity  and  on  its  assets  in  the  1990s,  Lloyds  was  soon  lagging  in  

Page 99: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  99  

size.  Its  competitors,  including  Barclays,  had  built  up  significantly  bigger  businesses  and  engaged  in  greater  volumes  of  work  (see  total  assets  in  Chart  6.4  below).  By  the  early  1990s,  Barclays  was  roughly  three  times  Lloyds’  size  in  terms  of  assets  and  had  set  itself  on  a  steep  growth  trajectory.    In  line  with  his  earlier  commitments  to  create  shareholder  value,  Pitman  recognised  that  he  needed  to  deliver  not  only  high  returns  on  equity,  but  also  asset  growth  (Fallon  2015,  p17).  But  Pitman’s  options  for  bulking  up  on  assets  were  rather  limited.  Pitman’s  strategic  aversion  to  wholesale  and  IB  really  left  Lloyds  with  few  options  for  growth.  Whilst  Pitman’s  competitors  were  bulking  up  on  cheap  borrowing  and  making  returns  in  derivatives  and  securitisation,  there  was  only  so  much  scope  for  growing  Lloyds’  market  share  in  domestic  retail  banking.          

       

 Chart 6.4: Barclays and Lloyds: total assets in £m (1992-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope)  Key:  Barclays  shown  in  blue;  Lloyds  shown  in  red    

6.2.3   The  cost  of  keeping  investors  happy  –  Lloyds      In  order  to  keep  up  with  competitors  and  retain  market  favour,  Pitman  

had  to  do  more  than  merely  driving  efficiencies  and  focusing  on  domestic  retail  operations.  He  also  needed  to  grow  Lloyds’  assets.  Having  cut  back  overseas  operations,  and  declined  to  grow  IB,  Pitman’s  only  option  for  doing  that  was  to  make  Lloyds  radically  acquisitive.  As  it  happened,  Pitman  was  in  a  prime  position  to  embark  in  M&A  and  conduct  hostile  takeovers  (Preston,  2001).  Having  become  CEO  at  Lloyds  in  1984,  just  before  the  Big  Bang,  Pitman  had  witnessed  first  hand  the  growing  market  in  M&A  and  leveraged  buy  outs  

0  

500000  

1000000  

1500000  

2000000  

2500000  

1992  

1993  

1994  

1995  

1996  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

2004  

2005  

2006  

2007  

2008  

2009  

2010  

2011  

2012  

2013  

Barclays  

Lloyds  

Page 100: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  100  

(Preston,  2001).  Being  at  the  helm  of  a  large  bank  gave  him  ready  access  to  cheap  finance.    In  the  1980s  and  1990s,  Pitman’s  plans  to  grow  domestic  retail  became  necessarily  more  takeover-­‐focused  therefore.  He  set  about  garnering  a  reputation  for  himself  as  a  master  of  M&A  (Preston,  2001),  aggressively  picking  fights  with  bigger  competitors  with  a  view  to  taking  them  over:  in  1984,  he  tried,  unsuccessfully,  to  acquire  the  RBS;  in  1986,  again  unsuccessfully,  he  went  for  Standard  Chartered;  and  in  1992,  he  tried  and  failed  to  acquire  the  Midland  Bank.    

According  to  Preston  (2001)  whilst  these  attempts  were  unsuccessful,  they  had  a  positive  impact  on  Lloyds’  perception  in  the  eyes  of  shareholders  and  investors  on  the  stock  market.  By  the  early  1990s  analysts  routinely  perceived  Lloyds  as  having  considerable  takeover  potential,  encouraging  people  to  ‘Buy!’  Lloyds  stock.  Having  failed  to  make  several  sizeable  acquisitions  in  the  1980s,  his  chance  came  in  the  1990s  when  there  was  a  wave  of  de-­‐mutualisations  in  the  UK  building  society  sector.  In  the  mid-­‐1990s  Lloyds  completed  a  spree  of  significant  acquisitions,  substantially  consolidating  Lloyds’  position  in  the  UK  banking  sector,  and  radically  increasing  its  branch  network.  Lloyds  acquired  the  Cheltenham  &  Gloucester  in  1995  and  then,  almost  doubling  the  size  of  its  branch  network,  the  TSB  in  the  same  year  (although  the  merger  was  complicated  and  did  not  complete  until  1999).    

After  the  wave  of  de-­‐mutualisations  was  over,  Pitman  looked  further  afield  both  to  European  banks,  and  other  financial  propositions.  In  1999,  by  which  stage  Pitman  had  become  Chairman,  he  acquired  the  insurer  the  Scottish  Widows,  making  Lloyds  the  first  mainstream  retail  bank  in  the  UK  to  acquire  an  insurance  company.  Pitman’s  strategy  shifted  focus  slightly  as  he  declared  his  desire  to  turn  Lloyds  into  a  one-­‐stop  shop  for  banking  and  insurance  services,  akin  to  the  continental  ‘bancassurance’  model.    Setting  the  scene  for  later  pressure  selling  to  customers  and  mis-­‐selling  financial  products,  this  acquisition  put  Lloyds  into  a  position  where  it  was  able  to  offer  its  own  pensions,  mortgages,  insurance  policies,  tax  and  investment  advice,  unit  trust  and  financial  planning  all  under  one  roof  and  across  an  extensive  branch  network  up  and  down  the  country.    

By  pursuing  his  strategy  of  building  a  domestic  bancassurance  business  and  engaging  heavily  in  M&A,  over  the  course  of  the  1990s,  Pitman  almost  trebled  Lloyds’  assets  (see  Chart  6.4  above)  for  a  time  significantly  narrowing  the  gap  in  size  between  itself  and  Barclays.  By  1997,  when  Pitman  stepped  down  as  CEO,  Lloyds  had  a  market  value  of  £42  billion,  forty  times  its  value  when  Pitman  had  taken  over,  and  four  times  what  it  had  been  in  1992  (Fallon  2015,  p26;  see  also  Chart  6.4  above  and  table  6.1  below).  The  stock  market  value  of  Lloyds  had  shot  from  £1bn  in  the  1980s  to  over  £40bn  by  the  late  1990s  and  Lloyds  became  known  as  ‘a  cash  machine’  (Down,  2000,  p1).  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  6.1  above,  in  1997,  the  year  when  Pitman  became  Chairman,  Lloyds  was  delivering  38%  RoE  and  by  the  end  of  the  1990s,  it  was  still  routinely  beating  25%.  By  1999,  it  reported  having  a  return  on  equity  which  was  three  times  its  cost  of  equity  (Collier  et  al,  1999).    And  by  the  end  of  that  decade,  for  many  analysts  Lloyds  was  still  ‘Best  in  market’  (Collier  et  al,  1998,  p1;  and  Collier  et  al,  1999,  p1).    

With  such  high  share  prices,  and  market  popularity,  Pitman  was  able  to  take  huge  personal  rewards,  at  least  relative  to  others  at  the  time.  In  1995,  the  

Page 101: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  101  

year  Lloyds  acquired  TSB,  Pitman  took  home  £571,383  which  was  28%  more  than  his  previous  year  (Preston  2012,  p45).  Whilst  that  might  seem  low  to  the  bonus  pool  created  in  Barclays  in  the  decade,  which  saw  Roger  Jenkins  take  more  than  £40m  in  2005  and  Bob  Diamond  take  home  more  than  £60m  in  2009  (Treanor,  2010a),  it  was  a  lot  higher  than  what  other  banking  bosses  were  receiving  in  the  UK  at  the  time,  and  made  him  the  highest  paid  commercial  banker  in  the  UK  (Fallon  2015,  pp15,  318).  

Pitman’s  combination  of  conservative  retail  banking  combined  with  his  talent  for  deal-­‐making  and  desire  to  build  up  a  bancassurance  model  proved  to  be  a  winning  formula  –  at  least  as  far  as  the  market  was  concerned.  He  broadly  met  his  aim  to  double  his  bank’s  stock  market  value  every  three  years  (Fallon  2015,  p14).  His  popularity  was  won  not  just  by  ‘safe  banking’  or  focus  on  building  up  domestic  services,  however,  but  mainly  by  risky  deal-­‐making  and  through  some  colossal  acquisitions.  Contrary  to  his  later  claims  about  pursuing  ‘long  term  shareholder  value’  and  ‘narrow’  banking  (Future  of  Banking  Commission  2010),  Pitman  was  not  immune  to  the  short  term  demands  of  the  stock-­‐market,  but  was  compelled  to  take  huge  gambles  to  achieve  growth.  As  proved  to  be  the  case  a  decade  later  with  the  Co-­‐op’s  troublesome  Britannia  acquisition,  or  with  RBS’  acquisition  of  ABN  Amro,  M&A  is  inherently  very  risky  business,  and  misplaced  assumptions,  miscalculations  or  misjudgement  can  prove  to  be  ruinous  –  as  may  indeed  have  been  the  case  had  Lloyds  later  succeeded  on  its  ambitions  to  acquire  Fortis  or  Northern  Rock.  

In  Lloyds’  case,  its  growth  in  assets  also  teetered  upon  a  tiny  amount  of  equity.    As  is  evident  from  Table  6.1,  the  amount  of  Lloyds’  equity  was  negligible  –  at  times  only  2  or  3%.    

Table 6.1: Lloyds: assets and equity in £m and equity/ assets in % (1988-2013)

 (source:  Bankscope)  

   Year  (Y/E  31/12)   Assets  (M£)   Equity  (M£)   Equity/assets  (%)  

1988   51,834   3027   5.84  

1989   57,542   2532   4.40  

1990   55,202   2441   4.42  

1991   51,306   2642   5.15  

1992  62,937   2870   4.56  

1993   71,636   3233   4.51  

1994   73,200   3835   5.24  

Page 102: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  102  

                                                                                         

       

1995   101,487   3430   3.38  

1996   109,744   3781   3.45  

-­‐-­‐1997   129,166   4737   3.67  

1998   114,969   7,188   6.25  

1999   124,724   10,116   8.11  

2000   140,762   11,422   8.11  

2001   162,358   12,016   7.40  

2002   178,193   12,427   6.97  

-­‐-­‐  

2003  

184,553   12,669   6.87  

2004   286,363   12,783   4.46  

2005   311,621   11,620   3.73  

2006   345,664   12,476   3.61  

2007   353,543   13,439   3.80  

2008   436,191   9,572   2.19  

2009   572,980   13,713   2.39  

2010   1,008,732   47,732  4.73  

2011   988,366   51,273   5.19  

2012   952,463   46,984   4.93  

2013   862,004   44,086   5.11  

Page 103: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  103  

   

6.2.4     Meeting  market  demand  -­‐  Barclays    Lloyds  was  not  alone  in  developing  a  risky  business  model  in  the  way  it  

pushed  for  growth.  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  6.4  above  and  Table  6.2  below  between  1992  and  2001,  Barclays  also  grew  rapidly,  more  than  doubling  its  assets.  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  6.5  below,  Barclays  did  this  chiefly  by  growing  its  IB  operations  and  in  particular  those  performed  by  Barclays  Capital.      Having  joined  Barclays  in  1996  as  Head  of  ‘Global  Markets’  in  Barclays’  investment  banking  business,  BZW,  Bob  Diamond  quickly  moved  up  the  ranks  within  a  year  becoming  Chief  Executive  of  Barclays  Capital  –  the  parts  of  BZW’s  debt  business  which  Barclays  had  not  sold  to  Credit  Suisse.  He  set  about  building  Barclays,  and  more  specifically  Barclays  Capital,  into  a  key  player  in  global  investment  banking.  Having  to  compete  with  IB  giants  such  as  Morgan  Stanley,  JP  Morgan  and  Goldman  Sachs,  Barclays  had  a  long  way  to  catch  up  however.    At  the  end  of  the  millennium,  Diamond  took  advantage  of  cheap  lending  in  increasingly  liquid  markets,  and  built  up  Barclays  IB  operations  by  recruiting  heavily  from  the  US  and  London,  poaching  ‘talent’  from  other  banks  with  the  promise  of  high  salaries  and  fixed  bonuses,  setting  up  an  equity  based  ownership  plan  and  bonus  pool  for  ‘key  employees’  at  BGI  and  Barclays  Capital  in  2000  (Salz  2013,  para.4.12),  sowing  the  seeds  for  later  scandal  and  public  indignation  for  huge  bank  bonuses.    

   

 

 Chart 6.5: Barclays: assets by business in £bn (1993-2012)

(Salz,  2013,  4.12,  collating  data  from  Barclays  accounts  1993-­‐2012)    

Page 104: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  104  

By  the  turn  of  the  millennium,  Diamond  had  managed  to  build  up  a  significantly  large  asset  base  around  wholesale  and  IB:    and  Barclays  was  delivering  consistently  high  returns  on  equity  (see  Chart  6.2  above,  and  also  6.8  below).  The  analysts  were  not  quickly  won  around  however.  Despite  delivering  consistently  high  returns  on  equity  for  example  nearing  20%  towards  the  start  of  the  millennium,  Diamond  did  not  commonly  find  favour  amongst  analysts,  who  tended  to  report  Barclays’  hangover  of  its  poor  performance  in  the  early  1990s,  when  it  had  to  set  aside  £4bn  for  losses  incurred  in  1991  and  1992  (Salz  2013,  para.4.7).  In  the  early  part  of  the  millennium,  despite  impressive  growth  and  returns  (see  Charts  6.2  above,  and  also  Table  6.2  below),  analysts  commonly,  but  inaccurately,  predicted  relative  decline  or  modest  growth  at  best.  Several  advocated  investors  to  sell,  for  example  ING,  who  suggesting  that  Barclays  recent  returns  and  impressive  performance  ‘simply  looks  wrong’  (Helsby,  2002,  p1).      

 Table 6.2: Barclays: assets and equity in £m and equity/assets in % (1992-2013)

(source:  Bankscope  using  available  Local  GAAP,  unqualified  annual  reports)    

Page 105: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  105  

Year  (Y/E  31/12)   Assets  (M£)   Equity  (M£)   Equity/ass

ets  (%)  

1992   157917    5878   3.72  

1993   163159   5885   3.61  

1994   159363   6490   4.07  

1995   164184   7370   4.49  

1996   180321   7587   4.21  

-­‐-­‐1997   226427   7903    3.49  

1998   212366   8113   3.82  

1999   246748   8830   3.58  

2000   30747     14782   4.81  

2001   348436   14613   4.19  

2002   395727   15306    3.87  

2003   435296   16768   3.85  

2004   513875   19172   3.73  

2005-­‐    924170   24243   2.40  

2006    996503    27106   2.62  

2007    1227583    31821   2.72  

2008    2053029    43574   2.59  

2009    1379148    58699   2.12  

2010    1490038    62641   4.26  

2011    1563402    65170   4.20  

Page 106: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  106  

2012    1488761   59923       4.17  

2013    1312840   63220   4.82  

 

 Barclays  quickly  outpaced  these  early  pessimistic  predictions.  In  2003,  

Diamond  launched  the  ‘Alpha  plan’  aiming  to  double  its  revenue  every  four  years  (Salz  2013,  para.4.15).  He  recruited  a  very  close-­‐knit  and  hierarchical  leadership  team,  including  his  later    most-­‐trusted  lieutenants,  Rich  Ricci  and  Jerry  del  Missier.  Together  they  encouraged  a  culture  in  the  bank  which  was  results-­‐focused  and  which  heavily  rewarded  success  (Salz  2013,  para.8.22).  According  to  Brummer  (2015,  p277)  between  2002  and  2009,  Barclays  paid  out  an  average  of  £170  million  per  year  in  bonuses  to  a  changing  group  of  around  60  people.    In  2003,  the  group’s  pre-­‐tax  profits  rose  to  a  respectable  20%  and  Barclays  delivered  22%  ROE  (see  Chart  6.2  above).    Having  distributed  more  than  £6  billion  in  dividends  and  having  spent  more  than  £3  billion  in  share  buy  backs  between  1995  and  2003,  Barclays  could  not  help  but  attract  market  attention.    At  the  time,  in  2003,  the  share  which  was  soon  to  rise  stood  at  350p.    

By  the  end  of  2003,  growing  favour  for  Barclays  began  to  emerge  amongst  analysts,  with  those  at  Credit  Suisse,  and  Bear  Sterns  persuading  investors  to  ‘Buy!’  (Lever  et  al,  2003  ;  Cummings  et  al,  2003)  and  others  such  as  Morgan  Stanley  advocating  shareholders  to  at  least  ‘Hold’  Barclays’  stock  (Down  et  al,  2003a).  Barclays  subsequently  ramped  up  its  assets  (see  Chart  6.5  and  Table  6.2  above)  largely  through  the  increased  volumes  of  IB  work  being  undertaken  by  Barclays  Capital,  which  started  to  make  huge  profits  (see  Charts  6.5  above  and  6.6  below).      

 

Page 107: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  107  

 

Chart 6.6: Barclays: profits before tax by business in £bn (1993-2012)

(Source:  Salz,  2013,  4.12,  collating  data  from  Barclays  accounts)    The  group’s  share  price  steadily  rose.  In  2004,  it  breached  500p  and  

safely  made  it  beyond  570p  by  the  end  of  the  year,  leading  Deutsche  Bank  to  pass  favourable  comment  encouraging  investors  to  at  least  ‘hold’  (Lord  et  al,  2004b).  From  there  on  in,  support  for  Barclays  seemed  to  harden.  Credit  Suisse  routinely  encouraged  investors  to  ‘buy’  considering,  in  the  first  half  of  2004,  that  Barclays  would  ‘outperform’  the  market  (Lever  et  al,  2004a)  and  reporting  towards  the  end  of  the  year  on  how  Barclays  Capital  ‘opens  up  new  revenue  pools’  (Lever  et  al,  2004b,  p1).    

With  much  of  the  group’s  assets  being  tied  up  in  the  IB  operations  being  performed  by  Barclays  Capital,  which  were  all  ran  by  Bob  Diamond  (see  Chart  6.5),  it  was  not  long  before  Barclays  Capital  and  Bob  Diamond  attracted  particular  attention  (Lever  et  al,  2005).  In  2004,  it  was  reported  that  Diamond  narrowly  missed  out  on  the  CEO  role,  in  favour  of  Varley.  Whilst  Varley  stayed  on  as  CEO  until  1  January  2011  when  he  was  succeeded  by  Diamond,  he  gave  Diamond  huge  responsibility  for  managing  Barclays  IB,  appointing  him  as  ‘President’  of  the  Investment  Banking  Group  in  2005.    

A  series  of  acquisitions  took  place  in  2004  and  2005,  which  caused  Barclays  market  share  and  global  and  product  reach  to  grow  further.  Investor  confidence  followed  suite,  as  Barclays  continued  to  ‘outperform’  largely  through  growth  in  IB  operations,  which  were  funded  by  borrowing  at  low  interest  rates  in  the  increasingly  liquid  capital  markets  prevailing  in  the  early  2000s.  Whilst  

Page 108: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  108  

before  2005,  the  two  biggest  earning  businesses  in  Barclays  were  Barclays  UK  retail  and  its  corporate  division,  from  2005  onwards,  the  biggest  single  earner  and  biggest  in  terms  of  assets  was  Barclays  Capital  (Salz  2013,  paras.4.26,  5.12;  see  Charts  6.5  and  6.6  above).    Under  Diamond’s  supervision,  Barclays  IB  operations  grew  rapidly  and  by  2006,  nearly  half  of  Barclays  revenues  were  being  geared  towards  capital  markets,  with  Barclays  Capital  earning  more  than  any  other  business  (see  Charts  6.5  and  6.6  above).    

6.2.5     Exceeding  expectations  -­‐  Barclays  The  analysts  predictions  in  the  early  part  of  the  2000s  about  lacklustre  

performance  from  Barclays  were  consistently  out-­‐performed  (see  for  example  Helsby  et  al,  2002).    Analysts  such  as  those  at  Credit  Suisse  began  to  note  that  Barclays  was  ‘out-­‐performing  the  market’  (Lever  et  al,  2003,  p1)  and  had  ‘Good  Momentum’  (Kambo  et  al,  2004,  p1).  By  the  mid-­‐2000s,  a  growing  consensus  emerged  amongst  analysts  who  regularly  sang  Diamond’s  praises,  and  routinely  touted  Barclays’  stock,  encouraging  investors  to  ‘Buy!’.  By  2005,  the  share  price  breached  650p  and  analysts  commonly  touted  Barclays  stock,  for  example  with  Credit  Suisse  advocating  investors  to  give  Barclays  ‘Wholesale  support’  (Lever  et  al,  2005b).  

According  to  Salz  as  Barclays  grew  and  the  source  of  its  income  originated  from  ever  more  complex  investment  banking  activities,  something  of  a  cultural  change  was  taking  place  internally  in  Barclays,  and  the  risk-­‐taking  mentality  which  pervaded  in  investment  banking  began  to  spread  (Salz,  2013,  paras.2.11-­‐2.13,  3.21).  That  same  trend  was  observed  more  generally  by  the  PCBS  in  relation  to  Britain’s  biggest  banks,  including  not  only  Barclays  and  Lloyds.  Having  become  too  big  to  manage  (PCBS  2013b,  para.84)  UK  banks  generally  permitted  the  ‘culture’  of  banking  to  be  corrupted,  with  banking  standards  and  duties  to  customers  giving  way  to  risk-­‐taking  and  reward-­‐seeking  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras.116,  119)  –  a  development  across  the  sector  which  was  being  reinforced  by  perverse  remuneration  structures,  and  sales  target  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras.203,  416,  519,  536,  597  and  784).    

Those  problems  within  the  culture  of  banking,  and  the  radical  growth  of  IB,  were  not  raised  as  concerns  by  the  analysts,  who  on  the  whole,  appeared  unconcerned  by  the  fact  that  Barclays  was  delivering  low  returns  on  its  assets  (see  Chart  6.3  above).  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  6.3  above,  Barclays  typically  made  less  than  1%  profits  on  its  assets  and  in  2006,  2007,  and  2008  respectively,  its  RoA  was  as  little  as  0.46%,  0.36%  and  0.21%.  In  the  same  period,  there  is  an  absence  of  concern  expressed  amongst  analysts  about  whether  Barclays’  viability  was  dependent  upon  unusually  high  levels  of  market  liquidity.  As  table  6.3  shows,  in  the  years  leading  up  to  the  GFC,  the  market  valued  Barclays  in  a  significantly  higher  order  than  its  net  value.      

           

Page 109: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  109  

Table 3.3: Barclays book value (as total assets less total liabilities) and market capitalisation (taking average of final month each year) (2003-2008)

(source:  Orbis-­‐banker)  

 Year   Book  value  (£m)     Market  value  (£m)   Market  

value/Book  value  (in  %)    

 2016  

 64,441  

 37,904    

 59%  

2015   60,631     36,785     61%  2014   61,657       40,173     65%  2013   61,082     43,820     72%  2012   59,863     32,125     54%  2011   65,110     21,477     33%  2010   62,581     31,874     51%  2009   58,639     31,496   54%  2008   43,514     12,842     30%  2007   31,775     33,303     105%  2006   27,072     47,382     175%  2005   24,243     39,497     163%  2004   19,172     37,691     197%  2003   16,768     32,557     194%    

   

 Leading  up  to  the  crisis,  it  seems  that  there  was  no  alarm  expressed  amongst  analysts  about  whether  liquidity  and  demand  for  Barclays  IB  products  might  dry  up.  As  chart  6.7  shows  below,  Barclays  increased  its  dividend  payments  during  this  same  period.  Whilst  the  dividends  continued,  analyst  remained  supportive  and  unconcerned  by  Barclays’  business  model  or  by  its  valuation  exceeding  its  book  value.  Shortly  before  Gordon  Brown  declared  ‘there  would  be  no  return  to  boom  and  bust’  claiming  that  banks  had  managed  to  transform  risk  and  remove  it  from  the  sector,  in  2008,  Morgan  Stanley  analysed  the  widespread  growth  in  wholesale  capital  markets  and  concluded  that  growth  was  a  result  of  structural,  and  not  ‘cyclical’  factors  (Haynes  et  al,  2008)  which  was  a  sign  of  the  times,  when  irrational  exuberance,  and  the  transformation  myth  appeared  to  be  widespread.    

Instead,  Diamond’s  business  model,  albeit  heavily  dependent  upon  revenue  from  Barclays  Capital  which  in  turn  relied  upon  high  levels  of  liquidity  and  demand  for  IB  products,  was  commended  by  analysts.  Bear  Sterns  considered  the  IB  ‘sector  [was]  leading  growth’  and  that  Barclays  would  ‘outperform’  (Patel  et  al,  2007,  p1).  With  its  consistent  year  on  year  growth,  analysts  continued  to  favour  the  Barclays  business  model.  In  2007,  Barclays  was  Deutsche  Bank’s  ‘top  pick  of  the  year’  (Napier  et  al,  2007a,  p1)  and  it  encouraged  investors  to  ‘buy’  (Napier  et  al,  2007b).  By  the  summer  of  2007,  when  the  prospect  of  acquiring  ABN  Ambro  was  announced,  market  confidence  in  Barclays  was  still  high,  even  when  the  deal  fell  through,  and  the  share  price  fell  to  678p,  analysts  such  as  those  at  JP  Morgan  continued  to  advise  investors  to  ‘Hold’,  

Page 110: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  110  

suggesting  Barclays  has  ‘solid  organic  momentum  despite  ongoing  uncertainty  around  ABN’  (Antunes  et  al,  2007,  p2).    

     

     

Chart 6.7: Barclays : dividend pay-out per share (2000 – 2017)

(Source  :  Barclays)    As  can  be  seen  from  table  6.3  above,  in  the  mid  2000’s,  the  market  placed  

a  far  higher  value  on  Barclays  than  the  net  value  of  its  assets,  and  sometimes  twice  as  much.  Leading  up  to  the  crisis,  Barclays  market  value  was  worth  significantly  more  than  its  book  value.    

 

6.3     Part  2:  When  the  market  demands  too  much    

6.3.1     Lloyds’  strategic  bind    The  analysts  and  stock  market  were  not  as  warm  to  Lloyds  throughout  

the  2000s  as  they  were  to  Barclays.    Lloyds  soon  reached  something  of  an  impasse,  finding  it  difficult  to  keep  the  analysts  happy  and  to  deliver  the  high  levels  of  RoE  and  growth,  which  the  market  appeared  to  be  calling  for.    Between  the  start  of  the  millennium  and  2006,  Lloyds  fell  from  being  the  biggest  bank  in  terms  of  market  capitalization  to  being  the  fifth  biggest.    In  2000  and  2001,  Lloyds  attempted  to  take  over  the  Abbey  National,  but  the  merger  was  blocked  by  the  Competition  Commission.  The  positive  sentiment  previously  expressed  by  

Page 111: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  111  

analysts  towards  Pitman  in  the  1990s  soon  dried  up  after  he  was  replaced  by  Peter  Ellwood  as  CEO  in  1997,  notwithstanding  that  he  became  Chairman.  By  the  turn  of  the  millennium,  analysts  such  as  those  at  Morgan  Stanley  openly  called  for  greater  growth  :  ‘the  landscape  is  changing…  the  main  battleground  will  be  for  income  growth…  revenue  growth  will  be  the  key  to  differentiation’  (Down  et  al,  2000,  p1).  

Despite  still  achieving  high  RoE  (see  chart  6.1  above),  Lloyds  found  itself  incapable  of  delivering  huge  growth,  and  consequently  Ellwood  came  under  heavy  fire.  In  an  interview  in  2001,  he  commented  about  how  shareholders  were  ‘worried’  and  how  having  only  recently  inherited  a  legacy  with  very  limited  scope  for  M&A  in  the  UK,  he  was  already  being  given  the  message  from  investors  that  it  was  now  his  ‘last  chance’  (Davidson,  2001).  In  2001,  perhaps  realising  that  his  strategy  had  ran  its  course,  Pitman  resigned  as  Chairman,  having  been  CEO  between  1983  and  1997,  and  Chairman  between  1997  and  2001.  Pitman  had  been  skilful  in  fine-­‐tuning  Lloyds  into  an  efficient  banking  machine,  and  growing  its  balance  sheet  through  some  risky  and  aggressive  deal-­‐making,  but  in  what  was  already  a  rapidly  consolidating  banking  market,  Lloyds  had  little  further  scope  for  M&A  in  the  2000s,  at  least  in  the  UK.    

After  the  failed  Abbey  National  bid,  Ellwood  opted  not  to  bid  for  the  Woolwich,  preferring  instead  to  bid  for  Scottish  Widows.  And,  after  Barclays  acquired  the  Woolwich,  growing  its  own  branch  network  from  1718  to  2,120  branches,  there  were  few  potential  acquisition  targets  left  for  Lloyds.  Ellwood  and  his  successors  instead  had  to  explore  potential  mergers  abroad  (Davidson,  2001),  and  they  contemplated  being  adventurous  like  HSBC,  Citibank  and  Barclays  by  looking  to  acquire  banks  in  Africa,  the  Far  East  and  South  America  (Fallon  2015,  p130).  They  scouted,  unsuccessfully,  for  a  ‘merger  of  equals’  on  the  continent  looking  to  big  continental  banks,  such  as  Fortis  and  even  ABN  Amro,  Credit  Agricole,  BBVA,  BNP  Paribus,  Commerzbank  and  the  German  Postbank  (Fallon,  pp133,  411).  If  Lloyds  was  to  keep  up  with  its  fast  growing  competitors,  it  either  needed  to  make  a  huge  acquisition,  which  was  a  rapidly  diminishing  option,  or  ditch  its  aversion  to  derivatives  and  grow  its  wholesale  and  IB  activities.      

Unable  to  get  out  of  that  strategic  bind,  and  apparently  buckling  under  shareholder  pressure  Ellwood  took  early  retirement  at  the  age  of  60:    

 ‘Peter  Ellwood  retires  from  Lloyds  TSB  with  more  detractors  than  supporters.  The  share  price  has  halved  since  his  acquisition  of  Scottish  Widows  in  1999;  profits  are  down,  bad  debts  are  up.  Oh,  and  the  dividend  is  under  threat’    (The  Guardian,  2002).      His  successor,  Daniels  (CEO  between  2003-­‐2011),  and  the  Chairman  that  

soon  succeeded  van  den  Bergh,  namely  Victor  Blank  (Chairmen  between  2006-­‐2009)  were  all  caught  in  the  bind:  unable  to  make  a  success  of  Pitman’s  strategy,  but  unwilling  to  abandon  the  model  which  had  worked  so  well  previously,  and  which  distinguished  Lloyds  from  more  risky  investment  banks.    

Throughout  the  early  2000s,  the  analysts  continued  to  make  demands  for  greater  growth,  routinely  commenting  for  example  that  Lloyds  could  do  more.  Deutsche  Bank,  for  example,  bemoaned  the  lack  of  growth  suggesting  it  had  ‘unexploited  corporate  arms’  (Lord  et  al,  2004a).  Compared  to  Barclays,  which  was  starting  to  gain  stock  market  favour  by  2004,  Lloyds  was  not  maximising  its  

Page 112: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  112  

‘leverage  potential’  (Lord  et  al,  2004a).  Morgan  Stanley  lamented  that  Lloyds  was  ‘Still  underweight?’  and  suggested  ‘Recovery  won’t  be  easy!’  (Down  et  al,  2003a).    Their  unrealistic  demands  for  more  growth  were  hard  to  satisfy.  Despite  delivering  consistently  high  RoE,  even  of  the  order  of  30%  in  2003,  the  analysts  called  for  more  growth.    According  to  the  Independent  (Griffiths  et  al,  2002)  the  City  was  ‘underwhelmed’  by  Daniels  who  was  ‘under  pressure  to  put  his  foot  on  the  accelerator  for  growth’.        

Resisting  calls  for  greater  securitization,  in  October  2003,  Daniels  unveiled  Lloyds’  plan  to  re-­‐invigorate  the  core  UK  franchise.  He  sold  off  Brazilian  and  New  Zealand  and  South  American  assets.  Whilst  the  share  price  subsequently  increased  by  5%,  it  was  outperformed  by  others  in  the  sector,  chiefly  Barclays  and  those  who  had  invested  heavily  in  wholesale  derivative  and  securitisation  operations.  Daniels  sought  to  sweeten  shareholders  by  increasing  their  dividends  and  Lloyds  began  to  pay  down  unusually  high  dividends  to  enhance  shareholder  loyalty.  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  6.8,  Lloyds  consistently  paid  a  high  dividend  in  the  years  leading  up  to  the  crisis.    

   

Chart 6.8: Lloyds: dividend pay-out per share (2000 – 2017)

(Source  :  Lloyds)    

Despite  consistently  high  dividends,  analysts  remained  sceptical.  In  fact  with  such  high  dividends  factored  into  shareholder  returns,  Lloyds  was  actually  performing  above  par  by  comparison  with  its  competitors.  In  2004,  Société  Générale  reported  that  Lloyds  had  delivered  34%  RoE,  when  accounting  for  dividends,  but  nevertheless  it  still  advocated  investors  to  ‘sell’,  suggesting  that  Lloyds  was  in  a  dire  position  :  ‘Sustained  growth  will  need  real  Daniels  magic’  (Erskine  et  al,  2004,  p1).  As  can  be  seen  from  Table  6.4,  Lloyds’  market  value  exceeded  its  book  value  by  a  significant  order.  When  comparing  table  6.3  (above)  with  table  6.4  (below),  it  is  clear  that  for  a  period  leading  up  to  the  crisis  Lloyds’  

Page 113: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  113  

market  capitalisation  exceeded  its  book  value  by  a  significantly  higher  margin  than  Barclays.    

Table 6.4: Lloyds book value (as total assets less total liabilities) and market capitalisation (taking average of final month each year) (2003-2009)

(source:  Orbis-­‐banker)  

 Year   Book  value  

(nearest  £m)    Market  value  (nearest  £m)  

Market  value/Book  value  (in  %)    

 2016  

 47,034    

   44,616    

 95%  

2015   47,353   52,153     110%  2014   49,990     54,116     108%  2013   44,086     56,295     128%  2012   46,984     33,705     72%  2011   51,273     17,804     35%  2010   47,732     44,725     94%  2009   13,713   32,327     236%  2008   9,572     7,526     78%  2007   13,439   26,656   198%  2006   12,476       31,980       256%  2005   11,620   27,336   235%  2004   12,783   26,468         207%  2003   12,669   25,056       198%  

   

 In  2005  and  2006,  Lloyds’  market  capitalisation  was  comfortably  more  

than  double  its  net  assets.  Yet  around  the  same  time,  the  analysts  became  more  critical  of  Lloyds’  strategy.  Deutsche  Bank,  for  example,  became  openly  hostile  towards  Lloyds’  aversion  to  securitisation:    

 ‘Turnaround  potential  exists…significant  opportunity  exists  for  Lloyds  TSB  to  leverage  a  strong  market  share  in  lending  and  basic  banking  products  in  the  W&  IB  [wholesale  and  IB]  division  into  higher  fee  and  less  capital  intensive  products‘    (Napier,  2005,  p1).      Whilst  others  had  profited  hugely  from  funding  and  selling  mortgages  

adopting  an  ‘originate  to  distribute’  model  to  capitalise  upon  property  price  increases  particularly  at  the  start  of  the  millennium,  Lloyds  resisted  market  demands  and  continued  to  shun  subprime  lending  (Fallon,  p150).  Unlike  Barclays  (see  Chart  6.6  above),  staple  retail  banking  represented  more  than  half  of  the  bank’s  earnings.  Despite  market  pressure  to  engage  in  securitisation  and  ramp  up  IB,  Daniels  continued  in  Pitman’s  footsteps.  He  was  sceptical  about  the  selling  and  funding  platforms  needed  to  gear  up  the  balance  sheet  through  IB,  and  unwilling  to  risk  Lloyds’  reputation  with  its  clients  (Fallon  pp151-­‐179).  Such  

Page 114: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  114  

prudence  doubtless  came  at  a  personal  cost.  Daniels  could  probably  have  done  better  personally  had  Lloyds  engaged  in  IB.  Whilst  he  was  paid  between  £1.8m  to  £2.8m  in  2007,  Bob  Diamond  made  £20m  in  bonuses  alone  in  that  year,  and  Barclays  Capital  distributed  £500m  in  bonuses  to  a  pool  of  senior  management  (Fallon,  p152).    

Withstanding  powerful  contrary  incentives  and  strong  market  pressure,  Daniels  ordered  his  executives  to  avoid  securitization  altogether  (Fallon  p154).  In  2006,  Lehman  brothers’  Jeremy  Isaacs  made  a  direct  approach  attempting  to  persuade  Daniels  to  get  into  subprime  to  pump  more  volume  out  of  its  already  efficient  machine  (Fallon  2015,  p155).    Internally,  Lloyds’  own  mortgage  division  also  sought  to  persuade  Daniels  to  adopt  the  Northern  Rock  model  (Fallon  2015,  p156),  and  in  2007,  Lloyds  faced  the  prospect  of  shareholder  revolt  and  potentially  buy  out  thereafter.  Robin  Saunders  approached  the  Chair  of  the  Victor  Board,  seeking  a  10%  share  issue  in  favour  of  a  consortium  of  backers,  mainly  middle  eastern,  who  she  had  interested  in  the  proposition  on  the  basis  that  Lloyds  would  engage  wholesale  in  subprime  adopting  an  ‘originate  to  distribute’  model  akin  to  the  Northern  Rock  (Fallon  2015  pp158,  160).  Daniels  flatly  declined  the  proposal  (Fallon  2015,  pp161,  162).    

Whether,  in  a  different  conjuncture,  Lloyds  could  have  continued  to  resist  the  market’s  demands  for  securitization  is  uncertain,  but  has  to  be  doubted.  Had  the  banking  crisis  and  global  financial  crisis  not  subsequently  unfolded,  Lloyds  could  well  have  been  a  takeover  target  itself  for  a  less  cautious  buyer  looking  for  growth.  What  is  clear  is  that  Lloyds  was  under  immense  pressure  to  ramp  up  the  volume  of  its  sales  and  without  engaging  in  IB  that  provided  pressures  for  Lloyds  to  generate  revenue  from  its  customers,  including  through  the  mis-­‐selling  of  PPI.  Daniels  continued  Pitman’s  bancassurance  model,  and  reigned  as  CEO  during  the  period  when  most  of  Lloyds’  PPI  mis-­‐selling  took  place  (Osborne  2013).  He  not  only  later  sought  to  justify  PPI,  denying  any  mis-­‐selling,  but  was  also  a  strong  proponent  for    high  interest  rates  and  charges  for  overdraft  facilities,  arguing  that  high  risks  entitled  banks  to  higher  charges,  an  argument  which  was  accepted  in  litigation  (Fallon  2015,  p129).  Whilst  Daniels  managed  to  resist  calls  to  engage  in  sub-­‐prime  he  was  forced  to  take  Lloyds  into  more  pressurised  sales,  seeking  to  maximize  profits  from  selling  product  to  its  own  customers,  often  products  which  they  had  little  need  for,  such  as  PPI.    All  the  while,  Lloyds  looked  around  for  further  acquisitions,  and  whilst  the  Competition  Commission  had  threatened  to  block  any  further  takeovers  in  an  already  largely  consolidated  market,  things  changed  in  the  autumn  of  2008.  

 

6.3.2     Delivering  value  in  a  crisis  –  Lloyds  and  HBOS    

The  market’s  demands  for  earnings  and  growth  had  led  Barclays  to  contemplate  taking  over  ABN  Amro  in  2007,  which  would  have  been  a  disastrous  move  (Robbins  2009),  and  Lloyds  to  look  far  and  wide  for  merger  options.  Having  considered  and  approached  various  continental  and  foreign  banks,  including  BBVA,  ABN  Amro,  BNP  Paribus,  Commerzbank,  Germany’s  Postbank  and  America’s  Washington  Mutual  (Fallon  2015  pp144,  411,  412),  Lloyds’  appetite  for  M&A  was  widely  known.  In  2006,  Blank  discussed  taking  over  HBOS  and  even  met  with  Andy  Hornby  to  discuss  the  possibility  (Fallon  2015,  p138).    

Page 115: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  115  

In  2007,  after  the  Northern  Rock  defaulted  on  repaying  its  short  term  lending,  due  to  a  decline  in  sub-­‐prime  origination  and  securitisation,  Lloyds  offered  to  acquire  the  Northern  Rock,  subject  to  the  Bank  of  England  providing  short  term  lending  to  help  Lloyds  plug  Northern  Rock’s  funding  gap  (Fallon  2015,  pp184-­‐185).  The  Bank  of  England  refused  and  a  run  on  the  Northern  Rock  followed  on  13  September  2007.    

To  the  excitement  of  commentators  and  analysts,  rumours  spread  that  Lloyds  might  subsequently  take  over  the  failing  Alliance  &  Leicester  or  Bradford  &  Bingley  (Fallon  2015,  p211).  Commentators  were  enthusiastic  about  opportunities  for  consolidation  for  example  with  Murden  advocating  ‘Now  is  the  time  for  banks  to  go  bargain  hunting’  (2008).  Believing  there  was  opportunity  to  be  found  in  the  chaos,  however,  Daniels  and  Blank  held  out  for  a  bigger  prize,  which  eventually  came  in  the  form  of  the  failing  HBOS,  which  threatened  to  collapse  and  cause  widespread  economic  upheaval.  A  deal  which  would  have  been  impossible  when  Hornby  and  Blank  met  in  2006,  moved  to  becoming  a  possibility  and  then  as  banking  crisis  unfolded,  became  increasingly  inevitable  resulting  in  the  government  suddenly  confirming  that  it  would  waive  competition  rules  to  allow  the  merger  in  September  2008.    

By  the  summer  of  2008,  the  FSA  policy  vis-­‐à-­‐vis  HBOS  was  to  encourage  and  facilitate  a  merger  with  a  stronger  bank  (Fallon  2015  p233).      HBOS,  which  had  announced  in  February  2008  that  it  held  £6.3  billion,  nearly  a  tenth  of  its  assets  in  high-­‐risk  assets,  posed  a  liability  the  government  could  ill-­‐afford  to  bear.    Lloyds  by  contrast  had  only  limited  exposure  to  sub-­‐prime  assets:  it  wrote  off  a  mere  £200  million  on  11  December  2007  (Monoghan  2013).    Both  banks  endured  losses  in  the  banking  crisis,  but  Lloyds  was  in  a  far  stronger  position.  Even  though  on  30  July  2008,  Lloyds’  profits  were  down  70%  and  it  had  realized  £585m  of  losses  attributable  to  the  credit  crisis  (Monoghan  2013),  HBOS  was  in  a  far  worse  predicament.    In  a  single  day  on  17  September  2008,  HBOS  share  price  halved  in  the  first  hour  of  trading  (Monoghan  2013).  

Over  September  and  October  2008,  Lloyds  performed  hurried  due  diligence  but  it  was  impossible  to  value  HBOS  in  what  was  a  collapsing  conjuncture.  The  £1.7  billion  which  Lloyds  had  forecast  for  HBOS  impairments  in  September  was  revised  up  to  £2.4  billion  in  October  and  revised  again  to  £6bn  in  the  following  month  as  Lloyds  revised  up  its  estimates  about  whether  there  would  be  a  1  in  15  year  recession  to  a  1  in  25  year  event,  and  not  knowing  that  it  was  dealing  with  the  worst  recession  since  the  great  depression,  closer  to  a  1  in  100  year  event  (Fallon  2015,  pp294,  344,  406).      

The  Government  added  incentive  for  Lloyds  to  buy  HBOS,  informing  Lloyds  in  a  series  of  emergency  meetings  that  it  would  need  to  be  bailed  out  even  if  it  did  not  take  the  deal  and  then  rapidly  changing  the  terms  on  which  bail  out  would  be  provided.  On  2  October  2008  (the  Monday),  Lloyds  was  told  it  needed  to  take  £1.5  bn  of  government  money  if  it  did  not  merge  with  HBOS,  which  was  revised  up  to  £3bn  by  6  October  2008  (the  Friday),  £4bn  by  7  October  (the  Saturday)  and  on  8  October  2008  (the  Sunday)  Lloyds  was  told  it  would  need  £7bn  (Fallon  2015,  p327).  The  Treasury  and  the  Bank  of  England  told  Lloyds  that  it  needed  to  take  £7bn  of  government  money  if  it  was  a  standalone  bank,  which  would  result  in  Lloyds  being  42.5%  government-­‐owned,  or  only  £5.5bn  if  it  merged  with  HBOS,  which  would  result  in  43.5%  government-­‐ownership.    

Page 116: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  116  

The  Government’s  intervention  was  perceived  at  least  by  Daniels  as  arm-­‐twisting  and  strong-­‐arming  him  into  the  HBOS  acquisition  (Fallon  2015,  pp321-­‐328;  Dey  2009).    If  Lloyds  was  having  to  be  bailed  out,  as  well  as  RBS,  Daniels  wanted  assurances  that  others,  particularly  Barclays,  were  also  being  required  to  take  government  capital,  and  he  felt  misled  by  the  Bank  of  England  who  told  Daniels  that  Barclays  was  also  in  the  Treasury  in  other  rooms  having  other  talks,  when  Barclays  had  in  fact  avoided  taking  the  ‘queen’s  shilling’  (Fallon  2015,  p315-­‐335).      

Although  Blank  subsequently  boasted  about  the  merger,  it  was  arrived  at  through  extraordinary  risk  and  at  extraordinary  cost.  Lloyds,  which  had  prided  itself  on  being  a  solid  proposition  and  had  been  disparaging  of  the  riskier  funding  platforms  operated  by  its  more  reckless  peers,  had  to  be  bailed  out  by  the  state  who  dictated  the  terms  of  such  intervention.  It  was  subsequently  precluded  from  issuing  dividends  without  Treasury  approval  and,  in  due  course,  required  to  buy  back  £1  billion  worth  of  preference  shares  and  to  sell  off  more  than  600  branches.  Far  from  being  seen  as  the  saviour  which  prevented  the  UK  economy  being  plunged  into  recession,  Lloyds  was  merged  with  HBOS,  a  bank  which  itself  had  recklessly  over-­‐extended  itself  by  pursuing  a  policy  of  growth  at  all  costs  (Brummer,  2015).    

The  terms  of  the  deal  were  also  questionable.  As  the  subsequent  House  of  Lords  inquiry  discovered,  the  impairments  on  HBOS’  balance  sheet,  proved  to  be  greater  than  contemplated  in  October  2008  (Fallon  2015,  p409).  For  example,  its  exposure  to  the  downturn  in  the  Irish  and  Australian  construction  industries  proved  to  be  more  extensive  than  anticipated  (Fallon  2015,  pp346;  344).  Lloyds  had  made  provision  for  impairments  of  the  order  of  £23  billion  in  2009,  most  of  which  was  for  HBOS  liabilities,  but  the  full  extent  of  those  liabilities  was  thought  to  exceed  40  billion  (Fallon  2015,  p409).  Lloyds  consequently  made  huge  losses  in  2009,  and  was  not  able  to  return  to  profitability  until  2010.  As  is  demonstrated  in  Chart  6.9  below,  its  share  price  crashed  in  2008,  with  recovery  slow  and  limited  since  then.    

     

Page 117: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  117  

   

Chart 6.9: Lloyds : share price (2008-2015)

(source:  BBC)      The  HBOS  acquisition  appeared  to  be  the  logical  consequence  of  Pitman’s  

strategic  choices.  Lloyds  was  essentially  left  with  no  choice  but  to  take  a  deal  with  HBOS  which  was  something  of  a  ‘shotgun  wedding’,  ministered  by  the  state,  to  marry  a  good  bank  with  what  would  have  otherwise  been  a  huge  liability  for  the  state.  The  subsequent  reaction  to  the  deal,  provided  further  proof  of  the  market’s  demands  for  growth.  Despite  the  unknown  liabilities  in  HBOS  and  losses  which  would  eventually  follow,  the  market  favoured  the  deal.  The  crashing  share  price  soon  stabilised  (see  Chart  6.9  above)  and  would  have  likely  fallen  much  farther  had  the  merger  not  gone  ahead.  Indeed,  the  implications  of  the  merger  on  its  share  price  appeared  to  be  tangible.  In  a  single  day,  doubts  about  the  deal’s  feasibility  caused  the  share  price  to  plummet  by  15%,  from  p242.25  to  p237.5  (Fletcher  2008).  The  balance  of  opinion  amongst  analysts  favoured  the  merger.  Société  Générale  advocated  investors  to  ‘hold’  (Lee  et  al,  2008,  p1)  and  UBS  revised  ‘sell’  to  ‘neutral’  (Curran  et  al  2008,  p1).  Whilst  some  questioned  Lloyds’  capacity  to  finance  the  acquisition  and  the  sense  of  making  the  deal  in  the  middle  of  the  banking  crisis  (see  for  example,  White  2008),  analysts  tended  to  be  keen  on  the  merger,  enthusiastic  about  asset  growth,  increased  business  and  economies  of  scale  (see  for  example  Lee  et  al,  2008  and  Curran  et  al,  2008).        

 

6.3.3   Avoiding  bail-­‐out  -­‐  Barclays      

Page 118: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  118  

After  the  run  on  the  Northern  Rock,  Barclays  also  faced  huge  liquidity  problems.  Unable  to  settle  its  day-­‐trading  debts,  it  was  forced  to  borrow  £1.6  billion  from  the  Bank  of  England  sterling  standby  facility.    The  path  which  Diamond  had  led  Barclays  down  meant  that  it  was  heavily  reliant  on  liquidity  to  fund  huge  volumes  of  wholesale  and  IB  business.  When  the  liquidity  dried  up  in  the  credit  crunch,  Barclays  developed  a  gaping  capital  shortfall.  John  Varley,  Barclays’  Chairman,  considered  the  prospect  of  nationalization  to  be  completely  unpalatable  and  Roger  Jenkins,  one  of  the  biggest  beneficiaries  of  the  bonus  pool  set  up  by  Diamond  (who  was  thought  to  have  earned  between  £40m  and  £75m  in  2005,  was  tasked  with  raising  finance  from  the  Middle  East  to  avoid  bail  out  (Fallon  2015,  p318).    In  a  funding  episode  which  was  later  called  into  question  and  alleged  to  have  involved  bribery  and  back-­‐handers  (Brummer,  2015,  pp72-­‐73),  Barclays  managed  to  raise  £7.3bn  to  meet  what  was  required  by  the  FSA.  In  June  2008,  Barclays  called  upon  Qatari  backers  to  invest  £2.3bn  to  support  a  £4.5bn  share  issue  and  in  October  2008,  in  response  to  the  UK  government  announcing  that  Barclays  needed  to  raise  more  capital,  it  unveiled  terms  for  a  fresh  £7bn  capital  injection  from  Qatari  and  Abu  Dhabi  investors  to  boost  its  balance  sheet.  To  the  chagrin  of  some  of  its  institutional  shareholders,  who  argued  that  they  had  pre-­‐emption  rights,  existing  shareholders  were  left  out  and  Barclays  raised  a  total  of  £12  billion  from  Middle  East  investors,  paying  some  £400  million  in  ‘commissions’  or  ‘kick-­‐backs’  to  do  so,  and  in  one  kick  back  alone,  the  former  model-­‐cum-­‐financier  Amanda  Staveley,  is  said  to  have  received,  through  her  company,  a  £40  million  ‘introduction  fee’  (Brummer,  2015,  pp72-­‐73).  Being  forced  to  raise  capital  at  such  short  notice  put  Barclays  at  a  huge  disadvantage.  It  issued  equity  at  a  40%  discount  on  market  value,  as  opposed  to  the  8.5%  discount  which  had  been  offered  to  Lloyds  by  the  Treasury  (Fallon,  2015,  p320),  and  it  resulted  in  Barclays  becoming  16%  owned  by  new  middle  eastern  investors.      

Although  that  funding  spree  later  subjected  Barclays  to  serious  investigation  –  not  only  by  the  FCA  and  FSO  but  also  by  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  for  breaching  the  US  Foreign  Corrupt  Practices  Act  1977–  the  market  appreciated  that  Barclays  had  avoided  the  stigma  of  being  bailed  out  and  had  plugged  its  own  capital  hole  without  government  meddling.        Whilst  the  share  price  of  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  fell  radically  in  the  banking  crisis,  amongst  the  analysts,  Barclays’  popularity  remained  largely  intact.    The  credit  crunch  and  run  on  the  Northern  Rock  did  not  seem  to  tarnish  Barclays’  reputation.  Deutsche  Bank  continued  to  encourage  investors  to  ‘buy’  suggesting  that  ‘BarCap  and  BGI  fears  are  overdone’  (Napier  et  al,  2007c).    

Despite  the  economic  down  turn,  like  Lloyds,  Barclays  sought  to  create  an  opportunity  out  of  the  crisis  by  building  up  Barclays’  assets.  In  2008,  Barclays  had  continued  its  foreign  M&A  spree,  not  least  buying  Russian  (US$745  million)  and  Pakistan  banking  assets  (US$100  million)  (Barclays,  2008).  Most  significantly,  having  bid  for  the  Lehman  Brothers  brokerage  in  a  deal  which  was  eventually  quashed  by  the  regulators,  thus  forcing  Lehman  into  bankruptcy,  Barclays  managed  to  pick  up  Lehman  stock  at  fire-­‐sale  prices  –  $1.75  billion  (Salz  2013,  para.4.24).  Just  two  days  after  the  Lehman  bankruptcy,  it  was  reported  that  Diamond  had  picked  up  ‘the  crown  jewels’  of  the  brokerage,  leaving  behind  most  of  the  toxic  assets,  and  getting  most  of  IB  business,  three  of  its  buildings  including  the  iconic  New  York  building  and  some  10,000  staff  (Fallon  2015,  

Page 119: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  119  

p268).  Having  tried  unsuccessfully  to  takeover  Lehman  Brothers  before  it  was  declared  bankrupt,  which  probably  would  have  been  ruinous  for  Barclays  which  had  not  anticipated  the  £100  billion  in  liabilities  which  later  materialized  on  Lehman  Brother’s  balance  sheet  (Fallon  2015,  p268),  Diamond  turned  what  he  himself  perceived  to  be  a  failure  into  victory.  He  got  the  best  bits  of  Lehman  brothers  which  had  been  worth  £40  billion  on  the  stock-­‐market  a  year  earlier,  for  less  than  two  billion  (Fallon  2015,  p268).    

   

Chart 6.10: Barclays: equity and liabilities (1993-2012)

(source:  Barclays  annual  reports)  

6.3.4     Barclays’  halo    The  analysts  roundly  applauded  the  acquisition  and  continued  to  

advocate  the  purchase  or  retention  of  Barclays’  stock.  In  2008,  whilst  predicting  extremely  low  RoE,  analysts  still  considered  Barclays  posed  an  attractive  long  term  investment.  Deutsche  Bank  enthused  investors  to  ‘Buy!’  throughout  2008  (Napier  et  al,  2008a,  Napier  et  al,  2008b,  Napier  2008c),  as  did  analysts  at  Morgan  Stanley  who  considered  the  stock  to  be  ‘overweight’  (Hayne,  2008).        Despite  the  global  financial  crisis,  there  was  very  little  concern  expressed  amongst  analysts  about  the  business  model  Barclays  had  developed.  There  was  an  absence  of  any  suggestion  that  Barclays  had  contributed  to  its  own  liquidity  problems  by  ramping  up  its  IB  operations,  and  on  the  contrary,  analysts  continued  to  encourage  such  strategy.  For  example,  as  Barclays  Lehman’s  stock  doubling  down  on  its  IB  operations,  Deutsche  bank  considered  Barclays  had  availed  itself  of  a  good  ‘restructuring  opportunity’  (Napier  et  al  2008a).  

In  the  years  which  followed,  although  analysts  became  increasingly  critical  of  the  extent  of  Barclays'  leveraging.  Nevertheless,  analysts  roundly  applauded  the  appointment  of  Bob  Diamond  as  CEO  in  2010  (Treanor,  2010b),  and  whilst  the  consensus  to  buy  Barclays  stock  had  diminished,  the  market  

Page 120: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  120  

continued  to  express  favourable  sentiment  towards  Barclays  throughout  2011  and  2012,  notwithstanding  the  more  contrary  view  emerging  in  public  perception.      

6.4     Part  3:  Widespread  mis-­‐behaviour,  and  the  need  for  regime  change    

6.4.1   Diamond’s  departure  -­‐  amidst  market-­‐rigging      Diamond  had  proven  to  be  extremely  skilful  playing  to  the  market’s  

demands,  but  he  did  not  prove  to  be  as  deft  at  managing  his  public  perception.  A  fracture  appeared  between  his  reputation  amongst  investors  and  his  reputation  with  the  wider  public.    In  2009,  when  Barclays  sold  BGO  to  Black  Rock  Inc,  Diamond  extracted  a  £23  million  bonus,  taking  home  nearly  £70  million  in  compensation  for  the  year.  Whilst  the  market,  the  analysts  and  shareholders  were  content  with  Diamond,  such  that  he  was  the  only  and  obvious  choice  for  CEO  when  appointed  in  2011  (Salz  2013,  para.4.16),  his  humungous  ‘compensation’  packages  did  not  endear  him  to  the  public,  whose  indignity  was  given  expression  by  Lord  Mandelson’s  suggestion  that  Bob  Diamond  represented  the  ‘unacceptable  face  of  banking’  (Collins  2011).    

Diamond’s  suggestion  shortly  after  being  appointed  as  CEO  in  2011  that  ‘the  time  for  banker-­‐bashing  [was]  over’  misjudged  the  public  mood  and  attitude  towards  banks  (Treanor  2013a).  His  attempt  later  in  that  year  to  justify  himself  by  writing  an  article  in  the  Guardian  about  why  he  felt  ‘Banks  would  be  good  global  citizens’  (Schäfer  2013)  was  not  enough  to  save  his  public  perception.  As  he  later  admitted  ‘I  think  that  the  anger  against  banks  and  bankers  particularly  in  the  UK  was  deeper  than  I  realised’  (Schäfer  2013).    On  30  June  2012,  the  FSA  announced  that  Barclays  had  admitted  to  rigging  LIBOR  rates,  and  was  to  be  fined  £290  million  (FSA,  2012).  It  was  revealed  that  on  numerous  occasions,  and  in  ways  which  were  widespread,  systematic  and  condoned  by  senior  management,  traders  at  Barclays  Capital  had  rigged  LIBOR  rates  to  maximize  their  own  returns,  generally  with  a  view  to  enhancing  their  own  bonuses  (FSA,  2012).    

LIBOR  is  a  benchmark  rate  for  interbank  lending  set  by  bank  submissions.  In  December  2008,  the  British  Banking  Association’s  Angela  Knight,  had  defended  bank  involvement  in  setting  the  rate,  claiming  that  they  could  be  trusted  (Bloomberg,  2013).  On  the  contrary,  between  2007  and  2009,  Barclays  had  understated  the  bank’s  borrowing  costs  to  the  city  committees  to  pretend  that  its  creditors  had  more  confidence  in  the  bank  than  was  actually  the  case  and  on  numerous  occasions  had  adjusted  their  submissions  to  enhance  their  bonuses  (FSA,  2012).      In  short,  Barclays  had  been  dishonest  with  their  submissions  in  order  to  distort  and  manipulate  markets  and  rates  for  their  own  gain.  Having  been  trusted  with  setting  the  LIBOR  rate,  Barclays  was  found  to  have  abused  its  privilege.    

The  consequence  of  this  malpractice  went  beyond  a  mere  fine  for  Barclays,  and  the  others  involved  (which  is  what  Diamond  might  have  expected  when  Barclays  owned  up  to  its  involvement).    In  an  unprecedented  move  for  recent  times,  on  2  July  2012  the  Governor  of  the  Bank  of  England,  summoned  the  Chairman  of  Barclays,  Mr  Agius  to  his  office  and  essentially  asked  the  Chairman  

Page 121: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  121  

to  resign  and  to  go  away  and  think  about  whether  confidence  could  be  restored  if  Bob  Diamond  remained  CEO(Brummer  2015,  p147;  Treasury  Select  Committee,  2012).      On  3  July  2012,  Bob  Diamond,  albeit  incredulous  at  the  Bank  of  England’s  request,  handed  in  his  resignation  and  the  Chairman,  Marcus  Agius,  and  Chief  Operating  Officer,  Jerry  del  Missier  followed  suit  (Treanor,  2013a).    

In  response  to  public  outcry  at  LIBOR-­‐rigging,  Barclays  subsequently  arranged  for  an  independent  review  into  its  banking  practices  by  Anthony  Salz.  The  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  was  also  empowered  to  investigate  what  was  perceived  to  be  a  failure  in  banking  standards  and  culture.  The  misbehaviour  in  Barclays  and  Lloyds  was  not  limited  to  making  dishonest  submissions  and  rigging-­‐LIBOR.  The  findings  of  the  PCBS,  which  are  explored  in  more  detail  in  chapter  2,  at  2.2.7,  suggested  that  the  culture  at  the  heart  of  banking  in  Britain’s  major  banks,  and  not  only  Lloyds  and  Barclays  had  deteriorated,  with  professional  standards  giving  way  to  risk-­‐taking  and  reward-­‐seeking  behaviour  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras.597).    

Bankers  had  compromised  standards  of  expected  behaviour,  to  exploit  their  often  vulnerable  customers  (2013b,  paras.416,  519,  536)  and  management  had  not  only  turned  a  blind  eye  to  incidents  misbehaviour  (2013b,  para.784).  There  were  widespread  and  perverse  incentives  encouraging  misbehaviour  in  banks  (2013b,  para.203)  and  governance  structures  which  were  inapt  to  ensure  responsible  behaviour,  giving  a  veneer  of  orderliness  to  cover  up  the  lack  of  control  and  understanding  (2013b,  para.684).    

   

6.4.2     Daniels’  disappearing  act  –  before  the  PPI  scandal  After  losses  of  £11  billion  were  realized  in  2009,  investors  lost  confidence  

in  Blank  and  he  stepped  down  on  17  May  2009  (Monoghan  2013).  Seeking  to  ride  out  the  storm,  and  following  a  further  issue  of  shares  to  the  government  in  2009,  which  realized  £5.7  billion  in  investment,  Daniels  stayed  on  until  Lloyds  returned  to  profitability  in  2010  (Monoghan  2013).  On  20  September  2010,  he  announced  he  would  stand  down.  Whilst  Daniels  had  managed  to  guide  Lloyds  through  the  aftermath  of  the  HBOS  acquisition,  he  could  not  avoid  the  oncoming  scandal  of  PPI  mis-­‐selling.  Shortly  afterwards,  and  having  sold  40%  of  all  PPI  policies,  Lloyds  was  found  to  be  the  biggest  offender  in  what  soon  became  the  biggest  mis-­‐selling  saga  in  banking  history  (Monaghan  2013).    

In  2011,  the  banks  lost  their  judicial  review  of  the  FSA’s  decision  to  uphold  mis-­‐selling  complaints  (Weardon,  2011).  The  British  Banking  Association’s  Angela  Knight,  had  played  a  prominent  role  in  denying  any  wrongdoing  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI,  and  the  BBA  had  intended  to  continue  the  fight  and  appeal  the  decision  (Garside,  2012).  Ironically,  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  broke  ranks  with  the  BBA  and  accepted  the  validity  of  the  ruling,  exposing  Angela  Knight,  who  resigned  the  following  year,  to  public  criticism  (Garside,  2012).  Daniels  avoided  the  costly  consequences.    PPI  mis-­‐selling  claims  were  estimated  to  be  worth  in  the  order  of  £40  billion,  easily  dwarfing  any  other  mis-­‐selling  scandal.  All  of  the  banks  (the  Co-­‐op,  and  Nationwide  included)  appeared  to  have  played  their  part  in  selling  PPI,  but  Lloyds  took  particular  criticism.  Even  in  dealing  with  its  PPI  claims,  for  a  time,  Lloyds  was  found  to  have  acted  unreasonably  by  denying  any  liability  on  any  case,  regardless  of  merit  (Monaghan  2013).      

Page 122: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  122  

And  the  mis-­‐selling  culture  did  not  stop  at  PPI.  Interest  rate  swaps,  premium  bank  accounts  and  various  other  products  were  also  allegedly  mis-­‐sold  and  both  Lloyds  and  Barclays  settled  investigations  and  proceedings  in  connection  with  the  sale  of  interest  rates  swaps  (Monaghan  2013).  Lloyds  was  also  implicated  in  the  on-­‐going  FCA  GRG  investigation  into  GRG  and  it  may  well  be  concluded  that  Lloyds  along  with  RBS  and  GRG  purposefully  colluded  to  destroy  otherwise  viable  small  businesses  in  order  to  pick  up  their  assets  as  was  suggested  by  Tomlinson  (2013).  It  also  inherited  a  dubious  legacy  from  HBOS,  which  had  operated  various  schemes  of  fraud  against  their  customers,  leading  to  later  class  action  (Treanor,  2017).        

Also  whilst  Barclays  was  first  in  the  line  of  fire  for  rigging  LIBOR,  it  was  not  alone.  Lloyds  also  rigged  LIBOR  and  was  fined  £226  million  for  its  part  (Treanor  2014).  Amongst  other  things,  Lloyds  was  also  found  to  have  purposefully  manipulated  rates  in  order  to  reduce  the  fees  payable  for  its  emergency  lifeline  in  the  financial  crisis  and  was  obliged  to  repay  the  Bank  of  England  £6  million  (Treanor  2014).        

6.5   Conclusions      What  emerges  from  looking  closely  at  Lloyds  and  Barclays  over  a  

prolonged  period  is  a  story  of  two  formerly  conservative  and  cautious  banks  being  led  into  riskier  and  unsafe  activities  in  an  effort  to  keep  their  share  price  high  and  their  stock  desirable  to  investors.  Having  followed  the  rise  of  both  Pitman  and  Diamond  through  the  1990s  until  long  after  the  banking  crisis  unfolded  when  both  banks  were  implicated  in  multiple  scandals  and  allegations  of  misbehaviour,  it  is  evident  that  investor  demands  have  had  an  influencing  role  upon  the  development  of  their  business  models,  and  the  findings  of  the  many  inquiries  would  tend  to  suggest  that  these  pressures  have  also  encouraged  misbehaviour  and  standards  to  be  compromised.      

Demands  for  earnings  and  growth  saw  both  banks  depart  from  traditional  lines  of  retail  business,  radically  ramp  up  the  scale  of  their  activities  and  engage  in  riskier  behaviours.  The  pressures  exerted  on  Lloyds  led  it  to  pursue  risky  M&A  and  in  the  case  of  Barclays  they  led  it  to  develop  a  business  which  relied  on  transacting  huge  volumes  of  wholesale  and  IB  business,  which  in  turn  were  dependent  upon  potentially  unsustainable  demand  and  liquidity.    

As  those  banks  grew  to  gargantuan  sizes,  and  focused  on  keeping  investors  happy  by  delivering  earnings  and  growth,  it  seems  that  such  ownership  pressures  also  encouraged    the  cultivation  of  reward-­‐orientated,  risk-­‐taking  cultures  tolerant  of  misbehaviour  and  willing  to  compromise  standards  (2013b,  para.203,  597,  784,  and  836-­‐838).    In  the  light  of  findings  made  by  the  PCBS,  it  is  widely  considered  that  in  addition  to  developing  risky  business  models,  the  culture  in  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  degenerated,  becoming  tolerant  or  encouraging  of  misbehaviour,  with  a  results-­‐driven,  profit-­‐oriented  mentality  typical  of  investment  banking  spreading  and  prevailing  in  those  banks  (FCA,  2012;  Brummer,  2015,  ch.5;  Salz,  2013;  and  Fallon,  2015;  PCBS,  paras116-­‐119).  As  those  banks  were  submitting  dishonest  LIBOR  submissions  and  mis-­‐selling  products  to  their  often  vulnerable  customers  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras519),  investors  were  calling  upon  them  to  further  enhance  their  earnings  and  growth;  rather  

Page 123: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  123  

than  discouraging  misbehaviour  their  demands  encouraged  irresponsibility,  and  they  were  wholly  unsuitable  to  effectively  govern  standards  of  behaviour  (PCBS,  2013b,  pp176,  660-­‐668).    

Without  addressing  how  the  incentives  for  risk-­‐taking  are  driven  by  ownership  pressures  in  the  first  place,  it  seems  doubtful  whether  the  banking  reforms  implemented  in  the  UK  and  aimed  at  fixing  ‘culture’  can  ever  really  succeed.  Whether  or  not  removing  ownership  pressures  will  avoid  unsafe  business,  and  misbehaviour,  is  something  which  the  next  chapter,  which  is  concerned  with  structural  pressures  and  stakeholder  models,  can  consider  further.          

Page 124: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  124  

 

Chapter  7. ‘Structural  pressures’  and  the  Co-­‐op  and  the  

Nationwide    

7.1     Introduction    

The  two  cases  explored  in  chapter  6  suggested  that  much  of  the  dysfunctionality  in  banking  is  driven  by  banks  being  run  for  shareholder  value.  Ownership  pressures  encouraged  the  adoption  of  risky  business  models  and  the  development  of  internal  cultures  which  tolerated  or  encouraged  risk-­‐taking  and  misbehaviour.    This  chapter  considers  how  other  pressures,  unrelated  to  ownership,  also  influence  bank  behaviour.  It  pays  particular  attention  to  the  structural  pressures  discussed  in  chapters  4  and  5.  In  particular,  it  has  regard  to  the  ‘scale  requirement’  whereby  banks  need  to  achieve  economies  of  scale  to  meet  high  operating  costs,  and  to  grow  large  branch  network  in  order  to  achieve  market  access.  It  also  bears  in  mind  how  banks  are  encouraged  to  be  mimetic  and  to  engage  in  similar  behaviours,  by  the  heavy  operating  costs  involved  in  branch  banking  and  maintaining  free-­‐whilst-­‐in-­‐credit  banking  services.    

These  structural  pressures  are  explored  by  looking  at  two  non-­‐PLC  banks,  the  Co-­‐op  bank  and  the  Nationwide.  Those  cases  are  considered  with  a  view  to  understanding  how  structural  pressures  affected  their  behaviour,  how  far  they  contributed  towards  the  failure  of  the  Co-­‐op  and  how  they  encouraged  the  Nationwide  to  avoid  the  types  of  misbehaviour  which  others  were  implicated  in.  By  looking  at  two  stakeholder  banks  where  the  ownership  pressures  considered  in  the  last  chapter  were  absent,  it  tries  to  gain  a  closer  understanding  of  how  far  such  structural  pressures  drove  bad  strategy  and  mis-­‐behaviour.  

 As  discussed  in  chapter  5,  this  chapter  draws  mainly  on  financial  media  and  performance  data  for  the  two  cases  studied  with  a  view  to  exploring  what  led  to  the  failure  of  the  Co-­‐op,  and  conversely  in  the  case  of  the  Nationwide  how  failure  was  avoided.    It  studies  those  cases  over  slightly  different  time  spans.  The  focal  point  for  the  Co-­‐op  was  its  failure  in  2012  and  2013,  whereas  the  resilience  and  stability  of  the  Nationwide  could  be  observed  over  a  much  longer  timeframe.  The  Co-­‐op  is  thus  considered  between  2005  and  2015  in  other  words  from  pre-­‐crisis  times  through  the  banking  crisis  right  up  until  just  after  the  Co-­‐op’s  failure  when  the  various  inquiries  and  reports  into  that  failure  were  published.  The  Nationwide  is  considered  over  a  slightly  longer  period  of  time  namely  between  the  end  of  the  1990s  and  2014  in  order  to  get  a  longer-­‐term  picture  about  its  stability.  The  performance  data  for  the  Nationwide  was  thus  considered  from  the  late  1990s  until  2014.    Since  the  behavioural  issues  in  the  Co-­‐op  and  Nationwide  were  very  different,  unlike  Barclays  and  Lloyds  which  could  be  considered  alongside  one  another,  the  two  stakeholder  banks  are  analysed  separately.    

Page 125: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  125  

The  chapter  is  thus  broken  down  into  two  parts.  The  first  considers  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op,  a  bank  which  was  until  2013  owned  by  the  Co-­‐op  Group  a  co-­‐operative  society  owned  by  its  members.  This  first  part  is  set  out  into  three  sections.  The  first  describes  how  the  Co-­‐op  failed  and  moves  on  in  the  second  section  to  discuss  how  structural  pressures  were  influential,  especially  the  Co-­‐op’s  own  ‘scale  requirements’.  The  third  section  then  considers  governance  failures,  and  the  part  played  not  only  by  incompetence  amongst  the  Co-­‐op  Group  and  the  Co-­‐op  bank’s  managers,  but  also  by  hubris  more  broadly  amongst  the  regulators,  financial  media  and  even  politicians  who  all  seemed  to  encourage  the  Co-­‐op’s  radical  push  for  growth.    

The  second  part  then  considers  the  Nationwide  and  how  it  avoided  failure,  scandal  and  the  sorts  of  allegations  of  misbehaviour  commonly  made  against  its  peers.  It  explores  how  it  developed  a  more  conservative  business  model,  considers  how  it  was  also  involved  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI,  and  considers  also  how  its  regulation  has  encouraged  its  more  orthodox  and  conservative  business  model.      

7.2     Part  1:  structural  pressures,  and  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op    

7.2.1   The  Co-­‐op’s  failure    

In  a  prolonged  advertising  campaign  spanning  years  after  the  banking  crisis,  the  Co-­‐op  bank  marketed  itself  as  the  go-­‐to  ethical  bank  claiming  to  be  ‘good  with  money’,  suggesting  it  was  not  only  ethically  good  but  also  competently  good  at  handling  other  peoples’  money.  That  claim  was  soon  rubbished  by  subsequent  events.  On  21  March  2013,  it  was  reported  that  the  Co-­‐op  had  realised  losses  in  the  order  of  £673  million  arising  out  of  its  Britannia  merger.  On  the  same  day,  its  claim  to  be  ethically  good  with  money  was  undermined  by  its  announcement  that  it  needed  to  budget  a  further  £150  million  to  compensate  customers  for  past  PPI  mis-­‐selling  (Neate,  2013).    

The  extent  of  bad  debts  stemming  from  the  Britannia  loan  book  eventually  rose  to  £14.5  billion,  creating  a  £1.9  billion  capital  hole  which  the  Co-­‐op  Group  could  not  afford  to  fill,  even  after  selling  its  insurance  and  asset  management  arms  (Treanor,  2014a).  Its  Chief  Executive,  Barry  Tootell,  quickly  resigned,  and  on  24  April  2013,  the  Group’s  chairman  Peter  Marks,  publicly  admitted  that  the  Co-­‐op  Bank  was  in  no  position  to  bid  for  Project  Verde,  the  632  branches  being  divested  from  Lloyds  (Neate  2013).    Moody’s  down-­‐graded  the  Co-­‐op’s  credit-­‐rating  to  junk  status,  and  the  Coop  had  to  suspend  its  corporate  lending  and  sell  off  8%  of  Britannia’s  loans  (Neate  2013).    

In  a  time  of  crisis,  when  one  might  look  to  a  company  Chairman  to  steady  the  ship,  the  Co-­‐op’s  Chairman,  Paul  Flowers,  was  caught  buying  illegal  drugs  (Craven,  2013).  The  Co-­‐op  Group,  which  had  itself  been  on  a  dash  for  growth,  demonstrated  by  its  expensive  acquisition  of  the  Somerfield  supermarket  chain,  was  not  in  a  position  to  help,  and  instead,  two  American  hedge  funds,  Aurelius  Capital  Management  and  Silver  Point  Capital,  bought  up  the  majority  of  the  Co-­‐op’s  bonds,  later  agreeing  to  convert  such  large  amounts  of  debt  into  equity,  for  a  

Page 126: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  126  

70%  stake  in  the  bank.  The  result  was  that  the  Co-­‐op  Group  become  a  minority  shareholder  initially  with  30%  and  subsequently  20%  shares  (Scuffham  2014).      

In  short  order,  the  Co-­‐op  lost  its  long-­‐standing  status  as  a  member-­‐owned  bank,  made  a  mockery  of  its  ‘good  with  money’  claim,  and  fell  into  the  ownership  and  control  of  the  US  hedge  funds  that  bailed  it  out.  Although  the  Co-­‐op  bank  tried  subsequently  to  preserve  its  brand  as  an  ethical  Co-­‐operative,  having  incorporated  its  ‘ethical  charter’  into  the  company  constitution,  there  was  an  exodus  of  customers  with  almost  40,000  customers  leaving  the  bank  and  switching  their  accounts  (Goff,  2014).    Amidst  public  outcry  and  confusion  as  to  how  the  Bank  could  have  got  itself  into  such  trouble,  various  official  inquiries  were  launched  into  the  Bank’s  failure.  The  Treasury,  the  Prudential  Regulation  Authority,  the  Financial  Regulation  Council  as  well  as  various  Parliamentary  select  committees  conducted  investigations.    It  is  clear  from  the  result  of  their  inquiries  that  the  Co-­‐op  had  not  been  ‘good  with  money’  and  its  stakeholder-­‐ownership  had  not  precluded  it  from  adopting  the  sorts  of  risky  strategies  and  behaviours,  which  were  common  for  shareholder-­‐owned  banks.    

The  Co-­‐op  was  lambasted  for  having  a  governance  structure  which  was  ineffective  and  management  who  were  unqualified  and  inept  (Kelly  2014;  FCA  2015).  The  Co-­‐op  avoided  being  fined,  and  was  issued  with  a  public  censure  by  the  FCA  and  PRA  whose  joint  investigation  was  critical  of  the  Co-­‐op’s  governance  and  management  (FCA  2015).  It  accused  the  Co-­‐op  of  failing  to  be  transparent,  concealing  information,  and  misrepresenting  and  misleading  the  public  and  regulators  about  its  capital  position.  The  FCA  and  PRA  (2015)  found  that  in  the  year  ending  31  December  2012,  the  Co-­‐op  wrongly  declared  that  adequate  capitalisation  could  be  maintained  or  was  available  to  cover  regulatory  requirements.    In  fact,  the  FCA  found  that  the  Co-­‐op  Bank  did  not  have  sufficient  capital  to  meet  requirements  and  concluded  that  there  was  no  reasonable  basis  to  justify  the  Co-­‐op  Bank’s  belief  to  the  contrary.    

Furthermore,  the  FCA  considered  that  the  Co-­‐op’s  management  had  adjusted  monthly  impairments  to  achieve  targets  over-­‐riding  the  risk-­‐grading  which  would  ordinarily  be  applied  to  the  loans  the  Co-­‐op  inherited  from  the  Britannia  merger  in  order  to  improve  perceptions  about  the  bank’s  capital  adequacy  position.  And  like  Britain’s  other  mainstream  banks  which  were  accused  of  cultivating  cultures  that  were  too  tolerant  of  misbehaviour  (PCBS,  2013b,  paras.116,  119,  176,  203,  519,  597,  784,  and  836),  the  Co-­‐op  bank  was  also  found  by  the  FCA  and  PRA  to  have  fostered  a  culture  which  prioritised  its  short-­‐  term  financial  position  at  the  cost  of  taking  prudent  and  sustainable  actions  for  the  longer  term  (FCA  2015,  para.1.76).    

The  report  criticised  management  incompetence,  exemplified  by  Paul  Flowers’  evidence  at  a  Treasury  Committee  hearing  that  the  Co-­‐op  had  only  £3bn  in  assets  when  it  had  over  £40  billion  (Treanor,  2013b).    The  Co-­‐op’s  governance  structure  was  found  to  be  unfit  for  purpose  with  senior  management  being  incapable  of  scrutinising  the  merits  of  the  Britannia  deal  and  running  a  large  bank  (Kelly  2014,  FCA,  2015).Populated  by  place-­‐men  and  political  appointments  both  the  management  and  the  board  were  not  qualified  to  assume  significant  financial  and  commercial  roles  (Kelly  2014).  The  set-­‐up  in  the  Co-­‐op,  as  Brummer  (2015,  p16)  put  it,  had  management  ‘on  top’  and  advisers  ‘on  tap’,  and  was  not  fit  to  provide  the  scrutiny,  oversight  and  checks  needed  to  ensure  that  the  right  decisions  were  made  if  and  when  advisers  got  things  wrong.    

Page 127: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  127  

The  Co-­‐op’s  failure  raises  important  questions  not  only  about  management  competence  and  governance  but  also  about  what  drove  a  small  stakeholder  bank  to  seek  to  grow  so  radically  and  in  such  short  succession      

7.2.2   The  Co-­‐op’s  growth  imperative    

The  Co-­‐op  had  spent  the  late  1990s  and  early  part  of  the  millennium  focusing  on  building  up  orthodox  banking  services,  rolling  out  new  products  such  as  premium  accounts  linked  with  insurance  products,  the  smile  credit  card,  and  its  internet  and  telephone  banking  services.  By  the  mid-­‐2000s,  the  Co-­‐op  bank  was  still  modest  in  size  compared  to  other  UK  banks  and  it  had  less  than  £15  billion  in  2008  (see  table  7.1).      Table 7.1: Barclays, Lloyds, Nationwide and Co-op: total assets in £m (2008-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope,  using  IFRS  unqualified  accounts  with  y/e  31.12  for  each  of  the  banks  save  for  Nationwide,  using  available  accounts  with  y/e  04.04)    

  Barclays   Lloyds   Nationwide   Co-­‐op  2008   2053029   436191   201093   14964  2009   1379148   572980   190497   46138  2010   1490038   1008732   187699   43581  2011   1563402   988366   194988   48935  2012   1488761   952463   189318   49772  2013   1312840   862004   188889   43396  

 As  far  back  as  1992,  the  Co-­‐op  committed  itself  to  pursuing  an  ‘ethical'  

banking  policy.  Whilst  ethical  banking  may  have  many  different  meanings,  in  the  Co-­‐op’s  case  it  branded  itself  as  an  alternative  to  shareholder-­‐run  banks,  offering  to  bank  not  in  self-­‐interested  ways,  but  for  the  benefit  of  its  customers,  investing  in  accordance  with  its  ethical  policy  informed  through  customer  feedback  in  order  to  promote  various  social  and  environmental  aims  (the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  2010,  pp1,  3).    

But  this  strategy  to  corner  the  ethical  banking  market  did  not  deliver  growth  on  the  scale  needed  to  give  it  the  market  access  its  peers  enjoyed.    Prior  to  merging  with  the  Britannia  the  Co-­‐op  had  only  90  branches,  and  even  post-­‐merger  in  2014,  it  still  only  had  342  branches,  whereas  the  Nationwide  had  800  and  Lloyds  had  2,875  branches  (Jones  2012).    Even  after  the  merger,  in  2008,  the  Co-­‐op  had  only  a  2%  share  of  the  retail  banking  market,  whereas  Lloyds  had  30%  and  the  Nationwide’s  had  7%  (Jones  2012).    The  Co-­‐op’s  scope  for  achieving  growth  was  very  limited.  The  retail  banking  market  was  characterised  by  customers  reluctance  to  switch  between  banks  and  a  stranglehold  by  the  biggest  banks  over  current  accounts,  with  the  big  four  providing  77%  of  personal  accounts  and  85%  of  SME  business  accounts  (Independent  Banking  Commission  2011).  Furthermore,  in  retail  banking,  a  bank’s  market  share  correlates  closely  with  the  size  of  a  bank’s  branch  network,  which  are  costly  to  operate  (Bowman  et  al  2014,p94).    

Page 128: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  128  

To  deliver  growth  on  a  radical  scale  in  such  a  market,  the  Co-­‐op  needed  to  do  more  than  capitalise  on  its  ethical  credentials,  which  is  something  it  had  been  doing  since  1992.  Drastic  steps  were  needed  if  the  Co-­‐op  was  to  become  a  ‘challenger  bank’  to  the  big  four.    It  radically  needed  to  grow  its  branch  network.  Having  sought  to  distinguish  itself  from  shareholder  banks  and  proclaimed  itself  as  ‘good  with  money’,  the  Co-­‐op  could  hardly  try  to  fund  building  such  branches  by  engaging  in  the  types  of  securitization  and  IB  the  Northern  Rock  and  other  demutualised  societies  had  capitalised  on.  The  only  obvious  alternative  was  to  try  to  make  a  sizeable  acquisition,  which  it  did  in  2009  when  it  merged  with  the  Britannia  adding  :  £35  bn  in  assets  to  its  own  £15  bn,  254  branches  to  its  90  branches,  and  2.8  million  customers  to  its  50,000  customers.    The  merger  with  the  Britannia  in  2009  in  fact  created  a  bank  with  £43  billion  in  assets,  300  branches,  and  more  than  3  million  customers  and  it  enabled  the  Co-­‐op  to  position  itself  as  a  challenger  bank,  and  to  put  itself  in  the  running  for  taking  on  the  632  branches  being  divested  from  Lloyds.      

In  July  2011,  just  two  years  on  from  the  merger,  the  Co-­‐op  set  itself  up  as  a  serious  contender  to  take  over  the  Lloyds  branches.    Were  it  to  succeed  in  doing  so,  it  would  have  resulted  in  the  bank  having  1,000  branches  and  in  other  words  10%  of  the  UK  branch  network,  serving  11  million  customers  and  having  a  7%  share  of  the  UK  retail  banking  market  (Jones,  2012).  Given  the  Co-­‐op’s  need  to  grow  its  branch  network,  the  prospect  of  both  merging  with  the  Britannia,  and  taking  over  Lloyds’  divested  branches  must  have  been  extremely  attractive  for  the  Co-­‐op’s  management.      

As  the  next  section  shows,  management  incompetence  and  governance  failures  played  a  key  part  in  causing  the  Co-­‐op’s  fateful  acquisition  of  the  Britannia.  But  what  is  interesting  about  the  Co-­‐op  is  that  its  progression  towards  its  own  failure  was  somewhat  pathological:  it  was  driven  down  a  perilous  path  by  its  manifest  need  to  gain  market  access,  which  required  it  to  achieve  radically  greater  scale.    Furthermore,  and  as  the  next  section  shall  explore,  the  Co-­‐op’s  management  was  clearly  not  alone  in  failing  to  foresee  problems  with  its  capital  adequacy  and  the  Britannia  deal.  Its  advisers,  auditors,  accountants,  as  well  as  the  regulators,  and  financial  commentators  who  approved  its  growth  all  failed  to  foresee  troubles  before  the  Co-­‐op’s  2012  crisis  unfolded.          

7.2.3   Governance  and  oversight  failures    

7.2.3.1  Immediate  oversight  failures  

 Whilst  the  Co-­‐op  Bank  was  considering  acquiring  the  Britannia,  the  Co-­‐op  

Group,  which  wholly  owned  the  bank,  was  committing  its  own  resources  to  expanding  its  supermarket  business,  having  paid  £1.57  bn  to  take  over  Sommerfield  (BBC,  2008).  By  the  time  the  Co-­‐op  encountered  its  own  capital  shortfall  in  2013,  the  Group  had  just  moved  into  expensive  newly  built  headquarters.  It  was  neither  in  a  position  to  provide  assistance  financially,  nor  was  it  governed  in  a  way  which  was  fit  to  supervise  and  oversee  the  activities  of  the  Co-­‐op  bank  (Myners,  2014,  ch.1).  Although  shareholders  may  have  more  of  an  interest  in  trading  their  shares  than  taking  a  long  term  interest  in  governing  

Page 129: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  129  

the  companies  they  own,  capital  market  actors,  such  as  analysts  and  financial  media,  provide  a  lot  of  analysis  and  scrutiny  of  company  activities.  In  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op,  whose  shares  were  not  traded,  there  was  not  only  an  absence  of  such  analysis  but  furthermore  a  labyrinthine  management  structure,  made  up  mainly  of  ‘placemen’,  which  was  not  fit  to  provide  long  term  oversight  and  governance  of  the  Co-­‐op  Bank  (Myners,  2014,  ch.1).           When  it  came  to  the  Britannia  acquisition,  there  was  thus  an  absence  of  analysis  and  a  failure  of  oversight  by  the  Co-­‐op’s  Group.  It  is  clear  in  retrospect  that  the  Britannia’s  mortgage  book  and  commercial  loans  were  wildly  over-­‐priced  in  the  merger,  and  the  Co-­‐op’s  management  failed  to  value  the  assets  and  foresee  likely  delinquencies  (Kelly,  2014).  The  mispricing  of  Britannia’s  assets,  and  the  subsequent  writing  down  or  writing  off  of  bad  loans,  was  the  main  cause  for  the  Co-­‐op’s  subsequent  failure,  although  various  operational  and  integration  costs,  not  least  in  respect  of  IT  infrastructure  and  provision  required  for  PPI,  also  contributed  towards  the  Co-­‐op’s  subsequent  capital  shortfall    (Kelly  2014;  Treasury  Committee  2014).      The  Co-­‐op’s  board  believed  its  management  had  performed  appropriate  due  diligence  and  stress-­‐testing,  and  that  they  had  made  a  prudent  allowance  against  future  impairment  of  the  more  risky  assets  in  the  form  of  a  Fair  Value  Adjustment  (Murray,  2014).  Unlike  other  M&As  where  goodwill  proved  to  be  the  riskiest  asset  and  most  difficult  to  value,  goodwill  does  not  appear  to  have  been  a  large  part  of  the  deal.  As  the  transfer  of  engagement  did  not  involve  a  direct  payment  of  cash  consideration  (other  than  the  maintenance  of  Britannia  customer  rewards  and  the  payment  of  their  fees  for  joining  the  Co-­‐op),  there  was  no  amount  directly  payable  for  Britannia’s  goodwill.  In  any  case,  Britannia’s  goodwill  was  only  a  fraction  of  its  total  assets,  being  valued  at  £194.8  million  in  2009.  The  Britannia  appears  to  have  written  that  off  as  a  part  of  the  deal,  and  the  Co-­‐op  appears  only  to  have  capitalised  £600,000  on  its  accounts  for  goodwill  as  a  result  of  the  deal  (Co-­‐op,  2009,  p3,  p132).  The  writing-­‐off  of  goodwill  by  the  Britannia  does  not  necessarily  mean  the  goodwill  disappeared  however,  as  it  may  well  have  influenced,  in  an  indirect  way,  the  amount  the  Co-­‐op  was  willing  to  pay  for  the  Britannia’s  other  assets.  But  by  far  and  away,  the  riskiest  part  of  the  Britannia’s  assets  was  its  corporate  loan  book,  and  in  particular  the  commercial  real  estate  lending,  which  according  to  Kelly  was  vastly  over-­‐valued,  with  only  the  most  cursory  of  due  diligence  being  performed  (Murray,  2014;  Kelly,  2014).      

7.2.3.2  Wider  oversight  failures  

 The  Co-­‐op  bank’s  management,  and  the  Group  which  was  criticised  for  

not  keeping  better  watch  on  management,  were  not  alone  in  failing  to  spot  the  risks.  Criticism  can  also  be  levelled  against  the  Co-­‐op’s  advisers  and  its  auditors  as  well  as  the  regulators  who  waved  through  the  Britannia  deal.  The  Co-­‐op’s  auditors,  KPMG,  who  were  paid  £1m  to  audit  the  merger  (Tyrie  2014),  did  not  doubt  the  pricing  of  assets.  Despite  later  claiming  to  have  conducted  ‘thorough’  due  diligence  (Brummer  2015,  p5),  it  transpired  that  KPMG  had  not  even  inspected  Britannia’s  loss-­‐making  corporate  loan  book,  which  was  one  of  the  biggest  factors  contributing  to  the  Co-­‐op’s  subsequent  capital  shortfall  (Brummer  2015,  2015,  p5).  KPMG  subsequently  denied  being  responsible  for  

Page 130: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  130  

performing  due  diligence  alleging  that  the  Co-­‐op  bank  was  responsible  for  its  own  due  diligence,  notwithstanding  their  earlier  claim  that  their  due  diligence  had  been  ‘thorough’    (Brummer  2015,  p5).    

The  Co-­‐op’s  investment  bankers,  JP  Morgan,  who  were  paid  £7m  to  assist  in  the  merger  (Tyrie  2014)  also  advised  that  that  the  deal  was  ‘fair’  and  its  commercial  and  strategic  logic  was  ‘compelling’  (Brummer  2015,  p6),  and  they  told  the  board  that  the  due  diligence  ‘exceeded  that  normally  undertaken  for  listed  companies’,  a  claim  which  must  be  doubted  if  nobody  had  scrutinised  the  commercial  loan  book  (Brummer  2015,  p6).  

Had  due  diligence  been  performed  properly,  it  should  have  been  reasonably  apparent  that  the  Britannia  was  overpriced  (Kelly,  2014).  Unlike  Lloyds’s  difficult  task  of  valuing  HBOS  hurriedly,  it  was  not  a  complicated  problem  to  value  the  Britannia’s  loan  books.  As  the  Kelly  Report  (2014)  noted,  the  commercial  loans  were  not  complex  syndicated  loans,  but  a  few  dozen  loans  on  shopping  centres  and  office  developments.  It  should  not  have  been  difficult  to  spot  that  there  were  a  small  number  of  large  commercial  loans  which  were  outside  of  the  Co-­‐op’s  traditional  risk  appetite,  and  which  had  the  potential  to  materialise  significant  impairments  if  property  prices  fell,  which  they  were  liable  to  do  in  2009.  It  should  also  have  been  evident  that  the  Britannia  had  been  over-­‐extending  itself  on  home  loans  for  some  time  including  providing  some  self-­‐certifying  mortgages,  whose  average  quality  must  have  been  at  least  questionable,  not  being  as  good  as  the  loans  the  Co-­‐op  made  (Kelly  2014).      But  it  seems  that  the  obvious  question  about  what  the  quality  of  Britannia’s  loan  book  was,  was  not  discussed  by  anyone,  including  the  Co-­‐op’s  advisers.      

The  Co-­‐op  contemplated  litigation  against  both  KPMG  and  J  P  Morgan  (Chu,  2014).  However,  no  formal  legal  proceedings  were  brought,  but  that  is  not  to  say  that  the  same  were  not  confidentially  compromised  in  an  unreported  settlement.  Without  official  findings  about  whether  the  Co-­‐op  was  responsible  for  its  due  diligence,  it  is  difficult  to  say  for  sure  whether  its  advisers  were  necessarily  negligent.  But  what  is  clear  is  that  there  was  an  absence  of  internal  expertise  and  a  failure  on  the  part  of  management  to  adequately  perform  due  diligence  (Kelly,  2014;  Murray,  2014).  Although  the  Co-­‐op  Bank  had  expertise  ‘on  tap’,  it  did  not  have  it  ‘on  top’,  and  instead  was  instead  populated  by  placemen,  wholly  unsuited  to  the  task  of  spotting  what  were  widely  considered  to  be  vastly  over-­‐valued  assets  (Brummer,  2015,  p16).      

 

7.2.3.3    hubris  everywhere  -­‐  the  financial  media’s  failure    

 There  was  also  an  absence  of  analysis  amongst  the  financial  media.  On  12  

October  2008,  just  4  days  after  the  UK  Government  had  announced  its  £850  billion  pound  bank  bail  out  programme,  the  mainstream  financial  press  all  announced  that  the  Co-­‐op  and  Britannia  were  in  merger  talks  to  create  a  super-­‐mutual.    In  mid-­‐January  2009,  the  necessary  legislative  instrument,  the  ‘Butterfill  Act’,  was  passed.  On  21  January  2009,  the  Co-­‐op  and  Britannia  announced  their  agreement  to  merge,  subject  to  approval  by  regulators  and  mutual  members.  On  29  April  2009  Britannia's  members  voted  overwhelmingly  in  favour  of  merger.  On  24  July  2009,  the  merger  was  approved  by  the  FSA,  who  had  conducted  its  own  audit  approving  the  deal.  And  on  1  August  2009,  the  merger  finally  took  

Page 131: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  131  

place.    Within  that  chronology,  there  were  three  events  which  ought  to  have  raised  serious  concerns  about  the  deal.  The  first  occurred  at  the  start  of  2009,  when  the  Britannia  reported  problems  in  2008  blaming  rising  bad  debt,  as  a  reason  for  profits  falling  from  £50.5m  to  £31.2m.  The  second  was  in  February  2009  when  Moody  and  Fitch  downgraded  the  Coop’s  credit  rating  to  ‘negative’  because  of  fears  of  it  taking  on  a  legacy  of  debt  from  the  Britannia.  The  third  occurred  in  March  2009,  when  Britannia  reported  92%  losses  for  the  full  2008  year.    

Notwithstanding  those  warnings,  it  appears  from  a  review  of  broadsheet  financial  commentary,  including  the  Financial  Times,  the  Telegraph  and  the  Guardian,  over  that  same  period  of  time  that  not  one  financial  commentator  questioned  the  prudence  of  the  deal.    On  the  contrary,  the  broadsheet  commentary  appeared  to  report  favourably  on  the  news  of  the  merger,  re-­‐publishing  what  looked  like  it  might  even  have  been  the  Co-­‐op’s  own  press  releases.  Commentators  typically  only  reported  on  the  beneficial  features  of  the  deal.  On  12  October  2008,  when  the  announcement  first  broke,  the  broadsheets  were  boastful  about  the  possible  creation  of  a  ‘Super  Mutual’  with  9  million  customers,  12,000  employees,  over  300  branches  and  £70  billion  worth  of  assets  under  management.  On  21  January  2009,  when  the  merger  announcement  was  made  the  financial  press  provided  remarkably  similar  coverage  to  one  another  about  the  beneficial  details  of  the  proposed  merger,  suggesting  that  there  was  scope  for  a  mutual  to  succeed  in  the  crisis  where  PLCs  failed.  The  FT  headlined  with  ‘Britannia  and  Co-­‐op  merge  into  “super-­‐mutual”’  (Croft,  2009)  and  the  Guardian  went  with  the  remarkably  similar  ‘Britannia  and  Co-­‐operative  to  create  £70bn  “super-­‐mutual”’  (Collinson,  2009).  The  former  suggested  the  Co-­‐op  was  in  a  ‘safer  haven’  (Croft,  2009)  and  the  latter  commented  upon  the  trend  for  consolidation  likely  continuing  amongst  mutuals  (Collinson,  2009).    

A  review  of  the  broadsheet  newspapers  in  this  period  suggests  that  not  one  commentator  raised  concerns  about  the  deal–  which  is  surprising  given  that  it  took  place  at  the  height  of  the  crisis  in  something  of  a  free  falling  economic  conjuncture,  when  regulators  were  requiring  banks  to  hold  increasing  amounts  of  capital.  Instead,  the  press  appeared  to  share  the  Co-­‐op’s  optimism  and  enthusiasm  for  the  deal  and  did  not  raise  concerns;  that  position  appeared  to  prevail  even  after  Moody  and  Fitch’s  decision  in  May  2009  to  downgrade  the  Co-­‐op’s  credit  rating  from  ‘stable’  to  ‘negative’.  Even  following  the  Britannia’s  announcement  in  March  2009  about  its  92%  losses,  commentators  did  not  seriously  challenge  the  merger  or  argue  that  it  looked  unsafe.  The  Financial  Times  did  not  retract  its  view  that  the  Co-­‐op  was  a  ‘safer  haven’  but  went  on  to  award  the  Co-­‐op  the  Financial  Time’s  ‘Sustainable  Bank  of  the  year  award’  (the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  2010,  p.3).      

7.2.3.4  Hubris  –  in  political  circles  

 Ironically,  the  success  of  the  Co-­‐op’s  ethical  branding  campaign  may  well  

have  encouraged  political  support  for  the  merger.    Having  capitalised  on  its  distinct  member-­‐owned  structure  free  from  shareholder  pressures  and  its  ethical  brand  (the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  2010,  pp3,  5),  the  Co-­‐op  had  smoothed  the  path  for  others  to  accept  its  claim  that  the  merger  would  create  a  super  mutual  

Page 132: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  132  

and  ethical  alternative  to  shareholders.    Its  success  in  moulding  the  public’s  perception  into  believing  that  there  could  be  a  ‘a  new  era  dawning  for  the  financial  services  market’  (the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  2010,  p.5)  with  a  place  for  a  ‘super-­‐mutual’  may  well  have  encouraged  complacency  more  broadly  amongst  politicians.  There  was  no  resistance  to  the  merger  reported  from  any  of  the  political  parties.  Many  politicians  favoured  the  Co-­‐op’s  radical  push  for  growth.  George  Osborne  welcomed  the  Co-­‐op’s  bid  for  project  verde  heralding:    

‘a  new  banking  system  for  Britain  that  gives  real  choice  to  customers  and  supports  the  economy.  The  sale  of  hundreds  of  Lloyds  branches  to  the  Co-­‐operative  creates  a  new  challenger  bank  and  promotes  mutuals’    (Trotman  2012).    

 The  regulators  were  similarly  apparently  supportive  of  the  Co-­‐op’s  push  

for  growth,  notwithstanding  that  the  FSA  had  secretly  identified  the  Britannia  as  a  building  society  which  needed  to  be  rescued  knowing  that  without  a  merger,  the  Britannia  might  need  bailing  out  (Brummer  2015,  p5).  The  FSA  permitted  the  deal  to  proceed  without  full  due  diligence  being  performed,  and  they  subsequently  allowed  the  appointment  of  the  Reverend  Flowers  as  Chairman  in  2010  –  a  person  who  was  subsequently  found  to  be  ‘not  suitably  qualified  for  the  role  of  chairman’  (Kelly  2014).    

In  this  climate  of  encouragement,  where  the  apparent  mentality  of  the  herd  favoured  the  creation  of  an  ethical  challenger  bank  and  where  the  Co-­‐op’s  strategic  growth  imperatives  had  been  set  by  structural  pressures  beyond  its  control,  the  willingness  of  the  Co-­‐op  to  take  on  assets  outside  of  its  traditional  risk  appetite  and  to  try  to  put  itself  in  the  running  for  project  Verde  is  not  entirely  surprising.    Whilst  the  Co-­‐op  provided  misleading  information  and  unreasonably  prolonged  what  were  unrealistic  expectations,  its  ambitiousness  in  the  first  place  was  a  natural  consequence  of  needing  to  get  market  access,  and  the  Co-­‐op’s  governance  structure  was  not  alone  in  failing  to  keep  such  ambitions  in  check:  the  shareholders  of  all  failing  shareholder  banks  also  provided  inadequate  oversight.  What  is  clear  in  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op  is  that,  however  owned,  the  problems  of  over-­‐ambition  and  hubris  still  need  to  be  checked.          

7.3     Part  2:  structural  pressures  and  the  case  of  the  Nationwide    

7.3.1   The  Nationwide’s  resilience    Whilst  the  Co-­‐op  pushed  for  radical  growth  in  unsafe  ways,  the  

Nationwide  got  through  the  financial  crisis,  whilst  growing  only  modestly,  and  whilst  also  delivering  award-­‐winning  retail  banking  services.    Like  the  Co-­‐op,  the  Nationwide  was  free  from  the  types  of  ownership  pressures  observed  in  chapter  6  in  the  cases  of  Barclays  and  Lloyds.  Although  the  Nationwide  had  issued  some  limited  equity,  it  was  never  ran  to  deliver  as  much  value  as  possible  for  its  shareholders,  and,  as  we  shall  see,  it  found  ways  to  issue  equity  which  necessarily  limited  returns  and  shareholder  rights.    

Page 133: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  133  

The  Nationwide  was  also  not  subject  to  the  same  structural  pressures  which  drove  the  Co-­‐op’s  over-­‐ambitiousness.  By  2008,  in  terms  of  its  size,  the  Nationwide  was  already  well  established  in  UK  retail  banking  being  five  times  the  size  of  the  Co-­‐op,  and  a  quarter  the  size  of  Lloyds.  As  can  be  seen  from  Table  7.2  below,  the  Nationwide  had  £189  billion  in  assets  compared  to  the  Co-­‐op’s  £43  billion  post-­‐merger  and  Lloyds’  £862  billion.  Before  Lloyds  acquired  HBOS,  Nationwide,  with  its  £178  billion  in  assets,  was  just  shy  of  being  half  as  big  as  Lloyds  which  had  £436  billion  in  assets  (see  Table  7.1  above  and  Charts  7.1-­‐7.3  below).          

   Chart 7.1: Barclays, Lloyds, Nationwide and Co-op: total assets in £m (2008-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope,  using  available  IFRS  unqualified  accounts)    

Barclays  

Nationwide  0  

500000  

1000000  

1500000  

2000000  

2500000  

2008   2009   2010   2011   2012   2013  

Barclays  

Lloyds  

Nationwide  

The  co-­‐op  

Page 134: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  134  

   Chart 7.2: Lloyds and Nationwide: total assets in £m (2008-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope,  using  available  IFRS  unqualified  accounts)      

   Chart 7.3: Nationwide and Co-op: total assets in £m (2008-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope;  using  available  IFRS  unqualified  accounts)    

 Nationwide’s  size  came  with  significant  market  access  and  market  share.  

The  Co-­‐op  only  had  90  branches  prior  to  the  Britannia  merger  and  only  342  branches  with  a  2%  share  of  retail  banking  market  afterwards,  in  2012,  the  

0  

200000  

400000  

600000  

800000  

1000000  

1200000  

2008   2009   2010   2011   2012   2013  

Lloyds  

Nationwide  

0  

50000  

100000  

150000  

200000  

250000  

2008   2009   2010   2011   2012  

Nationwide  

Co-­‐op  

Page 135: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  135  

Nationwide  already  had  over  800  branches  and  7%  of  the  market  which  was  half  as  many  as  Barclays’  1625  branches,  and  nearly  a  quarter  of  Lloyds’  2,875  branches  (Jones,  2012).  Because  the  Nationwide  already  had  a  lot  of  branches  and  a  significant  market  share,  it  did  not  suffer  from  the  same  growth  imperative  which  drove  the  Co-­‐op’s  acquisitiveness.    

Whilst  the  Nationwide  was  free  from  the  types  of  ownership  pressures  we  saw  were  exerted  on  Lloyds  and  Barclays  and  free  from  the  types  of  structural  pressures  exerted  on  the  Co-­‐op,  we  can  see  that  it  developed  a  more  conservative  business  model.  Its  business  model  was  neither  dependent  upon  making  huge  acquisitions,  nor  on  transacting  huge  volumes  of  wholesale  and  IB  business  relying  upon  wholesale  funding.    

That  is  not  to  say  however  that  the  Nationwide  was  adverse  to  risk-­‐taking  and  M&A.  The  Nationwide  is  the  product  of  scores  of  acquisitions:  its  website  suggests  it  has  acquired  172  building  societies  and  other  businesses  in  nearly  two  hundred  years  (Nationwide,  2015).  In  2006,  it  took  on  its  largest  acquisition  in  the  form  of  the  Portman  Building  Society.  According  to  Bankscope,  before  being  acquired,  Portman  had  assets  of  the  order  of  £21bn.  After  the  crisis  unfolded,  the  Nationwide  then  picked  up  the  Derbyshire  and  Cheshire  Building  Societies  which  according  to  Bankscope  had  combined  assets  of  nearly  £12bn.  In  short  succession,  between  2006  and  2008,  the  Nationwide  thus  grew  by  more  than  £30  billion  through  sizeable  acquisitions,  but  such  assets  still  represented  less  than  a  fifth  of  Nationwide’s  total  assets  (see  Table  7.2  and  Chart  7.4  below).    Table 7.2: Nationwide’s total assets in £m (1990-2014)

(Source:  Bankscope;  amalgamating  available  GAAP  and  IFRS  accounts:  GAAP  unqualified  accounts  y/e  04.04  for  years  1990-­‐2005;  IFRS  unqualified  accounts  for  y/e  04.04  for  years  2006-­‐2014)    YEAR   MILLIONS  

 1990   26647.1  1991   31124.9  1992   34119.0  1993   34996.0  1994   35423.4  1995   35742.2  1996   37600.9  1997   40292.2  1998   46522.6  1999   52052.0  2000   62612.2  2001   69576.8  2002   73044.6  2003   83946.0  2004   99645.5  2005   109674.3    2006   118228.3  2007   132695.2  

Page 136: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  136  

2008   178482.1  2009   201093.0  2010   190497.0  2011   187699.0  2012   194988.0  2013   189318.0  2014   188889.0          

   Chart 7.4: Nationwide’s growth trajectory in £m (1991-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope,  amalgamating  available  GAAP  and  IFRS  accounts:  GAAP  unqualified  accounts  between  y/e04.04  for  1990-­‐2005  and  IFRS  unqualified  accounts  for  y/e  04.04  for  2006-­‐2014)    

Whilst  the  Nationwide’s  growth  was  significant  in  the  decade  leading  up  to  the  financial  crisis,  its  growth  was  not  dominated  by  M&A,  and  what  M&A  the  Nationwide  engaged  in  was  not  significant  when  compared  with  the  M&A  activity  at  both  Lloyds,  and  the  Co-­‐op.    The  Britannia  had  more  assets  than  both  of  Nationwide’s  two  biggest  acquisitions  combined.  In  relative  terms,  the  Nationwide’s  M&A  was  thus  incremental,  and  not  transformative  like  that  of  Lloyds  or  the  Co-­‐op.  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  7.2  above,  before  HBOS  appeared  on  Lloyds’  radar,  Lloyds  only  had  £436  billion  in  assets,  which  is  slightly  more  than  twice  as  many  assets  as  Nationwide.    Through  the  single  acquisition  of  HBOS,  Lloyds  more  than  doubled  its  size,  and  for  the  briefest  of  periods  entered  the  £1  trillion  club  (see  Table  7.1  above).    The  Co-­‐op’s  M&A  was  even  more  radical  relative  to  its  size.  The  Co-­‐op  had  only  £13  billion  in  assets  when  it  acquired  the  Britannia  which  had  £37  billion  in  assets.  Prior  to  the  Britannia  acquisition,  the  Co-­‐op  was  less  than  a  tenth  the  size  of  the  Nationwide  (see  Chart  7.3  above).  By  making  that  one  acquisition,  the  Co-­‐op  was  able  to  grow  three-­‐fold  and  become  the  Nationwide’s  nearest  rival,  in  terms  of  size,  allowing  it  to  be  championed  as  a  challenger  bank  in  UK  banking  (see  Charts  7.3).  Unlike  the  Co-­‐

Nationwide  

0  50000  100000  150000  200000  250000  

1991  

1993  

1995  

1997  

1999  

2001  

2003  

2005  

2007  

2009  

2011  

2013  

Nationwide  

Page 137: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  137  

op  and  Lloyds,  the  Nationwide  did  not  bet  the  proverbial  house  on  a  single,  potentially  catastrophic,  deal.  And  unlike  Lloyds  and  the  Co-­‐op,  the  Nationwide  did  not  make  any  large  acquisitions  after  the  financial  crisis  and  banking  crisis  had  developed.      

 

7.3.2     Its  part  in  mis-­‐selling  The  Nationwide  not  only  embarked  upon  M&A  like  other  retail  banks,  but  

it  also  engaged  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI  and  interest  rate  swaps  (Osborne  2013).  However,  the  Nationwide  was  not  as  heavily  involved  as  other  banks  in  selling  PPI.  Its  was  responsible  for  mis-­‐selling  only  a  tiny  fraction  of  the  total  PPI  mis-­‐sold  :  see  Chart  7.5  below  which  compares  the  role  of  different  banks  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI  over  a  four  years  period  between  2010  and  2014.  As  can  be  seen  from  Chart  7.5,  both  in  actual  terms  and  in  relative  terms  in  proportion  to  their  retail  assets,  Barclays  and  Lloyds  played  a  far  bigger  role  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI.  As  at  20  September  2012,  the  Nationwide  accounted  for  only  1.3%  of  the  total  mis-­‐selling  amongst  banks  compared  to  Lloyds’  40%  (Collinson,  2014).  That  the  Nationwide  was  involved  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI  might  tend  to  suggest  that  an  absence  of  ownership  pressures  is  not  a  guarantee  for  good  behaviour,  at  least  not  when  it  comes  to  competing  in  what  was  a  developed  product  market  when  banks  are  under  pressures  to  recover  heavy  operating  costs  (Bowman  et  al  2014).      

On  the  other  hand  the  fact  that  the  Nationwide  was  less  heavily  involved  in  mis-­‐selling  PPI  than  its  peers,  might  even  suggest  that  it  was  subjected  to  less  pressures  to  exploit  its  customers,  than  those  exerted  on  its  peers.  Data  relating  to  the  handling  of  PPI  complaints  also  indicates  that  the  Nationwide  may  have  been  less  aggressive  in  selling  such  policies.  As  at  March  2014,  of  the  6,436  complaints  made  against  the  Nationwide,  only  10%  were  upheld,  which  is  significantly  smaller  than  the  77%  of  the  36,506  complaints  upheld  against  Barclays  (Collinson  2014).  There  is  also  evidence  to  suggest  that  the  Nationwide’s  reputation  with  its  customers  was  better  preserved:  in  2013,  the  Nationwide  was  complained  about  less  than  the  other  major  financial  institution  in  the  UK  (see  Table  7.3).  In  2012,  Nationwide  came  3rd  in  a  JD  Power  review  of  customer  services  amongst  banks,  and  was  rated  9th  out  of  28  banks  in  the  review  of  customer  satisfaction  amongst  28  banks  conducted  by  Which?  (Jones  2012).  Although  the  Co-­‐op  beat  the  Nationwide,  coming  2nd  in  both  surveys,  the  Nationwide  was  ahead  of  Lloyds  and  Barclays,  which  out  of  28  banks  surveyed  in  the  Which?  survey  came  25th  and  20th,  respectively  (Jones  2012).                            

Page 138: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  138  

Table 7.3: complaints upheld (July-December 2013)

(Source  Collinson,  2014,  citing  the  Financial  Ombudsman)    Most  complained  about  financial  institutions  Bank   Number  of  

complaints  (01.07.13-­‐31.12.13)  

Percentage  upheld  

Lloyds  TSB   40,500   54%  

Barclays   36,506   77%  

Nationwide     6,436   10%          

   Chart 7.5: Top six banks provision for mis-selling by category (2010-2014)

(Source:  Treanor,  2015,  referring  to  Standard  &  Poor’s)  

7.3.3   Its  more  traditional  business    

Page 139: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  139  

Nationwide’s  growth  appears  to  have  been  organic  and  not  radical  or  sporadic.    As  can  be  seen  from  table  7.2  and  chart  7.4  above,  at  the  start  of  the  millennium,  Nationwide’s  assets  were  just  over  £62bn,  and  they  had  more  than  tripled  over  the  period  leading  up  to  the  end  of  the  2014  financial  year  growing  to  £190bn.  Of  the  £130bn  increase,  it  appears  that  a  little  more  than  £30bn  can  be  attributed  to  M&A  and  the  lion’s  share  arose  from  originating  new  lending  to  borrowers,  which  as  we  shall  see  below,  was  comprised  mainly  of  lending  secured  against  properties.  Nationwide’s  funding  also  appears  to  have  been  relatively  conservative.    As  can  be  seen  from  table  7.4  below,  in  the  year  ending  4  April  2014,  79%  of  Nationwide’s  funding  came  from  deposits.  By  comparison,  looking  back  over  the  last  5  years,  generally  less  than  half  of  Barclays’  total  assets  have  been  contributed  by  depositor  funds  and  the  figure  is  slightly  more  than  half  for  Lloyds.  On  the  other  hand  like  the  Nationwide,  the  Co-­‐op  has  sustained  a  high  proportion  of  depositor  funding.  In  that  respect,  Nationwide  and  the  Co-­‐op  more  closely  resembled  the  paradigm  model  of  an  orthodox  retail  bank,  intermediating  between  small  savers  and  borrowers,  whereas  Barclays  and  Lloyds  departed  from  such  role.  

 Table 7.4: Barclays, Lloyds, Nationwide and Co-op: % of assets and % of lending composed of deposits (2006-2014)

(Source:  Bankscope)          

YEAR  

Barclays  %  of  assets  made  up  of  deposits  

Lloyds  %  of  assets  made  up  of  deposits  

Nationwide  %  of  assets  made  up  of  deposit  

Co-­‐op  %  of  assets  made  up  of    deposit  

Barclays  %  lending  made  up  of  deposits  

Lloyds  %  lending  made  up  of  deposits  

Nationwide%  lending  made  up  of  deposits  

Coop  %  of  lending  made  up  of  deposit  

2006   -­‐   57.51    72.66   81.67   -­‐   86.99   114.02   86.99  2007   -­‐   59.83   69.34     87.60   -­‐   86.84   122.30   86.84  2008   -­‐   51.21   66.96   84.30   -­‐   88.64   111.13   88.64  2009   48.03   40.88   -­‐   75.88   116.86   107.29   NS   107.2

9  2010   43.57   55.86   -­‐   81.11   117.01   104.58   NS   104.5

8  2011   45.54   60.25   -­‐   81.10   115.54   94.60   NS     94.60  2012   48.95   65.33   73.09   79.43   100.08   92.41   101.98   92.41  2013   52.84   71.49   74.57   82.19   94.03   94.77   105.68   94.77  2014       79.88         102.85    

     

The  Nationwide  thus  achieved  more  organic  growth  by  undertaking  more  traditional  lending  and  borrowing  and  without  ramping  up  its  assets  like  Barclays,  or  others  banks  such  as  the  Northern  Rock  who  fuelled  the  production  

Page 140: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  140  

of  large  volume  low  quality  securities  through  use  of  wholesale  funds  (see  table  7.5  which  compares  the  percentage  of  assets  made  up  of  interbank  lending  for  different  banks).  When  inter-­‐bank  lending,  and  the  market  for  selling  securities,  dried  up  in  the  credit  crunch,  Nationwide  was  not  directly  imperilled  but  had  developed  a  safer  business  model  built  upon  depositor  funding  and  mortgage  lending  (see  table  7.4  above).  By  focusing  on  retail  services  and  savings  product,  Nationwide  managed  to  build  up  a  high  quality  asset  base,  as  well  as  developing  a  lower  risk  profile  on  its  funding  base.  It  built  up  its  depositor  base,  whilst  also  growing  its  funding  and  lending.          Table 7.5: Barclays, Lloyds, Nationwide and Co-op interbank assets/ interbank lending in % (2006-2014) YEAR   Barclays:  

%  Interbank  assets/  interbank  lending  

Lloyds:  %  Interbank  assets/  interbank  lending  

Nationwide  :  %  interbank  assets/  interbank  lending    

Co-­‐op  Interbank  assets  /  interbank  lending  

2006   -­‐   109.32      49.04   195.12  

2007   -­‐   87.64    42.58   182.07  

2008   -­‐   60.81    49.58   142.01  

2009    46.88   125.31    38.67   29.29  

2010    40.88   59.17    25.11   81.47  

2011    47.63   80.20    212.65   60.75  

2012    60.23   200.23    104.40   52.72  

2013    77.01   195.48    128.16   57.82  

2014   -­‐      205.99    

   

 Building  society-­‐specific  rules  encouraged  Nationwide’s  stable  funding  

and  lending  platforms.  Section  7  of  the  Building  Society  Act  1986  requires  the  funding  platform  of  a  building  society  to  be  composed  of  at  least  50%  of  funds  provided  by  individual  members.  In  turn  the  Nationwide  has  powerful  incentives  to  encourage  individual  deposits  from  its  members.  Non-­‐retail  sources,  particularly  borrowing  from  wholesale  markets,  cannot  form  more  than  50%  of  a  building  society’s  funding  therefore  (although  the  Treasury  does  have  a  power,  which  has  not  been  exercised,  to  increase  this  proportion  to  75%.). Nationwide  

Page 141: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  141  

has  thus  had  limited  scope  to  resort  to  wholesale  funding.  In  fact  wholesale  funding  has  constituted  considerably  less  than  the  50%  available  to  it    (see  table  7.4).  Of  the  wholesale  funding  which  Nationwide  has  raised,  much  has  been  raised  to  meet  capital  adequacy  requirements,  rather  than  funding  core  aspects  of  its  business,  and  a  significant  proportion  of  that  funding  has  been  longer  term,  maturing  in  over  one  year,  rather  than  being  short  term  roll-­‐over  borrowing.  In  each  of  the  last  three  years  shown,  unlike  the  Co-­‐op,  Barclays  and  Lloyds,  Nationwide  has  also  borrowed  less  than  it  has  lent  on  interbank  markets  (see  table  7.5).    

Nationwide  has  not  only  developed  a  lower  risk  funding  profile,  but  has  also  stuck  to  originating  more  traditional,  low-­‐risk,  lending.  The  majority  of  Nationwide’s  assets  are,  and  were  at  the  time  of  the  crisis,  comprised  of  loans  fully  secured  against  residential  properties.    Indeed,  at  least  75%  of  Nationwide's  business  assets  (but  not  its  total  assets)  have  to  be  comprised  of  mortgages  in  order  to  comply  with  the  Building  Society  Act  1986  (as  amended).  Section  6  of  the  Act  provides  that  at  least  75%  of  the  ‘business  assets’  must  be  loans  ‘fully  secured  against  residential  property’.  Nationwide’s  role  in  mortgage  lending  is  thus  much  higher,  proportionately,  than  any  of  its  other  larger  banking  peers  and  consequently  its  assets  are  of  a  good  quality.  Of  its  ‘total  assets’,  between  a  fifth  and  a  quarter  is  held  in  securities,  and  even  less  was  held  by  the  Co-­‐op  (see  tables  7.6  and  7.8  below).  Barclays,  by  comparison  has  almost  two-­‐thirds  tied  up  in  securities,  and  only  a  tenth  or  so  in  residential  mortgages  (see  Table  7.7).  Unlike  Northern  Rock  which  operated  an  ‘originate  to  distribute’  model,  Nationwide  did  not  engage  originating  high  volume  sub-­‐prime  lending  with  a  view  to  off-­‐loading  such  assets  in  more  profitable  sale  of  securities.    

Nationwide  has  had  a  securitisation  programme,  but  securitisation  necessarily  represented  only  a  small  part  of  its  business.  As  there  is  no  restriction  on  what  categories  of  asset  Nationwide  can  hold  in  the  remaining  25%  of  ‘business  assets’  Nationwide  could  have  engaged  in  securitisation  more  heavily,  but  it  appears  from  the  absence  of  such  activity  that  the  Nationwide  has  never  been  incentivised  to  engage  in  securitisation.  Unlike  most  of  its  peers,  therefore,  Nationwide  managed  to  stick  to  more  orthodox  lending  originating  quality  secured  lending  and  generally  only  used  its  securitisation  programme  to  sell  off  mortgages  in  order  to  free  up  capital  to  manage  funding,  and  liquidity  issues,  and  not  to  fund  key  parts  of  its  business.      Table 7.6: Nationwide: amount of assets comprised of mortgages and securities in % (2009-2014)

Nationwide’s  asset  base  :  comparing  the  composition  of  residential  mortgage  lending  and  securities    (Source:  Bankscope,  using  available  IFRS  accounts)        YEAR   Residential  

mortgage  Total  assets  (£)m    

%  asserts  comprised  strictly  of  residential  mortgages  

Total  securities  

%  comprised  in  securities  

2009   112959.0   201093.0   56%   48447.0   24%  

Page 142: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  142  

2010   109721.0   190497.0   58%   46743.0   25%  2011   104960.0   187699.0   56%   44982.0   23%  2012   104599.0   194988.0   53%   51995.0   27%  2013   109969.0   189318.0   58%   42884.0   23%  2014   119084.0   188889.0   63%   39607.0   21%       Table 7.7: Barclays: amount of assets comprised of mortgages and securities (2009-2013)

(Source:  Bankscope)  

YEAR   Residential  mortgage  

Total  assets  (£)m    

%  asserts  comprised  strictly  of  residential  mortgages  

Total  securities  

%  comprised  in  securities  

2009   110605.0   1399428.0   8%   752313.0   54%  2010   123995.0   1536290.0   8%   857138.0   56%  2011   133516.0   1602603.0   8%   908183.0   57%  2012   171272.0   1515163.0   11%   884014.0   58%  2013   149974.0   1345833.0   11%   763517.0   57%        Table 7.8: Co-op: amount of assets comprised of securities in £m and in % (2009-2013)

(Source  :  Bankscope)  

YEAR   Total  assets  (£m)  

 

Total  securities  (£m)  

%  comprised  in  securities  

2009   46138.8   8041.6   17%  

2010   45581.3   6055.2   13%  

2011   48955.6   5921.5   12%  

2012   49772.8   8072.4   16%  

2013   43396.1   5173.3   12%  

       

Page 143: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  143  

7.3.4     Reinforcing  functionalism      

Nationwide  thus  developed  a  less  risked  business  model,  and  it  did  so  whilst  also  having  to  pay  proportionately  higher  costs  than  its  larger  peers  via  the  government  deposit  holding  scheme,  and  without  having  the  same  access  to  equity  funding  as  its  peers.  Proportionately  Nationwide  has  to  pay  greater  amounts  to  the  Financial  Services  Compensation  Scheme  (FSCS)  than  other  banks  as  the  FSCS  levy  is  proportionate  to  the  amount  of  savings  held  by  a  bank  regardless  of  how  safe  the  bank’s  lending  practice  is.  Nationwide,  the  UK’s  second  largest  savings  provider,  has  had  to  pay  a  heavy  toll  therefore  notwithstanding  that  it  originated  higher  quality  mortgage  lending  than  a  lot  of  its  peers.  In  that  connection,  the  levy  had  the  effect  of  penalising  safer  lenders  and  encouraging  reckless  lenders  as  those  engaging  more  heavily  in  sub-­‐prime  origination,  such  as  the  Northern  Rock,  holding  less  in  savings,  were  not  required  to  pay  as  much  as  the  Nationwide  (Weardon,  2009).  

In  addition,  as  a  mutual,  Nationwide  has  been  limited  in  the  way  it  can  raise  equity  to  provide  it  with  capital.  Section  8  of  the  Building  Society  Act  1986  prohibits  a  building  society  from accepting  corporate  bodies  as  shareholders;  and  funds  raised  from  individuals  must  be  in  the  form  of  shares  or  current  accounts.  In  order  to  meet  rising  capital  adequacy  standards,  Nationwide  issued  £500m  of  core  capital  deferred  shares  (CCDS)  in  November  2013.    Such  shares  rank  behind  all  other  forms  of  subordinated  debt,  and  are  thus  last  in  line  to  recover  in  the  event  of  insolvency.  They  also  have  weaker  control  rights  than  regular  equity.  Regardless  of  how  many  shares  are  owned,  an  investor  holding  CCDSs  will  be  a  single  member  of  the  organisation  only  entitled  to  cast  one  vote.  Whilst  the  shares  were  valued  as  producing  a  10.5%  yield,  their  maximum  yield  is  also  capped  at  15%.  According  to  Nationwide’s  treasury  division  director  Andy  Townsend,  the  shares  were  purposefully  designed  to  make  it  clear  to  shareholders  that  they  should  not  expect  unlimited  upside:  ‘The  purpose  of  the  cap  was  to  make  it  clear  that  the  introduction  of  this  new  class  of  security  was  not  a  suggestion  to  holders  to  influence  Nationwide  to  move  to  a  profit  maximising  model’  (Caiger-­‐Smith  2013).    

Given  the  more  demanding  capital  adequacy  standards,  future  share  issues  may  prove  to  be  popular.  Nationwide  will  not  only  have  to  pay  a  heavy  toll  to  the  FSCS  proportionate  to  its  savings,  but  may  also  have  to  de-­‐leverage  to  increase  its  capital.  Since  savings  constitute  liabilities,  not  assets,  and  its  main  line  of  business  –  mortgage  lending  –  does  not  free  up  adequate  capital  to  de-­‐leverage,  the  issue  of  CCDS  and  other  subordinated  debt  may  become  necessary.  The  2013  CCDS  issue  certainly  helped  boost  Nationwide’s  leverage  ratio,  increasing  its  available  capital  as  a  percentage  of  its  assets.  With  weightless  voting  rights  and  capped  dividends,  and  only  limited  scope  for  trading  such  shares  (Nationwide  not  being  listed  on  the  stock-­‐market)  such  shares  are  unlikely  to  subject  management  to  the  types  of  ownership  pressures  exerted  on  publicly  traded  banks.  Nationwide  has  also  confirmed  that  it  has  no  intention  of  being  a  regular  issuer.  For  the  time  being    therefore,  CCDS  are  more  akin  to  bonds  than  regular  equity  and  are  unlikely  to  jeopardise  Nationwide’s  mutual  status.  Whilst  Nationwide  has  been  forced  to  deleverage,  it  did  not  realise  a  deficit  on  the  same  scale  as  the  Co-­‐op,  nor  did  it  require  government  bail  out  like  

Page 144: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  144  

Lloyds  or  help  from  middle  eastern  investors  like  Barclays.    What  is  also  impressive  about  the  Nationwide  is  that  it  has  managed  to  

develop  a  safe  business  model  whilst  also  retaining  only  a  very  modest  interest  in  its  assets.  Like  many  other  banks,  its  equity,  was  extremely  small  compared  to  other  assets,  typically  no  more  than  5%,  but  unlike  other  banks  those  who  held  such  equity  were  not  treated  like  owners,  and  were  not  entitled  to  have  the  Nationwide  run  just  for  their  benefit.    A  less  risky  strategy  was  encouraged  in  the  Nationwide  therefore,  whose  ownership  model  limited  ownership  pressures  and  whose  external  regulation  required  it  to  stick  to  more  conservative  lines  of  retail  banking.    

7.4     Conclusions       What  emerges  from  looking  at  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op  is  the  lesson  that  an  ownerless  bank  can  be  driven  to  behave  in  similar  ways  to  banks  whose  ownership  is  publicly-­‐traded,  to  seek  radical  growth  in  unsafe  ways  and  to  foster  a  culture  focused  on  short  term  performance  where  misbehaviour  is  tolerated.  The  Co-­‐op’s  desire  for  growth  came  about  not  from  ownership  pressures  nor  from  management  avarice,  but  rather  from  competitive  pressures  exerted  on  it  as  well  as  smaller  banks  by  the  structure  and  dynamics  of  the  banking  market.  Unlike  Lloyds,  where  the  driver  of  failure  was  hard-­‐wired  into  its  ownership  design,  the  Co-­‐op  was  locked  into  its  own  perilous  path  by  its  need  to  gain  market  access  through  extending  its  branch  network.      Whilst  its  management  proved  to  be  utterly  incompetent  and  its  governance  structure  ineffectual  at  keeping  its  greed  in  check,  the  Co-­‐op  was  not  alone  in  being  over-­‐optimistic,  and  complacent  if  not  outright  blind  to  a  collapsing  conjuncture  :    the  major  political  parties,  the  regulators  and  even  the  public  seemed  to  have  bought  into  the  Co-­‐op’s  claim  that  a  new  era  of  ethical  banking  was  dawning.  The  story  of  the  Co-­‐op  suggests  that  re-­‐designing  an  ownership  model  to  remove  ownership  pressures  is  unlikely  in  itself  to  guarantee  stability  and  success,  and  that  account  needs  to  be  had  to  the  structure  and  market  environment  within  which  banks  operate  and  the  pressures  arising  from  operating  in  such  space.      

By  contrast,  what  we  witness  in  the  case  of  the  Nationwide,  is  that  the  problems  of  greed  and  hubris  are  less  present.  The  ownership  pressures  which  governed  Barclays  and  Lloyds  were  not  present  and  the  structural  pressures  which  governed  the  Co-­‐op  were  not  material,  mainly  because  the  rules  designed  to  regulate  Building  Societies  ensured  the  Nationwide  stuck  to  performing  orthodox  retail  banking  functions.  The  freedom  and  temptation  to  deviate  from  these  functions,  made  possible  for  most  banks  by  the  Big  Bang    was  not  an  option  for  the  Nationwide  which  remained  a  building  society,  and  remained  subject  as  such  to  regulation  requiring  it  to  perform  certain  functions.  Such  functional  regulation  kept  the  Nationwide  in  its  compartment  of  activity  and  acted  as  a  countervailing  force  against  the  structural  pressures  which  might  otherwise  have  pushed  it  into  riskier  behaviours.  The  case  of  the  Nationwide  suggests  that  ownership  and  structural  pressures  can  be  moderated  and  accommodated,  by  ownership  models  which  limit  the  extractive  demands  placed  on  management,  and  by  regulation  which  prevents  banks  from  departing  from  their  regulated  

Page 145: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  145  

retail  functions  and  engaging  in  more  riskier  behaviours.    The  following  chapter  will  consider  how  this  might  be  done.                

Page 146: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  146  

Chapter  8. Conclusion:  ‘ownerlessness’  must  be  part  of  

the  solution      

8.1   Introduction    

This  chapter  analyses  the  key  findings  of  the  preceding  empirical  chapters  and  discusses  their  relevance  and  implications.  It  is  organised  into  four  parts.  The  first  identifies  the  key  findings  and,  in  succession,  argues  first  that  these  findings  suggest  that  the  current  ownership  model  is  not  fit-­‐for-­‐purpose  and  must  be  reformed;  second  that  an  ownership  ‘fix’  is  unlikely  to  solve  all  of  the  problems  in  banking;  and  third  that  there  also  needs  to  be  greater  compartmentalisation  of  banking  functions  and  function-­‐specific  regulation  of  activities  within  those  compartments.  The  cases  of  Barclays  and  Lloyds  both  suggested  that  the  shareholder-­‐value  ownership  model  is  liable  to  demand  too  much  from  the  banking  business,  driving  mis-­‐behaviour  and  unsafe  strategies  and  encouraging  banks  to  depart  from  traditional  low  profit,  and  what  many  would  consider  to  be  more  socially  desirable,  behaviours.    

On  the  other  hand,  we  witnessed  in  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op  that  an  absence  of  any  shareholder-­‐value  ownership  does  not,  by  itself,  protect  against  other  structural  pressures  which  can  also  drive  bad  behaviour  and  strategy  and  what  was  suggested  by  the  case  of  the  Nationwide,  was  that  banks  are  less  likely  to  misbehave  where  their  functions  are  clearly  compartmentalized  and  their  regulation  aimed  at  enforcing  functionalism  within  those  discrete  compartments.  Indeed,  the  Nationwide  provided  something  of  a  back-­‐to-­‐the-­‐future  story  demonstrating  that  the  most  responsible  and  resilient  business  model  was  that  which  was  changed  the  least  in  the  Big  Bang.  Having  not  demutualised  and  floated  on  the  stock  market,  the  Nationwide  remained  subject  to  building  society  regulation  whose  focus  on  the  Nationwide’s  different  compartmentalized  and  clearly  defined  activities,  reinforced  sensible  behaviours  and  provided  safe-­‐guards  against  the  kind  of  misbehaviours  which  saw  other  banks  becoming  un-­‐stuck.    

Having  explored  the  key  findings  in  the  first  part  of  the  chapter,  the  second  part  then  discusses  the  relevance  of  these  findings  to  the  thesis  inquiry,  comparing  the  direction  of  the  official  ‘reform  agenda’  with  the  implications  from  the  thesis  findings.  This  part  criticises  the  absence  of  any  discussion  in  the  official  response  about  the  need  for  ownership  reform.  At  the  same  time,  we  note  that  the  status  quo  ante  is  not  set  in  stone  and  a  new  political  debate  appears  to  be  opening  up  as  politicians  and  intellectuals  from  diverse  walks  of  life  advocate  new  forms  of  banking  which  play  more  of  a  role  in  creating  productive  investment.  This  part  of  the  thesis  recognises  that  there  are  a  host  of  different  reforms  required  in  banking  which  are  un-­‐related  to  the  issue  of  ownership,  and  which  call  to  be  considered  outside  of  this  thesis.    

Page 147: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  147  

Rather  than  indulging  in  any  detailed  discussion  of  those  issues  therefore,  the  third  part  of  the  chapter  instead  focuses  on  how  we  should  now  think  about  the  way  banks  are  owned  and  how  we  might  seek  to  re-­‐design  their  ownership  model.  This  part  makes  proposals  bearing  in  mind  both  the  apparent  absence  of  political  will  to  consider  the  issue  of  ownership  in  post-­‐crisis  reform,  as  well  as  emerging  political  calls  for  greater  productive  investment.  The  argument  which  evolves  out  of  this  part  is  that  unless  we  challenge  and  displace  the  prevalent  assumption  that  banks  should  be  run  as  if  owned  by  shareholders,  we  are  unlikely  to  ensure  that  banks  behave  responsibly  and  perform  what  can  be  considered  to  be  more  socially  desirable  behaviours.  It  is  argued  in  this  part  that  we  need  to  be  far  more  courageous  not  only  in  clarifying  what  we  expect  of  our  banks  but  also  in  being  experimental  in  designing  new  forms  of  ownership  which  seek  to  remove  or  mitigate  ownership  pressures.  Different  ways  of  experimenting  with  ownerlessness  are  then  explored  including  preparing  plans  for  converting  banks  which  are  nationalised  or  bailed  out  in  the  future  and  creating  any  National  Investment  Bank,  such  as  that  currently  proposed  by  the  Labour  Party  (2017)  with  an  ownerless  model  to  ensure  that  it  can  effectively  dedicate  its  assets  to  perform  productive  investment.      

It  is  argued  that  if  we  want  to  seriously  pursue  greater  productive  investment  in  the  wider  economy  by  instituting  some  form  of  National  Investment  Bank,  how  such  a  bank  is  owned  is  important,  if  it  is  to  avoid  the  fate  of  3i  (Mayer,  2013,  pp132-­‐135),  or  the  Green  Investment  Bank  (Kollewe,  2017).  The  fourth  and  final  part  then  considered  the  findings  and  implications  in  the  light  of  the  motivations  which  initially  prompted  this  thesis,  evaluating  what  practical  and  academic  contributions  are  made  by  this  thesis  inquiry  in  connection  with  the  subjects  of  banking  reform  and  ownership  more  generally.          

8.2   Part  1:   The  key  findings    

8.2.1     Extractive  ownership  is  not  fit-­‐for-­‐purpose    The  evidence  uncovered  by  chapter  6  strongly  suggested  that  the  

demands  placed  on  management  by  the  stock  market,  shareholders  and  investors  in  the  cases  of  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  played  a  significant  role  in  influencing  and  shaping  strategy  and  behaviour.  Both  Bob  Diamond  and  Brian  Pitman  vowed  to  return  shareholder  value  to  investors,  and  with  their  reputations  and  compensation  packages  being  affected  by  their  ability  to  do  that,  they  both  had  vested  interests  in  succumbing  to  pressures  to  deliver  double  digit  returns  and  grow  their  banks’  profits.  Barclays,  formerly  reputed  for  being  a  conservative  retail  bank  of  a  respectable  Quaker  lineage,  essentially  doubled  down  on  its  investment  banking  operations,  raising  questionable  funding  in  doing  so.  Following  Bob  Diamond’s  2003  Alpha  Plan  there  was  a  pronounced,  one  way  trend,  to  ramp  up  its  IB  and  international  operations,  and  to  depart  from  its  lower  yielding  domestic  retail  functions  –  a  trend  which  became  apparently  irreversible  following  the  Lehman  Brother’s  acquisition  in  2009.  Whilst  profitable  during  the  economic  upswing,  when  liquidity  dried  up,  these  IB  

Page 148: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  148  

operations  proved  costly  and  difficult  to  sustain  and  resulted  in  a  significant  capital  shortfall  which  was  only  plugged  by  raising  colossal  amounts  of  equity  from  private  investors  in  the  middle  east  in  hurried  and  highly  questionable  fashion.      

As  for  Lloyds,  which  was  also  previously  considered  to  be  a  safe  and  reliable  retail  business,  it  was  taken  into  riskier  and  riskier  deal-­‐making  as  the  stock-­‐market  and  its  cheerleaders  called  upon  Brian  Pitman  and  his  successors  to  deliver  not  only  returns  on  equity,  but  also  radical  growth.  Pitman’s  aversion  to  investment  banking  meant  that  Lloyds  could  only  satisfy  these  demands  through  making  ever  bigger  and  riskier  acquisitions.  Having  tried  unsuccessfully  to  acquire  RBS  in  1984,  Standard  Chartered  in  1986,  and  the  Midland  Bank  in  1992,  Pitman  took  advantage  of  the  de-­‐mutualisations  in  the  1990s  and  made  a  spree  of  sizeable  acquisitions,  and  in  particular,  the  Cheltenham  &  Gloucester  in  1995,  and  the  TSB  in  1995.  These  additions,  together  with  other  acquisitions  which  were  considered  to  be  complimentary  for  banking  such  as  the  Scottish  Widows  in  1999,  consolidated  Lloyds’  position  as  a  dominant  bank  in  the  UK  retail  sector.  Whilst  this  M&A  trebled  Lloyds’  assets  in  the  1990s,  it  left  few  options  for  further  growth  in  the  millennium.  This  made  the  eventual  HBOS  acquisition  increasingly  inevitable,  and  also  put  strain  on  management  to  ramp  up  Lloyds’  retail  assets  through  in-­‐branch  sales.        

In  slightly  different  ways  therefore  the  cases  of  both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  provided  examples  of  shareholder-­‐value  driven  ownership  models  demanding  more  from  the  banking  business  than  could  be  safely  delivered,  and  not  only  during  times  of  economic  growth  and  high  liquidity,  but  also  during  recession.  The  efforts  of  Bob  Diamond’s  successor  to  ‘fix’  the  culture  in  Barclays  were  singularly  incapable  of  resisting  shareholder  demands  to  return  to  ‘business  as  usual’,  as  was  demonstrated  by  the  way  ‘Saint  Anthony’  was  quickly  derided  and  mocked,  and  subsequently  ousted  to  be  replaced  by  another  maverick  investment  banker.    Whilst  successive    CEO’s  of  Lloyds  publicly  resisted  calls  for  Lloyds  to  ramp  up  its  own  IB,  senior  management  within  Lloyds  came  under  immense  pressure  to  achieve  high  earnings  and  growth  in  other  ways.  As  well  as  engaging  in  dubious  retail  mis-­‐selling  on  an  industrial  scale,  it  proceeded  with  its  risky  growth  strategy  which  at  times  saw  Lloyds  even  contemplating  taking  over  the  Northern  Rock  and  ABN  Ambro  –  acquisitions  which  would  have  proved  disastrous  (Fallon,  2015  p112).  

Barclays  and  Lloyds  not  only  adopted  dangerous  strategies  but,  as  was  also  observed  in  chapter  6,  they  also  cultivated  cultures  which  celebrated  greed  and  recklessness  and  encouraged  the  pursuit  of  profits  at  the  expense  of  their  customers.  As  the  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  discovered  (2013b,  paras116,  119,  416,  519,  536,  597,  836-­‐838),  the  win-­‐at-­‐any-­‐cost  mentality  typical  of  investment  banking  spilled  over  into  other  departments  within  UK  big  banks  and  these  other  departments  came  under  pressure  to  take  advantage  of  their  customers,  in  some  instances  gulling,  swindling  and  cheating  them  in  doing  so.    Both  Barclays  and  Lloyds  manipulated  markets  and  mis-­‐sold  products  to  the  very  people  they  were  supposed  to  serve,  selling  an  array  of  over-­‐priced  financial  products  to  customers  who  generally  had  no  real  need  for  them.      

It  is  furthermore  telling  that  Lloyds  and  Barclays  were  not  the  worst  offenders  and  were  not  even  extreme  examples  of  banks  with  shareholder-­‐value  

Page 149: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  149  

ownership  models  developing  bad  behaviour  and  strategies.  Quite  the  contrary  Barclays  and  Lloyds  appear  to  be  rather  representative.  They  provide  two  variants  on  the  same  story  which  seems  to  have  been  told  by  the  rest  of  the  UK’s  big  banks,  whose  ownership  models  have  demanded  more  growth  and  earnings  from  the  banking  business  than  could  safely  be  delivered.  Northern  Rock,  the  RBS  and  even  HSBC  provide  other  examples  of  banks  which  went  awry  in  their  own  way.  Northern  Rock  built  up  a  business  model  dependent  upon  the  sale  of  sub-­‐prime  derivatives  which  was  no  longer  sustainable  when  demand  for  their  product  and  inter-­‐bank  lending  dried  up.  RBS  engaged  recklessly  in  M&A  and  IB  encountering  problems  similar  to  those  of  Lloyds  and  Barclays.  And  even  HSBC  engaged  in  money-­‐laundering  operations  apparently  on  an  industrial  scale  across  multiple  jurisdictions.    

Whilst  these  banks  call  for  their  own  studies  of  misbehaviour,  the  findings  of  this  thesis  would  tend  to  suggest  that  they  all  probably  developed  their  own  peculiar  problems  for  the  same  reason  :  their  ownership  model  demanded  double  digit  returns  and  asset  growth  on  a  scale  which  could  not  safely  be  delivered,  at  least  not  by  operating  solely  within  the  retail  compartment  of  banking,  or  without  taking  on  extraordinary  risks.    

8.2.2   Changing  ownership  is  not  enough    

The  case  of  the  Co-­‐op  proved  that  ownership  pressures  were  not  the  only  forces  driving  management  to  take  on  excessive  risks.  What  was  suggested  by  that  case  is  that  even  if  ownership  pressures  could  be  removed  entirely,  the  other  types  of  structural  pressures  considered  in  chapter  4  can  still  drive  bad  strategy  and  mis-­‐behaviour.  As  we  witnessed  in  chapter  4,  the  high  operating  costs  in  retail  banking,  together  with  fierce  product  competition  for  example  to  deliver  free-­‐whilst-­‐in-­‐credit  banking  services,  provides  powerful  incentives  for  retail  banks,  especially  smaller  banks,  to  act  mimetically  :  to  adopt  the  same  business    model  as  their  PLC  competitors.  All  banks  were  encouraged,  to  become  more  ‘universal’  in  their  offering,  to  engage  in  the  same  lines  of  business,  to  use  their  branches  as  sales  points  to  recover  costs,  and  thus  to  view  customers  as  sales  opportunities  and  profit  sources  in  their  own  right.  Because  market  share  still  correlates  closely  with  the  size  of  a  bank’s  branch  network,  success  in  retail  banking  inevitably  depends  upon  banks  having  lots  of  branches.  These  dynamics  can  provide  powerful  incentives  for  smaller  banks,  like  the  Co-­‐op,  to  grow  larger  branch  networks,  regardless  of  the  bank’s  ownership  model.      

In  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op  we  saw  a  tragedy  if  not  an  outright  horror  story  being  played  out.  A  self-­‐styled  ethical  bank,  free  from  the  types  of  ownership  pressures  exerted  on  Lloyds,  found  itself  behaving  in  essentially  similar  ways,  and  then  suffering  from  the  consequences  of  such  recklessness.    Any  argument  that  the  Co-­‐op’s  stakeholder-­‐ownership  removed  incentives  for  misbehaviour  were  seriously  undermined  in  2012  when  £14.5  billion  worth  of  bad  debts  opened  up  on  the  Co-­‐op’s  balance  sheet,  stemming  mainly  from  its  Britannia  acquisition.    The  Co-­‐op’s  accountants  and  auditors  and  the  regulators  who  approved  the  Britannia  deal  failed  to  spot  the  risks  with  the  Britannia  deal,  but  ultimate  responsibility  for  that  oversight  lay  with  the  Co-­‐op’s  board.  Its  governance  structure  permitted  decisions  to  be  taken  essentially  by  prominent  

Page 150: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  150  

figures  within  the  Co-­‐op’s  parent  group,  who  were  ‘placemen’  and  unqualified  to  manage  a  bank  (paragraph  203,  TC  Project  Verde  2015).  The  Co-­‐op’s  management  failed  to  spot  the  bad  commercial  loans  on  the  Britannia’s  loan  book  during  the  due  diligence  which  was  undertaken  prior  to  acquiring  the  Britannia.  That  failure  was  compounded  by  the  Co-­‐op’s  unrealistic  ambitions  in  putting  itself  in  the  running  subsequently  for  Project  Verde  and  the  acquisition  of  the  632  branches  being  divested  from  Lloyds.    

All  this  suggests  a  failure  in  the  Co-­‐op’s  governance  system,  which  was  inadequate  to  restrain  the  Co-­‐op’s  recklessly  acquisitive  ambitions.  But  the  Co-­‐op’s  greed  for  growth  came  about  from  its  strategic  imperatives  which  were  set  not  by  management  but  by  the  marketplace  within  which  it  found  itself.  Having  eschewed  risky  and  unethical  business,  and  having  opted  to  operate  a  bancassurance  type-­‐model  mainly  within  the  retail  department,  the  Co-­‐op  had  little  choice  but  to  seek  to  radically  grow  its  branch  network  if  it  was  to  succeed  in  UK  banking.  Its  best,  if  not  only,  opportunity  for  doing  that  was  to  take  over  the  Britannia,  and  to  try  to  put  itself  in  the  running  for  the  632  Lloyds  branches  being  sold  off  in  Project  Verde.  If  the  Co-­‐op  had  not  ventured  for  such  radical  growth,  its  prospects  otherwise  of  succeeding  in  retail  banking,  and  establishing  itself  in  what  is  a  costly  and  competitive  market  would  have  been  very  poor,  especially  since  it  had  confined  itself  to  ethical  banking.  

 Although  the  Co-­‐op’s  peculiar  governance  system  was  found  wanting,  so  too  was  the  governance  system  of  all  PLC  banks  which,  as  we  saw  in  chapter  2,  was  accused  of  being  ineffectual  and  incapable  of  reigning  in  recklessness  and  greed.  In  other  words,  the  Co-­‐op’s  governance  system  was  different,  but  it  was    not  alone  in  failing:  the  governance  system  of  all  ‘owned  models’  had  also  failed,  thus  suggesting  governance  problems  in  both  shareholder  and  stakeholder  models.  And  as  chapter  7  also  demonstrated,  non-­‐profit  ownership  models  could  succeed  as  in  the  case  of  the  Nationwide’s  governance  system  which  was  not  called  into  question.        

8.2.3   The  need  for  compartmentalisation  and  functional  regulation    

The  Nationwide  provides  something  of  a  success  story.  Unlike  the  Co-­‐op,  or  Lloyds  or  Barclays,  it  managed  to  steer  itself  on  a  far  safer  course  essentially  by  remaining  within  the  compartmental  limits    of  its  traditional  banking  activity.  The  irony  of  the  Nationwide’s  success  is  twofold.  First  it  had  the  business  model  which  changed  least  in  the  Big  Bang,  and  second  it  managed  to  deliver  better  banking  services  than  most  of  its  peers  and  in  a  more  sustainable  and  cautious  manner  without  actually  becoming  a  bank,  all  the  while  remaining  a  building  society.  Indeed  the  Nationwide  provided  a  back-­‐to-­‐the-­‐future  story  about  the  most  resilient  and  successful  bank  being  the  one  which  was  least  primed  for  change  in  the  Big  Bang.    Although  it  was  only  a  building  society  it  was  able  to  undertake  the  more  traditional  functions  typically  associated  with  fractional  reserve  banking,  namely  taking  deposits  and  lending  to  businesses  and  households  in  less  risky  ways  than  its  peers.  It  did  not  try  to  become  a  go-­‐go  bank,  demutualising  and  embarking  on  the  ‘originate  to  distribute’  business  model  of  some  of  its  peers.  It  pushed  instead  only  for  modest  growth  by  acquiring  other  building  societies  in  a  piecemeal,  organic  manner.    And  unlike  

Page 151: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  151  

Barclays  and  Lloyds  and  indeed  the  many  other  demutualised  building  societies,  the  Nationwide  did  not  seek  to  leverage  in  dangerous  ways,  nor  did  it  cultivate  the  results-­‐orientated  and  greedy  culture  we  saw  developing  in  Barclays  and  Lloyds.  The  Nationwide  instead  stuck  to  more  traditional  banking  services  all  the  while  delivering  respectable  albeit  more  modest  returns  on  equity  of  around  5-­‐10%.    

In  the  case  of  the  Nationwide,  the  absence  of  an  extractive  ownership  model  was  combined  successfully  with  other  internal  and  external  governance  factors  which  mitigated  the  effects  of  other  structural  pressures.  Like  the  Co-­‐op  the  Nationwide  was  subject  to  structural  pressures  to  grow,  but  being  more  than  ten  times  as  large  as  the  Co-­‐op  (before  2009),  its  growth  imperative  was  not  nearly  as  pronounced  as  for  the  Co-­‐op.  Nationwide  was  five  times  as  big  as  the  Co-­‐op  (even  after  the  Britannia  merger),  and  was  nearly  half  the  size  of  Lloyds  (prior  to  the  HBOS  acquisition).  Having  gradually  acquired  almost  two  hundred  building  societies  over  its  two  hundred  year  history,  the  Nationwide  already  had  an  extensive  branch  network  reaching  across  the  country.  Being  a  regulated  building  society,  its  capacity  for  financing  any  radical  acquisition  was  also  significantly  more  limited  than  the  Co-­‐op  bank.  Although  it  was  not  precluded  from  making  acquisitions,  a  combination  of  prudent  management,  and  functional  regulation  restrained  how  much  it  could  borrow,  thus  limiting  the  scale  on  which  it  could  pursue  growth.  The  Nationwide  did  engage  in  the  same  product  markets  as  its  peers,  and  in  particular  (mis)selling  PPI.  The  extent  of  Nationwide’s  mis-­‐selling  however  was  miniscule  by  comparison  to  other  PLC  banks,  especially  Lloyds.    

Whereas  other  banks  were  criticised  for  exploiting  their  customers  for  their  own  advantage,  following  the  crisis  the  Nationwide  won  accolades  for  serving  its  customers’  needs  through  delivering  award-­‐winning  services,  and  creating  innovative  competitive  retail  products.  Its  devotion  to  its  depositor-­‐members  was  positively  reinforced  by  the  rules  regulating  building  societies  which  limit  the  amount  of  wholesale  funding  building  societies  can  raise  (up  to  50%)  and  insist  upon  lending  being  originated  from  more  traditional,  low-­‐risk  activities  (at  least  75%  mortgages).    Whilst  the  various  banking  acts  passed  in  the  big  bang  caused  banks  to  become  risky  self-­‐interested  extraction  machines,  the  building  society  rules  kept  building  societies  within  their  compartments  of  activity,  encouraging  them  to  become  archetypal  fractional  reserve  intermediaries  allocating  loan  resources  by    traditional  retail  banking  criteria.  The  Nationwide  was  kept  within  its  compartment  of  regulated  activities  by  functional  regulation.    The  Nationwide’s  sustainability  story  thus  reflects  the  way  its  stakeholder  model  insulated  it  from  ownership  pressures  and  also  how  a  series  of  other  conditions  protected  it  from  structural  pressures.      

8.3   Part  2:  relevance  and  implications      

8.3.1   Implications  for  reform      The  key  findings  from  the  empirical  research  performed  in  chapters  6  and  

7  suggest  both  that  the  prevalent  ownership  model  is  liable  to  demand  more  

Page 152: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  152  

than  can  be  safely  delivered  by  the  banking  business  and  that  it  makes  little  sense  for  banks  to  be  exposed  to  such  demands,  especially  given  that  banks  are  expected  to  perform  a  lot  of  what  are  essentially  low  yielding  activities.  Shareholder-­‐value  ownership  provides  pressures  for  banks  to  act  in  self-­‐interested,  exploitative  and  risky  ways.  It  is  not  well  suited  for  businesses  whose  primary  function  is  to  manage  other  people’s  money,  especially  if  we  expect  such  money  to  be  allocated  in  certain  ways  for  example  to  meet  the  needs  of  businesses  and  the  broader  economy.    

The  inevitable  implications  arising  from  this  are  that  our  law-­‐makers  and  regulators  need  to  be  far  more  interventionist  in  three  respects:  first  in  determining  what  role  we  expect  banks  to  perform;  second  by  being  more  experimental  in  designing  how  banks  are  owned  to  help  them  perform  such  role;  and  third  by  being  keener  to  regulate  them  in  ways  which  also  aim  to  help  them  perform  such  role.    Without  changing  the  underlying  ownership  structure  of  the  PLC,  and  without  clarifying  what  we  want  from  banks,  the  relentless  expectations  of  investors  are  likely  to  drive  banks  to  further  mis-­‐behave,  to  take  bad  decisions  and  to  apply  investment  in  ways  which  do  not  necessarily  benefit  society.  If  banks  continue  to  be  owned  in  ways  which  provide  incentives  for  them  to  be  self-­‐interested,  exploitative,  and  reckless  with  other  people’s  money,  the  overwhelming  likelihood  is  that  there  will  always  be  a  pervasive  culture  of  greed  and  irresponsibility  in  them,  and  regulators  will  pursue  an  impossible  task  in  seeking  to  make  them  behave  more  responsibly.      

The  demands  of  shareholder-­‐value,  combined  with  the  structural  pressures  considered  in  chapter  4,  are  also  liable  to  encourage  banks  to  engage  in  activities  which  are  harmful  or  of  little  benefit  to  society  or  which  deviate  wildly  from  the  more  socially  useful  functions  we  might  want  them  to  perform  (Brummer,  2015,  p144;  Turner,  2016,  pp61-­‐63,  173-­‐174,  245-­‐246).    If  we  want  banks  to  originate  lending  which  benefits  society  and  is  not  useless  or  harmful  to  society,  it  seems  that  we  really  need  to  go  further  in  defining  what  economic  activities  we  expect  banks  to  finance  more  generously  or  not  to  finance  and  we  need  to  keep  banks,  or  parts  of  them,  within  the  compartments  of  prescribed  activities  which  we  require  them  to  perform  and  then  to  regulate  them  to  stay  within  those  compartments.    

8.3.2   Inadequacy  of  current  reforms    The  UK’s  post-­‐2008  financial  crisis  reform  agenda  has  not  gone  nearly  far  

enough  in  articulating  what  we  want  from  banking  or  in  ensuring  ownership  and  structural  pressures  are  tackled  and  managed  to  help  banks  meet  these  needs.  As  we  saw  in  chapter  2,  the  Government’s  reform  package  consisted  mainly  of  requiring  banks  to  hold  slightly  more  capital  and  to  ring-­‐fence  only  the  most  publicly-­‐sensitive  parts  of  their  business  to  protect  the  same  in  the  event  of  bank  failure.  It  was  a  feeble  attempt  at  compartmentalisation,  which  was  less  radical  than  reforms  in  other  countries.  Notably,  in  the  USA,  the  Dodds-­‐Frank  act  sought  to  end  the  too  big  to  fail  subsidy  to  protect  American  tax-­‐payers  and  prevent  any  future  bail  outs,  and  it  did  so  by  instituting  a  radical  overhaul  of  the  regulatory  regime  providing  extensive  powers  for  new  regulators  to  break  up  banks  if  needs  be,  but  critically  to  prescribe  how  activities  were  to  be  performed.  

Page 153: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  153  

Although  banks  were  not  broken  up,  the  new  regulatory  regime  imposed  limits  on  the  activities  banks  could  engage  in  and  required  regulators  more  carefully  to  monitor  and  control  how  they  performed  such  activities  (Paletta,  2010).  

In  the  UK,  the  ‘official  response’  did  not  engage  in  the  sort  of  philosophical  inquiry  one  might  have  expected  about  what  we  require  from  banks  as  the  quid  pro  quo  for  bailing  out  the  banks  and  for  giving  them  a  licence  to  create  credit  in  the  first  place.  We  did  not  grapple  with  the  ‘ownership’  issues  explored  in  chapter  3,  nor  did  we  seek  to  revisit  and  rebalance  the  relationship  struck  between  the  state,  market  and  financial  sector  in  the  Big  Bang,  which  was  discussed  in  chapter  4.    Instead,  the  official  response  sought  to  preserve  finance  as  a  sort  of  national  protected  treasure.  As  we  saw  in  chapter  2,  this  ‘halo’  which  has  been  constructed  around  the  City  of  London  has  made  it  extremely  difficult  for  politicians  to  resist  the  demands  of  the  finance  industry  or  to  be  radically  interventionist.    

8.3.3   Scope  for  determining  what  we  want  from  banks    

As  was  observed  at  4.2.2  banks  create  and  allocate  colossal  amounts  of  credit,  and  they  are  hugely  privileged  in  being  licenced  to  do  so.  Having  bestowed  that  privilege  upon  them,  the  state  has  something  of  a  right,  if  not  also  a  vested  interest,  in  having  more  of  a  say  in  determining  what  activities  are  financed,  or  need  to  be  financed  more  generously.      Although  the  Government’s  reform  agenda  did  not  break  ground  in  radically  defining  what  we  want  from  the  banking  sector,  it  seems  that  there  is  increasing  political  willingness  to  revisit  the  settlement  struck  between  state  and  the  financial  sector  in  the  Big  Bang.    

As  we  observed  in  chapter  4,  it  has  certainly  become  common  for  a  range  of  intellectuals,  academics  and  policy-­‐makers  to  argue  that  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  should  not  be  left  to  unbridled  market  forces  (see  CRESC,  2009,  pp40,  44;  King  2016;  Turner  2016,  pp61-­‐63,  174;  Kay  2015,  p248).    It  is  commonly  claimed  that  rather  than  allocating  credit  to  the  type  of  productive  investment  society  needs  to  repay  its  debts  and  to  grow  sustainably,  banks  instead  tend  to  finance  unproductive  activities,  particularly  property  which  fuel  dangerously  unstable  economic  cycles  and  pose  a  burden  to  society  (CRESC,  2009,  pp40,  44;  Turner,  2016,  ch.10).  

As  a  result  many  now  argue  that  banks  should  be  limited  in  how  they  create  and  allocate  credit.  Many  argue  that  the  state  needs  to  limit  fractional  reserve  banking  by  requiring  radical  more  reserves  or  by  having  more  of  a  role  in  determining  where  credit  is  to  be  allocated.  Wolf  (2014b,  2014c)  suggests  fractional  reserve  banking  should  be  abolished  altogether.  Others  advocate  that  we  need  more  credit  allocated  into  wealth  generating  capital  investments  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  real  economy.  For  example,  Kay,  and  also  Turner,  argue  that  as  well  as  requiring  banks  to  operate  the  payment  system  and  allocative  channel,  what  we  really  need  them  to  do  is  to  allocate  credit  to  finance  useful  investments  to  generate  the  additional  wealth  needed  to  sustain  and  repay  society’s  debts  (Kay,  2014,  p299;  Turner,  2016,  pp61-­‐63).  They  were  not  alone  in  calling  for  greater  productive  investment  from  banks.  Whereas  previously  calls  for  the  state  to  control  or  influence  the  direction  of  investment  capital  seemed  anathema,  the  pendulum  appears  to  be  swinging  the  other  way.    

Page 154: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  154  

Before  the  crisis,  there  was  a  widely  held  and  firm  belief  amongst  many  popular  commentators  that  unrestrained  free  market  capitalism  had  irrevocably  worked  its  way  into  every  aspect  of  life  (Perry,  2000;  Klein,  2007;  Pickett  et  al,  2009,  Tisher,  2009;  Mount,  2010).  The  political-­‐economic  consensus  appeared  to  be  intolerant  of  critics  of  free-­‐market  ideology  and  there  was  little  place  for  those  who  advocated  for  greater  state  intervention  in  directing  the  creation  and  allocation  of  credit.  After  the  crisis,  however,  there  has  been  something  of  a  political  shift  against  neoliberalism  and  growing  disenchantment  with  the  economic  status  quo  has  been  widely  expressed  not  only  through  anti-­‐capitalist  protests  and  demonstrations  such  as  the  Occupy  movement,  but  also  through  a  range  of  popular  commentary  (Mason,  2015;  Mazzucato,  2013;  Jacobs  et  al,  2016)  as  well  as  parliamentary  representatives.    

Political  parties  of  all  colour  have  sought  to  market  themselves  to  those  ‘left  behind’  or  ‘just  about  managing’,  promising  to  create  an  economy  which  works  for  all  (the  Guardian,  2017).  Cameron’s  aim  to  create  ‘capitalism  with  a  conscience’  (Elliot,  2009)  has  been  pursued  by  the  conservative  party  whose  2017  manifesto  rejected  free  market  capitalism  clarifying  ‘we  reject  the  cult  of  selfish  individualism..’  and  ‘We  do  not  believe  in  untrammelled  free  markets’  (Conservative  Party,  2017).  Recognizing  a  place  for  state  regulation  and  the  need  to  limit  executive  pay  and  asset-­‐stripping  by  foreign  investors,  the  Tories  have  promised  to  put  workers  first,  even  going  so  far  as  to  suggest  reforming  corporate  governance  to  give  employees  a  place  on  the  board  of  companies  (Conservative  Party,  2017).    The  Labour  party,  who  have  gained  in  popularity  on  a  platform  which  promotes  forms  of  nationalisation,  have  also  promised  to  put  workers  first,  and  reign  in  excessive  pay  and  the  excesses  of  the  City  of  London,  as  well  as  promising  to  create  a  National  Investment  Bank  to  promote  more  productive  investment  (Labour  Party,  2017).    

After  the  financial  crisis,  and  the  long  period  of  no  growth,  free-­‐market  ideology  thus  appears  to  be  losing  ground.  In  this  climate,  the  inevitability  of  free  market  forces  that  characterised  Naomi  Klein’s  Shock  Doctrine  (2007)  is  far  less  apparent.  It  is  not  entirely  certain  that  free  market  ideology  will  continue  to  determine  how  banks  create  credit  and  what  activities  they  finance.  Indeed,  there  appears  to  be  far  greater  scope  now  than  before  the  crisis  for  more  radically  intervening  in  banking  by  determining  what  activities  we  want  banks  to  undertake  and  finance.  This  is  unlikely  to  happen  however  as  long  as  our  law-­‐makers  continue  to  see  the  finance  industry  as  a  sort  of  national  treasure  which  needs  to  be  preserved  in  its  own  right  rather  than  as  a  means  to  growing  the  real  economy  and  an  engine  for  growth  which  needs  to  be  controlled.    

The  obvious  implications  from  all  of  this  are  that  we  still  need  to  go  a  lot  further  in  clarifying  what  functions  we  expect  banks  to  perform  and  which  activities  we  expect  them  to  finance  more  generously,  and  that  question  would  be  best  resolved  before  addressing  how  banks  are  owned  and  regulated.      

8.3.4   Reforms  unrelated  to  ownership        Notwithstanding  the  absence  of  clarity  about  what  we  want  banks  to  do,  

there  are  some  broader  lessons  to  be  learnt  from  the  empirical  research  unrelated  to  ownership.  The  clear  lesson  from  the  Nationwide  appears  to  be  that  

Page 155: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  155  

retail  functions  may  be  better  performed,  and  banks  themselves  more  resilient,  when  there  is  greater  compartmentalisation  and  functional  regulation.  Such  functional  regulation  would  inevitably  call  for  a  more  radical  and  interventionist  approach  from  our  regulators,  not  only  in  defining  what  we  want  from  banking,  but  also  in  identifying  and  tackling  the  structural  pressures  which  work  against  achieving  such  aims.  There  are  reasons  to  believe  that  such  radical  interventionism  may  one  day  be  feasible,  and  not  only  because  of  the  changes  in  the  political  climate  described  above.  The  more  radical  approach  of  Dodd-­‐Franks  to  functional  regulation  provides  a  useful  precedent.  If  other  regulators  in  other  countries  become  more  interventionist,  the  UK  may  follow  suit.      Also  the  failure  of  the  Government’s  ‘funding  for  lending’  initiative  (Jenkins  et  al,  2013)  also  provides  good  reasons  for  trying  to  set  explicit  targets  for  regulating  banks  to  achieve  certain  levels  of  funding  for  certain  activities.        

Whether  or  not  we  determine  what  role  we  want  banks  to  play,  it  seems  that  some  structural  pressures  will  need  to  be  tackled  come  what  may.  Without  breaking  up  the  strangle-­‐hold  the  big  banks  enjoy  on  the  retail  banking  market,  for  example,  we  are  unlikely  to  weaken  the  structural  pressures  discussed  in  chapter  4,  and  in  particular  the  growth  imperative  we  witnessed  for  smaller  banks  such  as  the  Co-­‐op  and  the  pressures  driven  by  high  cost  and  product  market  competition  which  encourage  banks  to  become  mimetic  in  their  offerings  and  activities.    

All  of  this  would  tend  to  suggest  that  we  need  to  be  more  sensitive  to  the  problems  faced  by  new  entrants  and  smaller  banks,  particularly  those  seeking  to  perform  ethical  and  low  yielding  activities  within  retail  functions.  Whilst  the  Co-­‐op  was  forced  to  acquire  branches,  the  biggest  banks  that  dominated  the  personal  and  SME  account  market  were  able  to  divest  themselves  of  branches.  That  the  big  banks  retain  such  competitive  advantage  over  smaller  banks  in  the  retail  market  still  appears  to  be  unfair,  and  there  are  good  reasons  to  suggest  that  competition  regulation  needs  to  go  further  to  reduce  the  dominant  position  of  big  banks  or  alleviate  the  pressures  suffered  by  small  and  ethical  retail  banks  to  mimic  their  less  ethical  peers.  Had  the  CMA  instead  proposed  ending  the  free-­‐if-­‐in-­‐credit  paradigm,  or  sought  to  impose  limits  on  target  returns  on  equity  from  certain  utility  functions  it  would  no  doubt  have  reduced  pressures  on  banks  to  seek  to  deliver  earnings  and  growth  in  unsafe  ways.  The  growth  imperative  might  also  be  reduced  if  access  to  the  payment  system  could  be  provided  on  terms  which  are  not  biased  in  favour  of  bigger  clearing  banks,  as  was  suggested  by  Philip  Augur  (2016).      

As  things  stand,  banks  remain  over-­‐leveraged  and  too  big  to  fail,  endangering  the  taxpayer  and  putting  unfair  competitive  pressure  on  smaller  banks  that  do  not  benefit  from  the  cheap  borrowing  rates  available  to  these  overly  subsidised  giants.  Retail  operations  have  not  been  properly  separated  from  the  rest  of  the  riskier  activities  performed  by  banks.  If  we  are  to  prevent  banks  from  imperilling  tax-­‐payers  in  the  future,  the  sector  as  a  whole  needs  to  be  radically  descaled,  and  broken  up  to  allow  for  parts  to  safely  fail  without  having  to  resort  to  the  lender  of  last  resort  for  a  bail  out.  The  obvious  way  of  achieving  that  would  be  to  break  up  and  separate  narrow  and  wide  banking  activities  into  separate  entities  and  to  put  an  end  to  universal  banking.  If  that  is  not  to  be  done,  then  we  at  least  need  to  find  ways  of  discouraging  banks  from  leveraging  

Page 156: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  156  

themselves  so  significantly,  as  otherwise  banks  will  always  have  incentives  to  become  too  big  to  fail.    

The  suggestions  for  banks  to  radically  increase  their  equity  (Admati  et  al  2012)  or  to  radically  increase  their  capital  reserves  paid  up  to  central  banks  (Turner,  2016,  ch.12)  are  sensible  ways  of  discouraging  banks  from  leveraging  themselves  so  dangerously.  The  proposals  of  Mian  and  Sufi  (Mian  et  al,  2014)  to  simplify  property  lending  and  Turner’s  suggestions  to  regulate  loan  to  value  ratios  also  appear  appropriate,  as  do  proposals  to  introduce  credit  limits  on  certain  lending  activities  (Turner,  2016,  p176).      As  well  as  implementing  greater  capital  requirements,  and  other  tax  reforms  might  also  assist  in  descaling  the  banking  sector.  A  credit  intermediation  tax  for  example  similar  to  that  initially  proposed  by  Tobin  might  reduce  transaction  generation  and  thus  likely  reduce  leverage.  Other  taxes  might  also  be  experimented  with,  especially  taxes  which  end  preferential  treatment  of  debt  over  equity  (Haldane  2012;  Turner,  pp191-­‐192;  Boon  and  Johnson,  2010)  or  even  wealth  tax  (Picketty,  2014).    

It  is  impossible  to  provide  a  comprehensive  list  of  all  of  the  reforms  required  to  fix  all  of  the  problems  in  banking  beyond  ownership  and  to  discuss  their  merits,  here.  The  task  of  defining  what  functions  we  expect  our  banks  to  finance  more  generously,  and  how  to  go  about  regulating  them  to  deliver  such  aims,  are  issues  which  really  call  for  further  study,  particularly  around  the  issues  of  capital  reserves,  leverage,  separation  of  functions,  and  tax  treatment.  It  would  significantly  exceed  the  scope  of  this  thesis  to  attempt  to  treat  such  subjects  or  to  venture  further  from  the  primary  focus,  which  must  return  to  the  issue  of  ownership.  What  appears  to  be  clear  from  the  findings  in  this  thesis  is  that  we  would  likely  benefit  from  more  functional  regulation  spelling  out  more  clearly  what  functions  we  expect  banks  to  perform  and  regulating  them  with  a  view  to  addressing  the  structural  pressures  which  work  against  banks  meeting  such  expectations.      

8.4   Part  3:  re-­‐thinking  and  re-­‐designing  ownership    

8.4.1   Stakeholder  stewards        

In  view  of  the  above  findings,  it  makes  little  sense  to  give  shareholders  all  of  the  rights  of  control  over  banks.  As  Haldane  (2015)  commented  in  the  quote  set  out  at  the  start  of  chapter  3,  it  is  erroneous  to  conceive  of  banks  as  being  ‘owned’  by  shareholders  at  all,  and  it  is  consequently  wrong  to  treat  shareholders  as  owners.  Whilst  shares  themselves  can  be  owned,  banks  themselves  cannot,  but  are  separate  persons  composed  of  a  community  of  interests.    And  whilst  shareholders  contribute  some  capital  to  banks  and  take  risks  in  doing  so,  banks  tend  to  handle  a  lot  more  of  other  people’s  money,  who  also  run  risks.  The  logic  of  having  banks  run  entirely  for  the  benefit  of  their  shareholders,  when  they  only  contribute  a  tiny  fraction  of  a  bank’s  assets  and  do  not  bare  all  of  the  risks,  makes  very  little  sense  in  this  context.  Instead,  it  is  logical  to  think  of  them,  as  indeed  Berle  and  Means  did,  as  being  ‘stakeholder’  or  ‘ownerless’  institutions,  subject  to  a  community  of  interests.  Once  conceived  of  in  this  way,  it  makes  far  more  sense  to  expect  those  who  control  banks  to  act  more  

Page 157: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  157  

like  trustees  handling  other  people’s  assets,  or  as  professional  bureaucrats  stewarding  assets  in  which  society  has  some  vested  interests.        

The  main  implication  of  this  thesis  is  therefore  that  we  need  to  stop  thinking  of  banks  as  being  ‘owned’  and  shareholders  as  ‘owners’,  and  we  need  to  devise  ways  of  ensuring  banks  are  run  not  only  in  the  interests  of  shareholders  but  more  broadly  in  the  interests  of  other  stakeholders.  It  is  difficult  to  reign  in  ideas  about  ownership  when  banks  are  run  for  their  shareholders  who  are  given  other  rights  to  govern  and  control  management.      We  therefore  need  to  find  ways  to  design  the  ownership  model  in  order  to  limit  the  rights  of  shareholders  and  to  make  such  rights  consistent  with  their  actual  contribution,  and  less  liable  to  conflict  with  the  interests  of  other  stakeholders.  We  also  need  to  recognise  that  if  we  continue  to  have  banks  run  primarily  for  shareholders,  there  are  likely  to  be  serious  adverse  implications  in  terms  of  their  behaviour  going  forwards.      

Fortunately,  there  are  a  plethora  of  ways  of  reducing  shareholder  rights  and  re-­‐designing  the  ownership  model.  The  obvious  starting  point  would  be  to  reform  directors’  duties.  One  possibility  is  that  suggested  by  the  Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  (2013b,  para.708)  namely  to  remove  shareholder  primacy  in  the  case  of  banks  and  to  expand  directors’  duties  to  ensure  the  long-­‐term  financial  ‘stability  and  soundness’  of  the  bank.  Another  possibility  would  be  to  pursue  Mayer’s  proposals  (2013,  p201)  to  create  trustees  within  the  board  owing  duties  to  promote  and  protect  the  corporation’s  particular  states  values  and  principles.      

Designing  and  experimenting  with  different  corporate  purposes  and  testing  their  governance  and  behavioural  dynamics  really  calls  out  for  a  collaborative  process  requiring  input  from  different  fields  of  social  science,  including  business,  economics,  law  and  perhaps  also  politics  and  accounting.  It  is  not  entirely  clear  which  fields  of  social  science  would  need  to  be  engaged  in  such  process,  and  the  methodology  would  likely  be  disputed.  Certainly  it  would  be  beyond  the  scope  of  this  thesis  to  attempt  to  prescribe  a  singular  type  of  reform  or  ownership  design  in  order  to  fairly  balance  the  different  interests  in  banks  and  enable  them  to  act  in  ways  which  meet  our  expectations  of  them.    

The  best  that  this  thesis  can  perhaps  attempt  to  do  is  to  advocate  for  greater  experimentation  in  looking  for  ways  to  reduce  shareholder  rights  and  make  those  who  run  banks  act  more  like  stakeholder  stewards  or  trustees  acting  for  a  wider  group  of  interests  than  just  shareholders.  In  that  connection,  it  is  a  shame  that  the  PCBS’s  recommendations  for  a  government  consultation  about  directors’  duties  in  banking  (2013b,  p344,  para.708)  has  fallen  by  the  way-­‐side.  A  sensible  opportunity  for  progress  has  been  missed.      

Changing  the  statutory  duties  of  directors  is  not  the  only  way  of  weakening  the  ownership  paradigm,  and  there  is  plenty  of  scope  for  experimentation  in  ways  of  reducing  shareholder  rights  and  enhancing  stakeholder  rights.  Options  include  :  re-­‐designing  financial  instruments  to  reduce  the  rights  bound  up  in  ‘shares’,  or  alternatively  spreading  about  control  rights  by  distributing  them  also  to  depositors,  bondholders  or  those  drawing  salaries  in  companies,  who  might  have  employee  representation  on  the  board.  Shares  are  already  capable  of  being  designed  in  ways  which  limit  control  rights.  They  can  reduce  control  rights,  for  example,  by  having  different  tiers  of  shareholding  with  different  associated  rights.  As  Haldane  pointed  out  (2015)  there  are  already  a  

Page 158: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  158  

plethora  of  ways  of  structuring  and  re-­‐purposing  shareholding  so  that  shareholders  or  some  classes  of  shareholders  have  fewer  control  rights.    

Those  shares  with  the  most  control  rights,  which  could  for  example  be  called  ‘tier  1’  or  ‘trust’  shares  could  be  held  by  specially-­‐selected  individuals,  or  groups,  on  trust  either  for  the  benefit  of  other  stakeholders  or  for  some  defined  purpose  for  example  in  accordance  with  explicit  values  or  principles.  In  other  countries,  employee  representatives  hold  a  proportion  of  shares  and  have  representatives  on  the  governance  board.  In  the  case  of  banks,  a  proportion  of  shares  might  be  held  by  employees  who  are  tasked  with  regulatory  compliance,  or  by  other  representatives,  including  those  employed  by  or  more  closely  affiliated  with  regulators  such  as  the  Bank  of  England.  In  such  an  example,  ‘tier  1’  or  ‘trust’  shares  might  be  privately  held  and  in  other  words  incapable  of  being  publicly  traded,  or  they  might  be  held  for  a  certain  number  of  years.    

In  the  UK  the  Charity  Commission  already  has  supervisory  and  oversight  powers  not  only  for  charities  but  also  for  other  forms  of  community  interest  or  social  purpose  companies.  There  is  no  reason  why  the  ownership  or  transfer  of  such  key  controlling  shares  could  not  be  more  carefully  monitored  or  controlled  by  the  Commission  or  another  public  body  which  could  be  empowered  to  act  as  a  check  against  the  sale  of  such  rights  for  short  term  profit  and  to  ensure  that  those  control  rights  are  owned  by  parties  who  are  well  placed  to  exercise  such  rights  in  the  long  term  interest  of  banks.  Other  tiers  of  shares  might  then  be  publicly  traded  but  endowed  with  lesser  control  rights  or  time-­‐limited  control  rights  or  rights  which  are  suspended  upon  given  events,  for  example  such  as  where  the  Bank  of  England  issues  certain  warnings.  Different  categories  of  shares  might  have  different  dividend  rights  for  example  with  core  controlling  ‘tier  1’  or  ‘trust’  shares  having  zero  scope  for  yielding  dividends  and  other  tiers  having  limited  or  conditional  scope  for  yielding  dividends.  Alternatively,  shares  might  be  accompanied  not  only  with  rights  but  also  with  liabilities  for  example  to  ‘bail  in’  capital  in  determinate  quantities  in  determinate  circumstances  when  a  bank  is  failing  or  risks  failing.    There  is  also  good  reason  for  experimenting  further  with  conditional  or  contingent  liabilities,  ‘bail  in’  shares  or  shares  with  limited  rights.  

In  these  different  ways,  the  extractive  capacity  of  share  ownership  might  be  reduced  or  abated  over  time  and  shareholder  control  rights  could  correspond  more  proportionately  with  the  amount  of  contribution  made  and  risk  taken  by  them.  Another  way  of  re-­‐designing  the  ownership  model,  or  governance  regime,  might  involve  removing  shareholders  from  the  equation  altogether.  As  Ireland  (2008,  2009)  and  more  recently  Haldane  (2015)  observed,  there  is  no  logical  or  necessary  reason  why  organisations  need  to  be  owned  whether  by  external  owners,  or  indeed  members.  Banks  are  social  constructs  which  can  be  made  in  different  ways  (Haldane,  2015).      

8.4.2     A  properly  ‘ownerless’  model    This  thesis  has  observed  with  particular  interest,  the  special  type  of  

stakeholder  model  which  has  no  owners  who  can  call  for  the  proceeds  of  its  business  operations  to  be  distributed.  Those  organisations  operate  not  to  benefit  their  members  or  outside  owners  but  rather  to  serve  their  own  predetermined  

Page 159: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  159  

purposes  (Hansmann,  1981).  Such  genuinely  ‘ownerless’  or  ‘social  purpose  not-­‐for-­‐profit’  models  have  interesting  potentially  very  positive  behavioural  implications  for  banks  (Bøhren  et  al,  2013).    By  design,  their  assets  and  proceeds  are    ‘locked’  from  distribution  and  must  be  applied  to  meet  defined  aims.  In  other  words  they  recycle  their  earnings.  Proceeds  which  would  otherwise  be  distributed  to  owners,  are  thus  available  to  be  applied  for  further  investment.  In  theory,  therefore,  an  ownerless  bank  would  be  in  a  better  position  to  serve  the  persons  or  purposes  it  aims  to  finance  than  a  shareholder-­‐owned  bank,  because  it  would  not  distribute  profits,  whether  through  dividends  to  shareholders  or  through  compensation  beyond  reasonable  remuneration  to  management.    

In  the  UK,  there  are  already  plenty  of  legal  forms  of  incorporation  in  which  an  ownerless  model  could  be  created.  An  ownerless  bank  could  even  be  run  through  a  regular  limited  company,  provided  its  constitution  was  modified  :  to  fix  its  social  purposes;  to  preclude  its  shares  from  being  traded  or  drawing  dividends;  and  to  preclude  distribution  of  earnings  to  managers  beyond  what  is  reasonable  remuneration.  The  Co-­‐operative  and  Community  Benefit  Societies  Act  2014  has  created  other  forms  of  incorporation  to  assist  in  entrenching  these  aims.  ‘Community  Benefit  Societies’  or  ‘Community  Interest  Companies’  both  afford  opportunities  to  entrench  an  organisation’s  social  aims,  and  to  prevent  assets  from  being  distributed  to  owners  or  to  management,  beyond  what’s  considered  reasonable  remuneration.      

There  are  also  plentiful  examples  of  ownerless  organisations  in  existence  in  the  UK  which  are  more  akin  to  a  trust  or  public  institutions.    There  are  also  ownerless  banks  in  other  jurisdictions,  including  the  Norwegian  Sparkassen  and  the  Spanish  Cajas  (Crespì  et  al,  2004;  Bøhren  et  al,  2013),  although  as  we  explored  in  chapter  5,  these  models  do  not  necessarily  make  for  easy  comparisons,  at  least  in  the  case  of  the  Cajas,  as  their  own  behaviour  calls  for  investigation  in  its  own  right  (Trenlet,  2012).  There  are  also  various  public  international  organisations,  such  as  the  European  Investment  Fund  and  European  Investment  Bank,  which  also  operate  in  ways  which  constrain  distribution  to  their  owners  and  allow  them  to  recycle  and  dedicate  their  proceeds  into  meeting  their  entrenched  social  aims.  More  parochially,  in  the  UK,  the  Charity  Bank  locks  its  assets  from  distribution,  and  applies  them  to  invest  in  charities.  There  is  also  a  social  investment  fund  in  the  UK  called  ‘Big  Society  Capital’  which  was  set  up  in  2012  and  capitalised  with  an  initial  fund  of  £600  million,  which  invests  in  to  the  ‘social  sector’  (O’Donohoe,  2014).    

Anybody  seeking  to  design  an  ownerless  bank  might  wish  to  consider  these  different  examples.  However,  they  are  not  the  only,  or  indeed  the  best  way,  for  designing  an  ownerless  bank,  and  each  of  those  examples  pursues  different  purposes.  The  Norwegian  and  Spanish  banks  for  example  play  a  particular  role  in  regional  development  rather  than  performing  productive  investment  nationally  (Bøhren  et  al,  2013).  The  European  Investment  Fund  and  European  Investment  Bank  on  the  other  hand  are  international  organisations  and  are  not  fractional  reserve  deposit  taking  banks.  They  tend  to  prioritise  infrastructural  projects  and  raise  money  in  capital  markets  by  going  into  joint  ventures  with  other  financial  institutions,  rather  than  dedicating  just  their  retained  earnings  (Lankowski,  1996).  Similarly,  the  Charity  Bank  and  Big  Society  Capital  are  not  deposit-­‐taking  fractional  reserve  banks.  The  former  pursues  extremely  social  aims  by  assisting  mainly  charities  and  the  latter  is  partly  externally  owned  with  

Page 160: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  160  

40%  of  its  shares  being  owned  by  four  of  the  high  street  banks  namely  Barclays,  HSBC,  RBS  and  Lloyds  (O’Donohoe,  2014).  

Any  attempt  to  design  an  ownerless  bank  would  need  not  only  to  find  ways  of  restraining  assets  from  distribution,  but  also  to  entrench  the  bank’s  purposes.    Following  on  from  the  above  discussion,  and  that  in  chapter  4,  Kay’s  list  of  banking  functions  might  provide  a  helpful  starting  point.  According  to  Kay  banks  perform  socially  helpful  functions  in  allocating  financial  capital  to  meet  the  borrowing  needs  of  households  and  businesses,  helping  them  to  understand  financial  risks  and  manage  their  finances  across  life-­‐cycles  as  well  as  providing  productive  investment  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  real  economy  (Kay,  2015,  p299).      All  of  these  activities  involve  handling  other  peoples’  money  in  often  routine  transactions,  where  an  absence  of  incentives  for  risks  might  foster  more  prudence  care  and  trust.  Certainly,  there  appears  to  be  a  perceived  funding  gap  in  terms  of  productive  investment,  with  many  commentators  and  politicians  calling  for  greater  investment  in  wealth  generating  enterprises  (Turner,  2016;  Eaton,  2012;  Elgot,  2016)  

Whatever  expectations  and  purposes  we  decide  upon,  in  order  for  banks  to  be  able  to  deliver  upon  them,  particular  attention  will  need  to  be  paid  to  the  cost  of  capital.  Unlike  a  PLC  any  ownerless  bank  would  be  limited  in  its  ability  to  raise  capital  from  the  issue  of  regular  equity.  Any  new  bank  would  thus  need  to  have  sufficient  capital,  or  access  to  capital,  to  be  insulated  from  the  problems  which  surfaced  in  the  case  of  the  Co-­‐op.  Since  retail  banking  still  requires  costly  high  street  branches,  an  ownerless  bank  might  need  to  be  capitalised  initially  with  sufficient  own  resources  to  have  a  sizeable  share  of  the  current  account  market.  Alternatively,  other  ways  of  providing  access  to  capital  could  be  explored.  Our  national  government  might  consider  pledging  capital  to  such  bank,  as  was  the  case  with  the  EIB  (Lankowski,  1996).    

Alternatively,  we  might  allocate  funds  from  redundant  bank  accounts,  as  currently  flow  into  Big  Society  Capital  (O’Donohoe,  2014),  or  we  could  allocate  capital  from  other  redundant  sources  such  as  those  which  currently  pass  to  the  state  bona  vacantia  when  a  person  dies  without  any  next  of  kin  or  will  disposing  of  their  assets.  Alternatively,  the  state  might  explicitly  guarantee  the  performance  of  our  new  bank’s  obligations,  as  the  Nordic  states  do  with  the  Norwegian  Investment  Bank,  thus  enabling  the  bank  to  access  cheap  capital  (Nordic  Investment  Bank,  2017).  The  Bank  of  England  might  provide  preferential  lending  as  a  quid  pro  quo  for  dedicating  its  proceeds  or  parts  of  its  proceeds  to  providing  productive  investment  in  the  real  economy.  Alternatively,  it  might  seek  to  raise  equity  by  offering  limited  returns,  as  experimented  with  by  the  equity  issue  granted  by  the  Nationwide  (Nationwide,  2017).    

Creating  any  new  bank  would  likely  encounter  significant  political  obstacles  and  require  significant  political  will.  In  the  current  conjuncture,  it  may  be  infeasible  to  convert  all  of  the  UK’s  retail  banks  into  ownerless  banks,  but  significantly  more  feasible  to  convert  those  banks  which  have  to  be  bailed  out  or  nationalised  in  the  future.  Certainly,  to  provide  for  that  eventuality  if  nothing  else,  there  is  good  reason  to  engage  in  further  discussion  and  experimentation  about  creating  more  ‘ownerless’  forms  of  banking,  to  remove  or  reduce  shareholder  rights  and  to  spread  oversight  and  control  rights  around  to  others  who  are  better  placed  to  ensure  they  behave  more  responsibly  and  invest  more  productively.        

Page 161: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  161  

 

8.4.3   An  ownerless  National  Investment  Bank    

It  may  also  be  feasible  to  create  the  national  investment  bank  which  is  currently  proposed  by  the  Labour  Party  in  a  form  which  is  ownerless.  Recent  leaders  of  the  Opposition,  including  Ed  Miliband,  Jeremy  Corbyn,  and  the  leader  contestant  Owen  Smith,  have  all  proposed  creating  a  national  investment  bank  to  undertake  more  productive  investment  (Eaton,  2012;  Elgot,  2016).  In  the  current  environment  of  low  growth,  it  is  entirely  feasible  that  political  will  for  creating  such  bank  may  bear  fruit.  Such  banks  have  fared  well  in  other  countries.  In  Germany,  the  state-­‐owned  KfW  development  bank  is  still  serving  its  post-­‐war  purposes  and  making  considerable  productive  investment  to  this  day  (Carrington,  2012),  and  in  Scandinavia,  the  Nordic  Investment  Bank  operates  across  various  states  to  make  investments  into  businesses  (Skidalsky  et  al,  2011).    

If  such  a  bank  were  created  in  the  UK,  there  would  be  good  reason  to  design  its  ownership  model  in  a  way  which  locked  its  assets  from  distribution  and  dedicated  them  to  investment  purposes.  Indeed,  unless  such  a  bank  were  created  in  this  way,  its  purposes  might  be  compromised  by  extractive  demands  of  shareholders,  as  was  the  case  with  the  last  national  investment  bank  created  in  the  UK,  and  more  recently  the  case  with  the  Green  Investment  Bank  (Kollewe,  2017).    

In  his  critique  of  shareholder  governance,  Meyer  (2013,  pp132-­‐135),  explored  the  case  of  the  ICFC  which  later  became  known  as  3i,  and  the  reasons  for  its  changing  role.    Following  the  great  depression,  in  1931,  the  Macmillan  Committee  proposed  the  creation  of  the  Industrial  and  Commercial  Financial  Corporation  (ICFC),  which  was  eventually  created  after  the  Second  World  War.  Keynes,  who  sat  on  the  committee,  was  a  prominent  advocate  for  a  new  bank  to  perform  productive  investment.    Set  up  in  1945,  the  ICFC  was  capitalised  with  £15  million  and  charged,  as  its  namesake  suggests,  with  the  purpose  of  providing  productive  investment  to  small  industrial  and  commercial  businesses.    A  sister  fund  was  also  set  up  also  in  1945  called  the  Finance  Corporation  for  Industry,  with  the  purpose  of  providing  finance  for  larger  industrial  companies.  Both  were  intended  to  plug  what  was  called  the  ‘Macmillan  gap’  namely  the  lack  of  sources  of  capital  for  medium  sized  firms  which  banks  were  failing  to  provide.    

Those  funds  were  not  designed  to  be  ownerless.  Their  constitutions  did  not  entrench  their  aims  in  irrevocable  ways,  nor  constrain  their  shares  from  being  traded  and  their  assets  from  being  distributed  to  outsiders.    Eventually,  its  shareholders  sought  to  raise  more  equity  and  floated  the  company  on  the  stock  market.  Having  merged  with  its  sister  company  in  1973,  eventually  becoming  ‘Finance  for  Industry’  the  company  floated  on  the  London  Stock  Exchange  in  1994.  Following  floatation,  it  then  changed  its  name  to  3i,  and  was  ran  for  the  benefit  of  its  shareholders  who  themselves  were  typically  interested  in  profitably  trading  its  shares,  3i  moved  away  from  pursuing  productive  investment.  Having  become  more  value  driven,  it  shifted  into  more  profitable  activities.  Since  the  1980s,  and  leading  up  to  its  floatation,  the  firm  became  increasingly  involved  in  private  equity,  and  financing  management  buyouts,  in  other  words  funding  corporate  raiders  in  their  endeavours  to  take  over  other  

Page 162: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  162  

companies.  The  organisation  which  should  have  been  value  creative  ended  up  operating  in  the  market  for  corporate  control,  effectively  disciplining  the  management  of  other  companies  to  work  more  efficiently  for  the  benefit  of  their  own  shareholders.    

Some  argue  that  the  UK  Green  Investment  Bank  is  likely  to  go  the  same  way  (Kollewe,  2017).  Having  been  mostly  sold  to  external  investors,  many  fear  that  its  green  agenda  will  be  undermined  by  more  profit-­‐oriented  aims.  Time  will  tell  whether  the  retention  of  some  shares  by  government  suffices  to  protect  and  promote  those  greed  aims.    

These  precedents  provide  cautionary  tales  for  those  who  create  any  new  National  Investment  Bank.  If  societally  important  functions  are  to  be  protected  from  ownership  pressures,  such  bank  would  do  well  to  be  designed  with  an  ownerless  model.  Had  the  ICFC  been  less  dependent  on  equity  for  investment,  for  example  had  it  been  endowed  with  more  capital,  or  licenced  to  act  also  as  a  fractional  reserve  bank  to  also  take  deposits,  or  indeed  given  the  benefit  of  redundant  assets  such  as  those  in  dormant  bank  accounts,  or  perhaps  some  of  the  assets  which  pass  bona  vacantia,  it  might  have  still  served  its  original  aims  of  productive  investment  today.  Instead,  however,  its  assets  were  not  protected  from  distribution,  and  it  was  able  to  distribute  its  proceeds  and  cede  control  to  those  in  whose  interest  it  was  eventually  run  for.  Had  the  ICFC  been  ownerless  over  time,  without  distributing  proceeds  to  members,  it  may  well  have  grown  in  size  and  economic  power  and  might  have  been  in  a  better  position  to  offer  finance  for  productive  investment.    

 

8.4.4     Encouraging  responsibility    Ownerless  banks  also  pose  benefits  in  terms  of  enhancing  standards.  

According  to  Hansmann  (1980,  1981,  1988)  having  no  scope  to  distribute  surplus  proceeds  to  outsiders,  and  being  required  to  apply  such  proceeds  to  meet  its  aims,  the  not-­‐for-­‐profit  model  puts  a  check  upon  profit-­‐seeking  incentives  and  is  a  recipe  for  more  responsibility.  Without  incentives  for  irresponsibility  there  is  arguably  less  need  for  external  regulation  and  potentially  also  scope  for  cultivating  better  standards  from  counter-­‐parties.        

At  present,  as  we  explored  in  chapter  4,  the  responsibility  for  promoting  public  good  is  not  placed  within  the  sphere  of  private  institutions,  and  it  seems  almost  inconceivable  therefore  that  banks  might  ever  work  to  enhance  standards  within  those  they  have  dealings  with.    As  we  observed  at  4.1,  following  the  Big  Bang,  banks  become  increasingly  responsible  for  serving  their  private  interests  and  less  responsible  for  the  morality  of  their  behaviour  which  tended  to  be  externalized.  This  predicament  resulted  in  what  Luyendijk  called  a  culture  of  ‘amorality’  within  banks  and  led  to  inevitable  failure  as  regulators,  whose  job  it  became  to  police  against  bad  behaviour,  faced  an  impossibly  difficult  task.  Run  purely  along  private  lines  for  extraction,  our  current  banks  are  largely  absolved  of  responsibility  for  their  actions  –  anything  goes,  provided  what  they  do  is  not  illegal,  or  not  likely  to  be  caught  (Luyendijk,  2015).    Banks  do  not  have  incentives  to  behave  themselves,  let  alone  to  encourage  better  behaviour  from  their  counterparties.  

If  banks  were  purpose-­‐built  to  perform  socially  beneficial  investments  with  their  assets  being  locked  and  dedicated  to  meeting  those  purposes  there  

Page 163: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  163  

would  potentially  be  scope  to  condition  better  behaviour  from  those  they  invest  in  by  requiring  them  to  respect  certain  rights  or  undertake  and  honour  certain  obligations.  Indeed,  freed  from  extractive  ownership  pressures  large  international  banks,  such  as  the  European  Investment  Bank,  already  practice  a  form  of  loose  conditionality,  not  only  by  vetting  the  social  and  environmental  practices  of  those  they  invest  in  (many  of  whom  are  outside  of  the  EU)  (Lankowski,  1996),  but  also  by  extracting  contractual  agreement  from  such  borrowers  to  abide  by  the  acquis  communautaire,  and  in  other  words  to  abide  by  the  entire  gamut  of  EU  social,  environmental  and  employment  protection  legislation  (Wilkinson,  2005).  Although  in  practice,  such  clauses  are  not  enforced  in  private  law  by  the  EIB,  in  theory  they  could  be,  and  it  is  not  impossible  to  imagine  a  world  where  our  future  financial  institutions  are  owned  and  organised  in  such  ways  that  they  are  so  limited  in  pursuing  their  own  self-­‐interest  that  they  instead  seek  to  use  their  economic  power  for  public  good  by  conditioning  better  behaviours  in  those  they  invest  in.    

8.5   Part  4:  evaluation  and  contribution      The  inquiry  made  in  this  thesis  was  really  motivated  by  an  interest  in  

Hansmann’s  claims  (1980,  1981,  1988)  and  in  particular  the  idea  that  banks  might  behave  more  responsibly  and  invest  more  productively  if  they  were  not  run  for  shareholder-­‐value,  but  were  instead  run  as  social  purpose  non-­‐profits.  The  idea  of  having  an  ownerless  bank  recycle  the  proceeds  of  its  investments  and  continually  apply  them  to  making  productive  investments  whilst  fascinating  appeared  to  be  unexplored  by  the  official  response  to  the  global  financial  crisis,  which  lacked  any  will  to  challenge  or  even  question  the  existing  ownership  paradigm,  and  seemed  intend  to  assume  that  banks  should  be  treated,  at  least  notionally,  as  if  they  were  owned  by  their  shareholders.    

We  have  since  witnessed  how  the  banking  reform  debate  has  moved  on  and  how  what  were  previously  marginalised  criticisms  of  shareholder-­‐value  banking  have  moved  more  into  the  mainstream.  As  we  witnessed  in  part  4  of  chapter  3  (3.5),  there  is  now  a  nascent  but  important  branch  of  corporate  governance  literature  which  appears  to  be  growing  in  influence  and  which  is  critical  of  the  ownership  paradigm  at  least  in  banking.  Whereas  previously  the  balance  of  opinion  seemed  to  weigh  strongly  in  favour  of  shareholder-­‐value  governance  and  across  the  spectrum  whatever  the  industry  of  activity,  after  the  crisis,  at  least  as  far  as  banking  is  concerned,  the  scales  seem  to  have  tilted.  Significant  inroads  have  now  been  made  into  exposing  the  illogicality  of  having  banks  run  as  if  owned  by  their  shareholders  and  the  political-­‐economic  consensus  appears  to  have  weakened  both  on  the  micro-­‐level  where  shareholder-­‐value  banking  has  been  criticised  even  by  central  bankers  such  as  Andy  Haldane,  and  also  on  the  macro-­‐level  where  the  wisdom  of  leaving  credit-­‐allocation  to  free  market  forces  has  been  questioned  by  former  regulators  such  as  Turner  (2016)  or  prominent  commentators  such  as  Wolf  (2014c).      

The  implications  of  this  thesis  speak  to  those  two  issues  :  how  companies  are  and  should  be  owned  and  governed,  and  what  we  as  a  society  need  from  them.  The  conclusions  are  that  banks  should  be  treated  not  as  if  owned  by  their  shareholders  but  in  a  way  which  is  more  consistent  with  the  reality  that  banks  create  and  allocate  huge  amounts  of  credit  and  as  a  society  we  have  a  vested  

Page 164: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  164  

interest  in  ensuring  such  credit  is  allocated  in  helpful  and  not  harmful  ways.    It  is  hoped  that  the  thesis  might  add  to  what  is  now  a  growing  and  important  body  of  literature  which  is  both  critical  of  shareholder-­‐value  banking,  and  which  is  keen  to  reform  banking  to  ensure  that  the  credit  it  creates  and  allocates  is  directed  more  usefully  into  productive  investment.    

It  is  also  hoped  that  the  means  of  diagnosis  as  well  as  the  prognosis  might  prove  of  relevance  and  use  to  others.  The  taxonomy  employed  by  this  thesis  deliberately  emphasised  the  concept  of  ‘ownership’  in  preference  to  other  more  exacting  terms  such  as  ‘shareholder  value’  or  ‘governance’.  Whilst  the  latter  may  have  been  semantically  more  accurate  in  describing  governance  phenomena,  the  former  is  more  emotive  and  helps  to  emphasise  one  of  the  key  implications  of  the  thesis  namely  that  we  need  to  try  to  find  ways  of  structuring  and  regulating  banks  which  recognise  that  banks  are  not  in  fact  owned  by  shareholders.  This  thesis  chose  to  refer  to  the  ‘ownership  model’  rather  than  the  ‘governance  regime’  and  to  employ  the  semantics  of  ‘ownership’  because  such  terminology  was  useful  shorthand  and  also  provided  a  conceptualisation  which  helped  to  emphasise  the  illogicality  of  treating  shareholders  like  owners.      

As  well  as  adopting  the  language  of  ‘ownership  pressures’  and  ‘ownerlessness’,  the  thesis  also  described  the  pressures  arising  from  the  market  environment  within  which  banks  operate  as  ‘structural  pressures’.  This  term  was  not  employed  as  a  means  of  encapsulating  all  other  phenomena  which  might  impact  upon  bank  behaviour  under  one  heading.  Rather,  it  made  conceptual  sense  to  consider  external  pressures  arising  out  of  the  space  and  environment  within  which  banks  operated  as  such  factors  were  logically  distinct  from  internal  pressures  arising  out  of  the  way  the  governance  structure  regulates  how  banks  are  ran.  This  terminology  might  be  criticised  as  lacking  in  precision  and  it  might  also  have  required  repeated  exemplification  and  illustration  throughout  the  thesis.  But,  it  was  nevertheless  useful  as  a  way  of  conceiving  of  other  influences  on  bank  behaviour.  It  is  hoped  that  this  kind  of  conceptual  distinction  and  use  of  terminology  might  prove  useful  for  others  in  distinguishing  governance  and  ownership  issues  and  as  a  means  of  conceiving  of  and  exploring  the  other  dangers,  limitations  and  opportunities  arising  in  the  market  and  regulatory  environment  within  which  banks  operate.        

8.6   Conclusions    

Until  now,  the  halo  which  was  constructed  around  finance  following  the  Big  Bang  has  made  it  difficult  for  politicians  to  resist  the  demands  of  the  finance  industry.  This  has  meant  that  the  reform  package  implemented  in  the  UK  has  preserved  the  City  as  a  sort  of  protected  national  treasure,  rather  than  seeking  to  fix  banking  to  make  it  serve  the  economy’s  needs.  As  the  economy  proves  increasingly  prone  to  low  productivity,  short-­‐termism,  and  the  problems  of  boom  and  bust,  there  may  well  be  greater  willingness  than  before  to  contemplate  more  radical  ways  of  making  banks  behave  more  responsibly  and  invest  more  productively.    Those  seeking  to  dislodge  neoliberalism  and  replace  it  with  an  economic  system  which  creates  and  redistributes  wealth  more  sustainably  and  equitably  may  have  more  political  opportunity  to  do  so  now  than  before  the  crisis.    

Page 165: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  165  

Despite  Government  claims  that  the  banking  reform  agenda  has  come  to  an  ‘end’  (H.  M.  Treasury,  2015),  the  debate  about  how  to  reform  banks  still  continues.  There  is  now  increasing  willingness  to  criticise  the  structural  and  ownership  paradigms  entrenched  since  the  Big  Bang  and  to  look  for  ways  to  make  banks  serve  our  broader  economic  needs.  Where  banking  reform  goes  from  here  has  reached  something  a  cross-­‐roads:    we  can  continue  along  the  same  path  opened  up  by  the  neoliberal  agenda,  championing  the  City  of  London  as  a  key  industry  in  itself,  and  trusting  free  market  forces  to  determine  how  credit  is  created  and  allocated;  or,  the  state  can  take  more  control  of  credit-­‐creation  and  allocation  by  determining  what  sectors  and  businesses  are  to  be  financed  more  or  less  generously;  or,  we  might  take  the  middle  path  by  being  more  watchful  of  the  City’s  credit-­‐creation,  and  at  the  same  time  take  steps  to  ensure  there  is  greater  investment  into  wealth  producing  activities  for  example  by  creating  a  National  Investment  Bank,  as  proposed  by  the  Labour  Party.    

Whichever  route  is  taken,  ‘ownership’  still  matters.  If  we  want  to  address  the  fundamental  structural  incentives  which  drive  bad  behaviour  and  which  encourage  credit  to  be  allocated  in  harmful  or  unhelpful  ways,  then  the  underlying  ‘ownership’  problem  needs  to  be  tackled.  Fixing  ‘ownership’  will  not  necessarily  ensure  that  credit  is  allocated  sustainably  where  needed  in  the  economy  and  it  will  not  be  the  only  reform  needed  to  ensure  that  banks  behave  themselves.  But  the  findings  of  this  thesis  strongly  suggest  that  this  is  nevertheless  a  necessary  reform,  which  still  needs  to  be  made.  Whether  or  not  we  see  the  finance  sector  as  an  essential  engine  for  economic  growth,  as  a  means  to  an  end  rather  than  a  protected  industry  in  itself,  we  need  to  address  the  ownership  dynamic  which  appears  to  be  driving  much  of  the  dysfunctionality  and  irresponsibility  in  banking.    External  regulation  is  unlikely  ever  to  be  adequate  in  ensuring  responsible  behaviour  and  helpful  productive  investment  if  at  the  same  time  as  policing  against  misbehaviour  banks  are  given  incentives  to  act  in  reckless,  exploitative  and  self-­‐serving  ways.    

In  whose  benefit  banks  are  run,  is  thus  something  which  needs  to  be  re-­‐visited  and  re-­‐vised.  We  need  to  arrest  all  notions  that  banks  are  owned  by  their  shareholders.  They  are  not.  And  we  need  to  modify  the  requirement  that  banks  should  be  run  primarily  in  their  interests,  because  that  arrangement  is  liable  to  jeopardise  other  interests  which  need  also  to  be  protected.  We  instead  need  to  be  far  more  experimental  and  creative  in  exploring  ways  of  making  banks  act  more  like  stewards  or  trustees  administering  assets  in  which  we  all  have  some  vested  interest.    

As  was  explored  above  in  8.3  and  8.4,  there  is  not  only  increasing  willingness  to  contemplate  more  radical  ways  of  making  banks  behave  more  responsibly,  but  there  are  also  a  range  of  options  for  tackling  the  ownership  problem.  As  well  as  re-­‐defining  in  whose  interest  banks  are  run,  a  whole  host  of  other  initiatives  could  be  explored  including  :  drawing  up  the  blueprints  for  converting  into  an  ownerless  banks  any  bank  which  is  nationalised  in  the  future;  or  designing  an  ownerless  model  for  any  newly  created  National  Investment  Bank,  such  as  that  currently  proposed  by  the  Labour  Party.  If  the  examples  of  the  Green  Bank  and  3i  are  not  to  be  followed,  any  National  Investment  Bank  which  is  created,  would  do  well  to  have  an  ownership  model  which  protects  it  from  shareholder  governance  and  which  enables  it  to  dedicate  its  assets  to  productive  investment  and  to  entrench  such  purposes.    

Page 166: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  166  

Whilst  truly  ‘ownerless’  models  remain  untested  in  the  arena  of  UK  banking,  there  appears  to  be  every  reason  for  trying  to  experiment  with  them,  especially  since  there  is  considerable  scope  in  banking  for  assets  to  be  dedicated  for  investment  in  socially  desirable  ways.    Indeed,  the  idea  of  having  an  ownerless  bank  constantly  recycle  the  proceeds  of  its  investments  into  further  productive  investments,  may  well  form  a  component  of  some  new  economic  system  seeking  to  create  and  redistribute  wealth  more  sustainably  than  under  the  current  neoliberal  order.  

       

     

   

Page 167: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  167  

References  Adams,  R.  and  Mehran,  H.,  (2003)    ‘Is  corporate  governance  different  for  bank  holding  companies?’  Economic  Policy  Review,  9,  pp.  123-­‐142.      

Admati,  A.,  and  Hellwig,  M.  (2012)  The  bankers'  new  clothes:  what's  wrong  with  banking  and  what  to  do  about  it,  Princeton  University  Press.  

Ahmed,  K.  (2016)  ‘Sale  of  Lloyds  shares  to  public  delayed  by  George  Osborne’  The  BBC,  28  January  2016  (available  online  at:  http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-­‐35429472  [accessed  21.09.17]).      

Allen,  F.,  Carletti,  E.,  and  Robert,  M.  (2009)  ‘Stakeholder  capitalism,  corporate  governance  and  firm  value’  Boston  University  Working  Paper  (available  at:  http://ssrn.com/abstract=968141  [accessed  15.09.17]).    

Amess,  K.  (2002)  ‘Financial  institutions,  the  theory  of  the  firm  and  organizational  form’  The  Service  Industries  Journal,  22(2),  pp.129-­‐148.    

Antunes  de  silva,  C.,  and  Stuart,  A.  (2007)    ‘With  or  without  you:  Barclays  displays  solid  organic  momentum  despite  ongoing  uncertainty  around  ABN’  JP  Morgan  Securities  Limited,  London,  3  August  2007  

Ayadi,  R.,  Schmidt,  R.  and  Valverde,  C.  (2009)  ‘Investigating  diversity  in  the  banking  sector:  the  performance  and  role  of  savings  banks’,  Centre  for  European  Policy  Studies  Brussels,  26  June  2009    

Baker,  S.  and  J.  Menon  (2011)    ‘Diamond  parries  attacks  on  pay  with  vow  to  earn  public  trust’,  Bloomberg,  30  November  2011.  

Barclays  (2008)  Annual  Report  2008,  Barclays  (available  at:  https://www.home.barclays/content/dam/barclayspublic/docs/InvestorRelations/AnnualReports/AR2008/2008-­‐barclays-­‐bank-­‐plc-­‐annual-­‐report.pdf    [accessed  on  20.04.17])    

Barclays  (2010)  Annual  Review  2010  ‘delivering  on  our  promises’  (available  at  :https://www.home.barclays/content/dam/barclayspublic/docs/InvestorRelations/AnnualReports/AR2010/2010-­‐barclays-­‐plc-­‐annual-­‐review.pdf  [accessed  16.09.17])  

Barclays  (2011)  full  year  2011,  results  presentation,  Bob  Diamond,  Chief  Executive,  Barclays,  (available  at:  https://www.home.barclays/content/dam/barclayspublic/docs/InvestorRelations/ResultAnnouncements/2011FYResults/Speech-­‐Bob-­‐Diamond-­‐Group-­‐Chief-­‐Executive-­‐Full-­‐Year-­‐2011-­‐Results.pdf  [accessed  20.04.17])  

BBC  (2008)    ‘Co-­‐op  buys  Somerfield  for  £1.57bn’,  BBC,  16  July  2008  (available  online,  at  :  http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/7508982.stm  [accessed  18.09.17])  

Page 168: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  168  

Berle,  A.  (1954)  The  twentieth  century  capitalist  revolution,  Harcourt  Brace,  New  York.  

Berle,  A.  and  Means,  G.  (1932)  The  modern  corporation  and  private  property,  (1st  Ed.)  Harcourt,  Brace  and  world,  New  York.  

Black,  J.,  Kershaw,  D.  (2015)    The  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  and  report  on  bank  incentives:  a  missed  opportunity,  Law  and  Financial  Projects  Briefing,  London  (available  online  at  http://www.lse.ac.uk/collections/law/projects/lfm/LFMP%202%20-­‐%20A%20Missed%20Opportunity%20%5Bfinal%5D.pdf  [accessed  on  15.09.17)]  

Blair,  M.  (1995)  Ownership  and  control  –  rethinking  corporate  governance,  Washington  DC,  the  Brookings  Institution.    

Bloomberg  (2013)  ‘Libor  lies  revealed  in  rigging  of  $300  trillion  benchmark’  Bloomberg,  28  January  2013.  

Bøhren,  Ø.  and  Josefson,  M.  (2013)  ‘Stakeholder  rights  and  economic  performance:  the  profitability  of  nonprofits’,  Journal  of  Banking  and  Finance,  37(2013)11,  pp.4073-­‐4086.    

Bøhren,  Ø.,  Josefsen,  M.  and  Pål,  S.  (2012)  ‘Stakeholder  conflicts  and  dividend  policy’,  Journal  of  Banking  and  Finance,  36,  pp.2852–2864.    

Bowman,  A.,  Froud,  J.,  Johal,  S.,  Law,  J.,  Leaver,  A.,  Moran,  M.,  and  Williams,  K.  (2014)  The  End  of  the  Experiment,  University  of  Manchester  Press,  Manchester.    

Brummer,  A.  (2015)  Bad  Banks:  greed,  incompetence  and  the  next  global  crisis,  Penguin  Random  House  Business  Books.    

Carpenter,  D.  Moss,  D.  (2004),  Preventing  Regulatory  Capture,  Cambridge  University  Press  

Carrington,  D.  (2012)  ‘How  a  green  investment  bank  really  works’,  The  Guardian,  24  May  2012.  

Cassidy,  J.  (2013)    ‘Andrew  Haldane:  The  World's  100  Most  Influential  People’,    Time  Magazine,  23  April  2013.  

Chu,  B.  (2014)  ‘Co-­‐op  Bank  mulls  suing  directors  and  advisers  over  Britannia  deal’,  The  Independent,  30  April  2014.  

Coco,  G.,  and  Ferri,  G.  (2010)  ‘From  shareholders  to  stakeholders  finance:  a  more  sustainable  lending  model’  International  Journal  of  Sustainable  Economy,  2(3),  pp.352-­‐364.    

Collier,  N.  (1998)  ‘Briefing  Lloyds  TSB’,  Morgan  Stanley  Dean  Witter,  18  February  1998.  

Page 169: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  169  

Collier,  N.  (1999)  ‘European  Investment  Research,  Lloyds  TSB  not  just  a  cost-­‐cutting  story’,  Morgan  Stanley  Dean  Witter,  16  February  1999.  

Collins,  N.  (2011)    ‘Bob  Diamond:  the  “unacceptable  face  of  banking”’,  The  Daily  Telegraph,  11  January  2011.  

Collinson,  P.  (2009)    ‘Britannia  and  Co-­‐operative  to  create  £70bn  'super-­‐mutual'’,  The  Guardian,  21  January  2009.  

Collinson,  P.  (2014)    ‘Ombudsman  still  receiving  1,000  complaints  a  day  on  PPI  mis-­‐selling’  The  Guardian,  4  March  2014.    

Competitions  and  Markets  Authority,  Retail  banking  market  investigation,  final  report,  9  August  2016,  CMA:  London    

Conservative  Party  (2017)  Manifesto  (available  at  :  https://s3.eu-­‐west-­‐2.amazonaws.com/manifesto2017/Manifesto2017.pdf  [accessed  14.09.17]).  

Craig,  P  and  DeBurca,  G.  (2008)  Competition  Law,  Oxford  University  Press.  

Craven,  N.  (2013)    ‘Crystal  meth  shame  of  bank  chief’,  The  Mail  on  Sunday,  16  November  2013.  

CRESC  (2009)  An  alternative  report  on  UK  Banking  Reform,  CRESC  Manchester  and  Milton  Keynes,  Cente  for  Research  into  Socio-­‐Cultural  Change  (available  at:  http://hummedia.manchester.ac.uk/institutes/cresc/sites/default/files/Alternative%20report%20on%20banking%20V2.pdf  [accessed  21.09.17]).  

Crespí,  R.,  García-­‐Cestona,  M.  and  Salas,  V.  (2004)  ‘Governance  mechanisms  in  Spanish  banks.  Does  ownership  matter?’  Journal  of  Banking  and  Finance,  28,  pp.2311-­‐2330.    

Croft,  J.,  ‘Britannia  and  Co-­‐op  merge  into  ‘super-­‐mutual’’,  The  Financial  Times,  21  January  2009.  

Cuevas,  C  and  Fischer,  K  (2006)  ‘Cooperative  financial  institutions:  issues  in  governance,  regulation  and  supervision’,  World  Bank  Working  Paper  No  82.    

Cummings,  T.,  Tam,  H.,  and  Willquist,  C.  (2003)    ‘Seeking  International  Growth’  Bear  Sterns  International  Limited,  2  April  2003.  

Curren,  R.  and  Ryan,  A.  (2008)  ‘Lloyds  TSB  upgrading  to  neutral’,  UBS  Limited,  London  22  September  2008.  

Davidson,  A.  (2001)    ‘The  Andrew  Davidson  interview:  Peter  Ellwood,  Lloyds  TSB's  Chief  Executive’  Management  Today,  1  October  2001  (available  online  at  https://www.managementtoday.co.uk/andrew-­‐davidson-­‐interview-­‐peter-­‐ellwood-­‐lloyds-­‐tsbs-­‐chief-­‐executive/article/407643#rvUOerChLcPlJI0u.99  [accessed  20  September  2017]).  

Dey,  I.  (2009)    ‘Run  nearly  broke  RBS’,  The  Sunday  Times,  4  October  2009.  

Page 170: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  170  

Dodd,  M.  (1932)  ‘For  whom  are  managers  trustees?’,  Harvard  Law  Review,  p1367.  

Douglas,  J.  (2015)  ‘U.K.  Activist  Group  Emerges  as  Voice  for  Monetary  Reform’  The  Wall  Street  Journal,  19  August  2015.  

Down,  R.  (2003a)  ‘Barclays  revenue  story  intact’,  Morgan  Stanley  Dean  Witter,  7  August  2003.  

Down,  R.,  Toeman,  P,  Grinyer,  N.  and  Winton  de,  W.,  (2000)  ‘Lloyds  TSB,  the  changing  dynamic’,  Morgan  Stanley  Dean  Witter,  29  March  2000.    

Down,  R.,  Toeman,  P.  and  Winton  de,  W.  (2003b)    ‘Recovery  won’t  be  easy’  Morgan  Stanley  Dean  Witter,  London  4  August  2003.  

Dul,  J.  and  Hak,  T.  (2008)  Case  study  methodology  in  business  research,  Butterworth-­‐Heineman,  Oxford.  

Eaton,  G.  (2012)  ‘Miliband  backs  a  National  Investment  Bank’,  New  Statesman,  9  July  2012.    

Eccles,  R.  and  Youmans,  T.  (2015)    ‘Materiality  in  corporate  governance:  the  statement  of  significant  audiences  and  materiality’,  Harvard  Business  school,  Working  Paper,  16-­‐023,  15  September  2015.  

Edwards,  P.  (2016)    ‘Corbyn  calls  for  a  new  bank  to  kick-­‐start  era  of  “re-­‐industrialisation”’,  21  May  2016  labour  press  release  (available  at:  http://labourlist.org/2016/05/corbyn-­‐calls-­‐for-­‐a-­‐new-­‐bank-­‐to-­‐kick-­‐start-­‐era-­‐of-­‐re-­‐industrialisation/  [accessed  22.05.17].  

Elgot,  J.  (2016)  ‘Labour  pledges  national  investment  bank  to  mobilise  £500bn’,  The  Guardian,  18  July  2016.  

Elliot,  L.  (2009)  ‘Recapitalize  the  poor  not  just  the  banks,  says  Cameron’,  The  Guardian,  31  January  2009    

Engelen,  E.,  Erturk,  I.,  Froud,  J.,  Johal,  S.,  Lever,  A.,  Moran,  M.,  Nilsson,  A.  and  Williams,  K.  (2011)  After  the  great  complacence:  financial  crisis  and  the  politics  of  reform,  Oxford  University  Press.  

Erskine,  R.,  Firth,  E.,  Straite,  R.  and  Tyce,  J.  (2004)  ‘Lloyds  TSB  Group:  sell’,  Société  Générale  Equity  Research,  13  October  2004.    

Ertürk,  I.  (2015)    ‘Financialization,  bank  business  models  and  the  limits  of  post-­‐crisis  bank  regulation’,  Journal  of  Banking  Regulation  17,  23.  

Fallon,  I  (2015)  Black  Horse  Ride,  the  inside  story  of  Lloyds  and  the  banking  crisis,  Robson  Press,  London.    

Fama,  E.,  and  Jensen,  M.,  (1983)  ‘Separation  of  ownership  and  control’,  Journal  of  Law  and  Economics  26,  pp.301-­‐326.    

Page 171: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  171  

Fergurson,  N  (2008)  The  Ascent  of  Money,  Penguin  Press,  London.  

Ferri,  G.,  Kalmi,  P.  and  Eva,  K.  (2012)  ‘From  shareholders  to  stakeholders  finance:  a  more  sustainable  lending  model’,  International  Journal  of  Sustainable  Economy,  Vol.2,  Issue.3.  

Ferri,  G.,  Kalmi,  P.,  Eeva,  K.  (2010)    Organizational  structure  and  performance  in  European  banks,  advances  in  the  economic  analysis  of  participatory  &  labor-­‐managed  firms,  Emerald  Group  Publishing.    

Financial  Conduct  Authority  (2015)  Final  notice:  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC,  FCA,  London,  10  August  2015.  

Fisher,  I.  (1936)  ‘100%  money  and  the  public  debt’  Economic  Forum,  Spring  pp406-­‐420  

Fletcher,  N.  (2008)    ‘Market  forces:  Lloyds  TSB  pays  price  of  merger  doubts’,  The  Guardian,  19  September  2008.    

Foster,  J.  and  Magdoff,  F.  (2009)  ‘The  great  financial  crisis:  causes  and  consequences’,  NYU  Press,  New  York.  

Friedman,  M.  (1948)  ‘A  Monetary  and  Fiscal  Framework  for  Economic  Stability’  American  Economic  Review  38(3).  

Friedman,  M.  (1962)  Capitalism  and  freedom,  Chicago  Press.  

Friedman,  M.  (1970)  ‘The  Social  Responsibility  of  Business  is  to  Increase  its  Profits’  The  New  York  Times  Magazine.    

FSA  (2012)  Final  Notice  to  Barclays  Bank  PLC,  FSA,  London,  27  June  2012  

FSA  (2013)  Final  Notice:  Lloyds  TSB  Bank  PLC  and  Bank  of  Scotland  plc,  FSA,  London,  10  December  2013.  

Future  of  Banking  Commission  (2010)  The  Future  of  Banking.  Which?  (available  online  at  http://i.telegraph.co.uk/telegraph/multimedia/archive/01656/Bankpdf_1656684a.pdf  [21.09.17]).  

Garside,  J.  (2012)  ‘Angela  Knight  steps  down  as  British  Banker’s  Association  Chief’,  The  Guardian,  2  April  2012.  

Glyn,  A.  (2006)  Capitalism  unleashed,  Oxford  University  Press.  

Goff,  S.  (2014)    ‘Co-­‐op  Bank  slashes  first-­‐half  losses  but  loses  38,000  customers’,  The  Financial  Times,  22  August  2014  

Greene,  G.  (1998)  The  48  Laws  of  Power,  Viking  Press  (HC),  London,  1998    

Grey,  K.  and  Grey,  S.  (2008)  Elements  of  Land  Law,  Oxford  University  Press.  

Page 172: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  172  

Griffiths,  K.  (2002)    ‘City  underwhelmed  as  American  takes  the  helm  at  Lloyds  TSB’,  The  Independent,  21  December  2002.    

H.  M.  Treasury  (2009)  ‘Reforming  the  financial  markets’,  Press  release  47,  Cm7667,  The  Stationary  Office,  London,  July  2009.  

H.  M.  Treasury  (2015)  ‘Government  completes  banking  reforms,  announcement  5  March  2015  (available  at:  https://www.gov.uk/government/news/government-­‐completes-­‐banking-­‐reforms  [accessed  17.11.15]).    

H.M.  Treasury  (2010)  ‘Sir  John  Vickers  to  Chair  the  Independent  Commission  on  Banking’,  announcement  10  June  2010  (available  at:  https://www.gov.uk/government/news/sir-­‐john-­‐vickers-­‐to-­‐chair-­‐the-­‐independent-­‐commission-­‐on-­‐banking  [accessed  on  23.05.17]).    

Hakenes,  H.,  R.H.  Schmidt  and  R.  Xie  (2009)    ‘Public  Banks  and  Regional  Development’,  Journal  of  Financial  Services  Research,  2009.  

Haldane,  A.  (2009)  ‘Rethinking  the  financial  network’  speech  delivered  to  the  Financial  Student  Association  in  Amsterdam  on  28  April  2009,  published  by  the  Bank  of  England.  

Haldane,  A.  (2010)  'The  contribution  of  the  financial  sector  –  miracle  or  mirage?’,  a  speech  given  at  the  Future  of  Finance  conference,  London,  14  July  2010,  published  by  the  Bank  of  England.    

Haldane,  A.  (2011)  ‘Control  rights  (and  wrongs)’,  a  lecture  given  at  the  Wincott  Annual  Memorial  Lecture,  Westminster,  London,  on  24  October  2011,  published  by  the  Bank  of  England.    

Haldane,  A.  (2015)  ‘Who  owns  a  company?’,  a  lecture  given  at  the  University  of  Edinburgh  Corporate  Finance  Conference  in  Edinburg,  on  Friday  22  May  2015,  published  by  the  Bank  of  England.  

Hamel,  J.,  Dufour,  S.,  and  Fortin,  D.  (1993)  Case  study  methods.  Newbury  Park,  CA:  Sage  Publications.    

Hansmann,  H.  (1980)  ‘The  role  of  nonprofit  enterprise’,  Yale  Law  Journal.  

Hansmann,  H.  (1981)  ‘Reforming  non-­‐profit  corporation  law’,  University  of  Pennsylvania  Law  Review  129(3),  pp497-­‐623.  

Hansmann,  H.  (1988)  ‘Ownership  of  the  firm’,  Journal  of  Law,  Economics  and  Organization  4,  pp267-­‐303.    

Hayne,  S  (2008)  ‘Barclays  overhang’,  Morgan  Stanley  Dean  Witter,  26  June  2008.  

Helmke,  G.,    Levitsky,  S.  (2004),  ‘Informal  Institutions  and  Comparative  Politics:  A  Research  Agenda’,  Perspectives  on  Politics,  Vol.  2,  No.  4  (Dec.,  2004),  pp.  725-­‐740,  American  Political  Science  Association    

Page 173: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  173  

Helsby,  M.  and  Willis,  S.  (2002)    ‘Outperformance  since  10  September  simply  looks  wrong’,  ING  Barings,  28  January  2002.  

IMF  (2006)  Global  financial  stability  report,  IMF,  Washington,  April  2006.  

Independent  Commission  on  Banking  (2010a)  ‘Terms  of  reference’,  2010  (available  at  http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130129110402/http://www.hm-­‐treasury.gov.uk/d/banking_commission_terms_of_reference.pdf  [available  21.09.17]).    

Independent  Commission  on  Banking  (2010b)  ‘Issues  paper  publication’,  Domarn  Group,  London,  24  September  2010.  

Independent  Commission  on  Banking  (2011)  Final  report,  Dorman  Group,  London,  September  2011.  

Ireland,  P.  (2007)    ‘Limited  liability,  rights  of  control  and  the  problem  of  corporate  irresponsibility’  paper  published  at  the  corporate  accountability’  Limited  Liability  and  the  Future  of  Globalisation  Conference,  School  of  African  and  Oriental  Studies,  July  2007.  

Ireland,  P.  (2008)  ‘Law  and  the  neoliberal  vision:  pension  privatization,  and  the  ownership  society’,  Northern  Ireland  Law  Quarterly,  62(1),  pp1-­‐31.  

Ireland,  P.  (2009)    ‘Financialization  and  corporate  governance’,  Northern  Ireland  Law  Quarterly  60(1),  pp1-­‐34.  

Jacobs,  M.  and  Mazzucato,  M.  (2016)  Rethinking  Capitalism,  Wiley  Blackwell.  

Jakab,  Z.  and  Sumhof,  M.  (2015)  ‘Banks  are  not  intermediaries  of  loanable  funds  —  and  why  this  matters’,  BoE  Working  Paper,  No.  529,  May  2015.  

Jenkins,  P.,  Jones,  C.,  Groom,  B.  (2013)  ‘Funding  for  Lending  failure  dismays  BoE’,  The  Financial  Times,  19  August  2013.  

Jenson,  M.,  Meckling  (1976)  ‘Theory  of  the  firm:  managerial  behaviour,  agency  costs  and  ownership  structure’,  Journal  of  Financial  Economics  (October),  3(4),  pp.305–360.      

Jones,  R.  (2012)  ‘Co-­‐operative  bank:  how  does  it  compare?’,  The  Guardian,  20  July  2012.  

Jordà,  Ò.,  Chularick,  M.,  Taylor,  A.,  (2014)    ‘The  great  mortgaging:  housing  finance,  crisis  and  business  cycles’  Working  Paper  MIT,  20501.  Cambridge  MA:  National  Bureau  for  Economic  Research.    

Kambo,  G.,  Lever,  M.  and  Pierce,  J.  (2004)  ‘Good  momentum’,  Credit  Suisse,  London,  11  February  2004.  

Kay,  J.  (1995)  Why  firms  succeed,  Oxford  University  Press.  

Page 174: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  174  

Kay,  J.  (2012)  The  Kay  Review  of  UK  equity  markets  and  long-­‐term  decision  making,  HM  Department  for  Business  Innovation  and  Skills,  London,  July  2012.    

Kay,  J.  (2015)  Other  people’s  money,  masters  of  the  universe  or  servants  of  the  people,  Profile  Books,  London.  

Kelly,  D.,  Kelly,  G.,  Gamble,  A.  (2001)  Stakeholder  capitalism,  Palgrave  Macmillan,  Basingstoke.  

Kelly,  C.  (2014)  Failings  in  management  and  governance:  report  of  the  independent  review  into  the  events  leading  to  the  Co-­‐operative  bank’s  capital  shortfall,  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank  PLC,  30  April  2014.  

Kelly,  M.  (2003)  The  divine  right  of  capital:  dethroning  the  corporate  aristocracy,  Berrett-­‐Koehler  Publishers,  San  Francisco.  

Kelly,  M.  (2012)  Owning  our  future:  the  emerging  ownership  revolution,  journeys  to  a  generative  economy,  Berrett-­‐Koehler  Publishers  Inc,  San  Francisco.  

King,  M.  (2016)  The  end  of  alchemy,  Little,  Brown.  

Klein,  N.  (2007)  The  shock  doctrine:  the  rise  of  disaster  capitalism,  Random  House,  Canada.  

Knight,  F.  (1933)  ‘Memorandum  on  banking  reform’  Franklin.  D.  Roosevelt  Presidential  Library,  President’s  personal  file  431.    

Kollewe,  J.  (2017)    ‘Green  Investment  Bank  sell-­‐off  described  as  a  disaster  by  critics’,  the  Guardian,  20  April  2017.  

Kraakman,  R.  and  Hansmann,  H  (2000)  ‘The  end  of  history  for  corporate  law’,  Yale  Law  Journal,  439,  Yale.    

Kuchler,  H.  (2012)    ‘BoE's  Haldane  says  Occupy  was  right’,  Financial  Times.  30  October  2012.  

Labour  Party  (2017)  Manifesto  (available  at  http://www.labour.org.uk/page/-­‐/Images/manifesto-­‐2017/Labour%20Manifesto%202017.pdf.  [accessed  14.09.17]).  

Lankowski,  C.,  (1996)    ‘Financing  intergration:  the  European  Investment  Bank  in  transition’  Law  and  Policy  in  International  Business,  Vol.27,  no.4  (1996)  pp999-­‐1026.  

Lee,  P.  (2008)  ‘LLOYDS  TSB  GROUP  The  dash-­‐for-­‐cash  amongst  UK  banks  comes  full  circle  Hold’,  Société  Général  Equity  Research,  22  September  2008.    

Leigh,  D.  and  Lawrence,  F.  (2009)  ‘New  whistleblower  claims  over  £1bn  Barclays  tax  deals’,  The  Guardian,  19  March  2009.    

Page 175: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  175  

Lever,  M.  and  Pierce,  J.  (2003)    ‘Good  value’,  Credit  Suisse  First  Boston,  13  March  2003.  

Lever,  M.  and  Pierce,  J.  (2004)    ‘Barclays  Capital’,  Credit  Suisse  First  Boston,  11  November  2004.  

Lever,  M.  and  Pierce,  J.,  Raye,  P.  (2005a)  ‘Proposed  acquisition  of  ABSA’,  Credit  Suisse  First  Boston,  10  May  2005.  

Lever,  M.  and  Pierce,  J.,  Raye,  P.  Self,  R.  (2005b)  ‘Wholesale  support’,  Credit  Suisse  First  Boston,  10  May  2005.  

Lord,  N.,  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2004a)  ‘Lloyds  TSB  Group  Hold’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  5  March  2004.  

Lord,  N.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2004b)  ‘Ab(sa)  Fab?’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  24  September  2004.  

Luyendijk,  J  (2015)  Swimming  with  sharks:  my  journey  into  the  world  of  bankers,  Guardian  Faber.    

Macey,  R.  and  O’Hara,  M  (2003)  ‘The  corporate  governance  of  banks’,  Economic  Policy  Review,  Vol.  9,  No.  1,  April  2003.    

Makin  (1998)  ‘First  big  bang,  now  big  brother’,  Institutional  Investor,  May  1988,  pp58-­‐67.    

Mason,  P.  (2015)    ‘The  end  of  capitalism  has  begun’,  The  Guardian,  17  July  2015.  

Mayer,  C.  (2013)  Firm  commitment,  Oxford  University  Press.    

McDonough,  J.  and  McDonough,  S.  (1997)  Research  methods  for  English  language  teachers,  Arnold,  London.  

Mian,  A.  and  Sufi,  A.  (2014)  House  of  debt,  how  they  (and  you)  caused  the  great  recession  and  how  we  can  prevent  it  from  happening  again,  May  2015,  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Minsky,  H.  (1992)  ‘The  financial  instability  hypothesis’,  Levy  Economics  Institute.  

Mollenkamp  (2010)    ‘Probe  circles  globe  to  find  dirty  money’,  The  Wall  Street  Journal,  3  September  2010.  

Monoghan,  A.  (2013)    ‘Lloyds  Banking  Group  timeline:  from  bailout  to  government  sale’,  The  Guardian,  17  September  2013.    

Moran,  M.  (1991)  The  politics  of  the  financial  services  revolution,  Macmillan  Academic  and  Professional  Limited.  

Mount  F.  (2010)  The  new  few:  a  very  British  oligopoly,  Simon  &  Schuster  UK.    

Page 176: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  176  

Murden,  T.  (2008)    ‘Now  is  the  time  for  banks  to  go  bargain  hunting’  Scotland  on  Sunday,  28  February  2008.    

Murray,  A.  (2014)  ‘Nine  problems  that  caused  the  debacle  of  the  Co-­‐operative  bank’  The  News  Co-­‐op,  30  April  2014.  

Muzzucato,  M.  (2013)  The  entrepreneurial  state:  debunking  public  vs.  private  sector  myths,  Anthem  Press,  2013.    

Napier,  J  (2005)  ‘Lloyds  TSB  turning  the  tanker’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  16  November  2005.  

Napier,  J.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2007a)  ‘Barclays  Target  Price  to  850p  Hold’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  4  January  2007.  

NapierJ.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2007b)    ‘Strong  outlook  +  earnings  upgrade’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  20  February  2007.  

Napier,  J.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2007c)  ‘Barclays’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  8  October  2007.  

Napier,  J.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2008a)    ‘Barclays’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  7  February  2008.  

Napier,  J.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2008b)    ‘Barclays’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  19  February  2008.  

Napier,  J.  and  Sheridon,  J.  (2008c)    ‘Barclays’,  Deutsche  Bank  A  G,  London,  15  May  2008.  

Nationwide  (2016):  http://www.nationwide.co.uk/about/corporate-­‐information/our-­‐history#xtab:g-­‐p  [accessed  18.05.16]).  

Nationwide  (2017)  ‘Core  Capital  Deferred  Shares’,  Nationwide  (available  at  http://www.nationwide.co.uk/about/investor-­‐relations/funding-­‐programmes/ccds-­‐market-­‐data-­‐and-­‐investor-­‐information  [accessed  14.09.17]).  

Neate,  R.  (2013)  ‘Co-­‐operative  Bank  rushes  to  reassure  customers  after  downgrade’,  The  Guardian,  5  May  2013.  

New  Economics  Foundation  (2012)  ‘Where  does  money  come  from?,  the  New  Economics  Foundation,  12  December  2012  (available  at  http://neweconomics.org/2012/12/where-­‐does-­‐money-­‐come-­‐from/  [accessed  on  30.05.17]).  

Nissan,  S  and  Spratt,  S.  (2009)  ‘The  Ecology  of  Finance  -­‐  An  Alternative  White  Paper  on  Banking  and  Financial  Sector  Reform’,  New  Economics  Foundation,  London.    

Page 177: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  177  

Nordic  Investment  Bank  (2017)  ‘Member  countries'  guarantees  for  environmental  investment  loans  and  environmental  investment  guarantees’(available  at:  https://www.nib.int/MIL  [accessed  14.09.17]).  

O’Donohoe  (2014)  ‘Big  Capital  Society  is  showing  how  successful  social  investment  can  be’,  the  Guardian,  30  April  2014.  

O’Hara,  M.  (1981)  ‘Property  rights  and  the  financial  firm’,  Journal  of  Law  and  Economics  29,  pp317-­‐332.  

Osborne,  H  (2013)    ‘PPI  –  facts  and  figures  from  the  'biggest  mis-­‐selling’,  The  Guardian,  4  March  2013.    

Osterwalder,  A.,  Pigneur,  Y.  (2009)  Business  Model  Generation:  a  handbook  for  visionaries,  Modderman  Druckwerk  

Paletta,  D  (2010)  ‘Law  Remakes  U.S.  Financial  Landscape’.  Wall  Street  Journal,  16  July  2010.      

Parkinson,  J.  (1993)    Corporate  power  and  responsibility:  issues  in  the  theory  of  company  law  Clarendon,  London.  

Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  (2013a)  Changing  banking  for  good,  Volume  I,  HL  27/1  175/1,  29  June  2013.  

Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  (2013b)  Changing  banking  for  good,  Volume  II,  HL  27/I  HC  175/II,  29  June  2013.    

Parliamentary  Commission  on  Banking  Standards  (2014)  ‘Statement  of  Former  Members’,  House  of  Commons,  London,  4  November  2014.  

Patel,  V.  and  Sage,  R.  (2007)  ‘Outperform’,  Bear  Sterns  International  Limited,  London,  23  February,  2007.  

Pickett,  K  (2009)  The  spirit  level:  why  more  equal  societies  almost  always  do  better,  Allen  Lane.  

Picketty,  T.  (2014)  Capital  in  the  twenty-­‐first  century,    Harvard  University  Press,  2014.  

Porter,  M.  (1992)    Capital  Disadvantage:  America’s  Failing  Capital  Investment  System,  Harvard  Business  Review  October  1992.  

Preston,  R.  (2001)    ‘Brian  Pitman  steps  down’  the  Sunday  Times,  28  October  2001.  

Preston,  R.  (2010)  ‘What  Sir  Brian  Pitman  can  teach  today’s  bankers’,  The  BBC,  15  March  2010  (available  at  :  http://www.bbc.co.uk/blogs/thereporters/robertpeston/2010/03/what_sir_brian_pitman_can_teac.html.  [accessed  21.09.17]).  

Page 178: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  178  

Preston,  R.  (2012)    How  do  we  fix  this  mess?,  Hodder  &  Stoughton  Ltd.  

Ralph,  B  (2012)  ‘Catching  a  frisbee  is  difficult:  the  Bank  of  England  tells  it  like  it  is’,  Forbes,  22  October  2012.  

Rasmusen,  E.  (1988)  ‘Mutual  banks  and  stock  banks’  Journal  of  Law  and  Economics  31,  pp.395-­‐421.    

Reid,  M.  (1988)  All-­‐change  in  the  City:  the  revolution  in  Britain’s  financial  sector,  Macmillan.  

Robbins,  M.  (2009)    ‘Was  ABN  the  worst  takeover  deal  ever?’,  The  Independent,  20  January  2009.    

Salz,  A.  (2013)  Salz  Review  :  An  independent  review  of  Barclays  Business  Practices,  Barclays  Bank  PLC,  London,  April  2013.  

Saunders,  M.,  Lewis,  P.,  &  Thornhill,  A.  (2007),  Research  Methods  for  Business  Students,  (6th  ed.)  Pearson  

Schäfer,  D.  (2013)    ‘Diamond  misjudged  public  anger  over  bankers’,  The  Financial  Times,  2  May  2013  

Schopenhauer  (2004)  The  art  of  always  being  right,  Gibson  Square  Books  Ltd,  London  2004.    

Scuffham,  M.  (2014)    ‘UK's  Co-­‐op  Bank  completes  400  million  pound  fundraising’,  Reuters,  10  May  2014.  

Simons,  H  (1936)  ‘Rules  versus  authorities  in  monetary  policy’  Journal  of  Political  Economy  44(1),  pp1-­‐30.  

Skidalsky,  R  (2011)  ‘For  a  National  Investment  Bank’,  New  York  Review  of  Books,  30  March  2011.  

Soddy,  Frederick  (1926):  Wealth,  Virtual  Wealth  and  Debt:  The  Solution  of  the  Economic  Paradox.  London:  George  Allen  &  Unwin.    

Stone,  R  (2016)  ‘Owen  Smith  has  adopted  Jeremy  Corbyn's  policies’,  Independent,  27  July  2016.  

Strange,  S.  (1986)  Casino  Capitalism,  Blackwell,  1986.  

Strange,  S.  (1988)  States  and  Markets,  Blackwell,  1988.  

Summers,  D.  (2008)  ‘No  return  to  boom  and  bust:  what  Brown  said  when  he  was  chancellor’,  The  Guardian,  11  September  2008.  

Talbot,  L.  (2010)    ‘Of  insane  forms,  from  collectives  to  management  controlled  organisations  to  shareholder  value  organisations:  building  societies  a  case  study’,  Journal  of  Banking  Regulation,  Vol.11  (No.3)  2010.  

Page 179: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  179  

Talbot,  L.  (2013)  ‘Why  shareholders  shouldn’t  vote:  a  Marxist  progressive  critique  of  shareholder  empowerment’,  The  Modern  Law  Review  76(5)  September  2013.  

Tellis,  W.  (1997)  ‘Introduction  to  case  study’,  The  Qualitative  Report,  Volume  3,  Number  2,  July  1997  (available  at  :  http://www.nova.edu/ssss/QR/QR3-­‐2/tellis1.html  [accessed  01.08.16]).    

The  Co-­‐operative  Bank  (2009),  Financial  Statements:  Support  in  the  Community,  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  Manchester.    

The  Co-­‐operative  Bank  (2010)  Annual  Report,  the  Co-­‐operative  Bank,  Manchester.  

The  Cooperative  Financial  Services  (2010),  Financial  statements  2010,  The  Cop-­‐operative  Financial  Services,  Manchester.  

The  Cooperative  Financial  Services  (2011),  Statement  to  the  company  announcements  office  2011,  the  Co-­‐operative  Financial  Services,  Manchester.  

The  Guardian  (2002)  ‘This  time,  Nestlé  really  takes  the  biscuit’,  The  Guardian,  London,  21  December  2002.  

The  Guardian,  ‘How  Britain  fell  out  of  love  with  the  free  market’,  The  Guardian,  4  August  2017.  

The  Ownership  Commission  (2012),  ‘plurality,  stewardship  &  engagement’,  Mutuo,  April  2012.  

The  Oxford  Centre  for  Mutual  &  Employee-­‐owned  Business  (2009)    ‘Converting  failed  financial  institutions  into  mutual  organisations’,  Policy  and  Issue  Reports,  Kellogg  College,  University  of  Oxford  (available  online:  http://www.kellogg.ox.ac.uk/wp-­‐content/uploads/2015/11/Converting-­‐financial-­‐institutions-­‐into-­‐mutual-­‐organisations.pdf  [accessed  21.09.17]).    

The  Panel  on  Takeovers  and  Mergers  (2006),  The  Takeover  Code  (8th  Ed),  The  Panel  on  Takeovers  and  Mergers,  London.  

Thomas,  G.  (2011)  How  to  do  your  case  study:  a  guide  for  students  and  researchers,  Thousand  Oaks,  CA:  Sage.  

Tisher,  M.  (2009)  Capitalist  realism:  is  there  no  alternative?,  O  Books,  2009.  

Tomlinson,  L.  (2013)  Banks’  lending  practices:  treatment  of  businesses  in  distress,  Department  for  Business  and  Innovation,  25  November  2013.  

Treanor,  J.  (2010a)    ‘Barclays  boss  could  get  £60m’,  The  Guardian,  19  March  2010.    

Treanor,  J.  (2010b)    ‘Barclays  confirms  Bob  Diamond  as  new  chief’,  The  Guardian,  20  September  2010.  

Page 180: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  180  

Treanor,  J  (2013a)    ‘Bob  Diamond:  I  wasn’t  in  it  for  the  money’,  The  Guardian,  2  March  2013.  

Treanor,  J  (2013b)    ‘Questions  were  already  being  asked  about  Paul  Flowers's  credentials’,  The  Guardian,  18  November  2013.  

Treanor,  J.  (2014a)    ‘Co-­‐operative  Group's  terrible  year  leads  to  growth  slowing  in  wider  movement’,  The  Guardian,  22  June  2014.  

Treanor,  J  (2014b)    ‘Lloyds  suspends  seven  people  after  £226m  bill  for  rigging  interest  rates’,  The  Guardian,  28  July  2014.    

Treanor,  J.,  (2015)    ‘UK's  big  four  banks  face  extra  £19bn  in  fines,  analysts  predict’,  The  Guardian,  27  April  2015.    

Treanor,  J  (2016)  ‘Competition  watchdog  criticised  by  MPs  over  bank  reform’,  The  Guardian,  2  November  2016.  

Treanor,  J.  (2017)  ‘HBOS  compensation  chief  criticised  by  Noel  Edmonds  insists  he  is  independent’,  The  Guardian  26  September  2017.  

Treasury  Committee  (2008a)    The  Run  on  the  Rock,  HC  52  26  January  2008.    

Treasury  Committee  (2008b)  ‘Treasury  Committee  outlines  terms  of  reference  for  inquiry  into  the  banking  crisis  and  calls  for  evidence’,  press  notice  85  of  2008  (available  at  :  http://www.parliament.uk/business/committees/committees-­‐archive/treasury-­‐committee/tc0708pn85/  [accessed  on  3  November  2016]).    

Treasury  Committee  (2009a)  Banking  crisis:  the  impact  and  failure  of  Icelandic  banks,  HC  402,  4  April  2009.      

Treasury  Committee  (2009b)  Banking  Crisis:  dealing  with  the  failure  of  the  UK  banks,  HC  416,  1  May  2009.        

Treasury  Committee  (2009c)  Banking  Crisis:  reforming  corporate  governance  and  pay  in  the  City,  HC  519,  15  May  2009.    

Treasury  Committee  (2009d)  Banking  crisis:  international  dimensions,  HC  615,  24  July  2009.  

Treasury  Committee  (2009e)    Banking  Crisis:  regulation  and  supervision  HC  767  31  July  2009.  

Treasury  Committee  (2010)  Too  important  to  fail–too  important  to  ignore’  HC  216-­‐I  22  March  2010.  

Treasury  Committee  (2011)    Competition  and  choice  in  retail  banking’  HC  612-­‐I,  24  March  2011.      

Treasury  Committee  (2012a)    The  Financial  Conduct  Authority,  HC  1574  13  January  2012.  

Page 181: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  181  

Treasury  Committee  (2012b)  Fixing  LIBOR:  some  preliminary  findings:  second  report  of  second  session  2012-­‐2013,  Treasury  Select  Committee,  HC  481-­‐1  Standing  Order  137,  2012.  

Treasury  Committee  (2014),  Report  on  Project  Verde,  Treasury  Select  Committee,  23  October  2014.  

Treasury  Select  Committee  (2012)  Lord  Turner’s  evidence  to  the  Treasury  Select  Committee,  Treasury  Select  Committee,  London,  29  July  2012.  

Tremlet,  G.  (2012)  ‘Spain's  savings  banks'  culture  of  greed,  cronyism  and  political  meddling’,  The  Guardian,  8  June  2012  

Trotman,  A.  (2012)  ‘Lloyds  sells  632  branches  to  Co-­‐op  for  £1.25bn  less  than  hoped  for’,  The  Daily  Telegraph,  19  July  2012  

Turner,  A.  (2010)  The  future  of  finance:  the  LSE  report,  London  School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science.    

Turner,  A.  (2016)    Between  Debt  and  the  Devil,  Princeton  University  Press  

Tyrie,  A.  (2014)    ‘the  Co-­‐op  has  been  derailed  by  the  wrong  kind  of  bankers’,  The  Daily  Telegraph,  8  November  2014  

Veblen,  T.  (1904)  The  theory  of  business  enterprise,  Charles  Scribner's  Sons:  New  York.  

Veblen,  T.  (1923)  Absentee  ownership  and  business  enterprise  in  recent  times:  the  case  of  America,  B.  W.  Huebsch:  New  York    

Wapshott,  N.  (2012)  Keynes  Hayek,  the  clash  that  defined  modern  economics,  Norton  &  Company  Inc,  New  York  

Warner,  J.  (2008)    ‘With  HBOS  under  renewed  attack,  forced  takeover  may  be  the  solution’,  The  Independent,  17  September  2008    

Warwick  Commission  (2009)  The  Warwick  Commission  on  International  Financial  Reform:  In  Praise  of  Unlevel  Playing  Fields,  the  University  of  Warwick,  Warwick,  27  November  2009.    

Weardon,  G.  (2009)    ‘Nationwide  attacks  government  savings  compensation  scheme  after  £250m  bill’  The  Guardian,  20  March  2009    

Weardon,  G.  (2011)  ‘How  the  PPI  saga  unfolded’  The  Guardian,  5  May  2011  

Weyer,  M.  (2000)  Falling  Eagle:  the  decline  of  Barclays  Bank,  The  Orion  Publishing  Group  Ltd.    

White,  D.  (2008)  ‘Dust  needs  to  settle  before  Lloyds  deal  shows  worth’,  The  Daily  Telegraph,  19  September  2008      

Page 182: Bankingreform,!andthe importanceofownership:! how ...

  182  

Wigley,  B.  (2008)  London:  winning  in  a  changing  world,  December  2008,  Merrill  Lynch  Europe  Limited.  

Williams,  R.  (2014)  Keywords:  a  vocabulary  of  culture  and  society,  Fourth  Estate,  London.  

Wilkinson,  M.  (2005)  Contractual  conditionality  –  the  powers  of  the  European  Investment  Bank  in  practice  and  in  theory,  LLM  thesis  presented  to  the  College  of  Europe,  Bruges,  2005.  

Wilson,  H.  (2012)    ‘Barclays  hit  with  £290m  fine  over  Libor  fixing’,  The  Daily  Telegraph,  27  June  2012.      

Wolf,  M.  (2012),  ‘Comment  on  Andrew  G  Haldane,  “Control  rights  (and  wrongs)”,  Wincott  Annual  Memorial  Lecture,  24th  October  2011’  (available  online  at:  www.wincott.co.uk/lectures/Wolf_comment_on_Haldane_Lecture.doc  [accessed  24.09.17]).  

Wolf,  M.  (2014a)    ‘Financial  reform:  call  to  arms’,  The  Financial  Times,  3  September  2014.  

Wolf,  M.  (2014b)  ‘Strip  private  banks  of  their  power  to  create  money’,  The  Financial  Times,  24  April  2014.  

Wolf,  M.  (2014c)  The  shifts  and  the  shocks:  what  we've  learned-­‐-­‐and  have  still  to  learn-­‐-­‐from  the  financial  crisis  Penguin  Press,  Allen  Lane.  

Yin,  R.  and  Moore,  G.  (1987)  ‘The  use  of  advanced  technologies  in  special  education’,  Journal  of  Learning  Disabilities,  20(1)  p60.    

Yin,  R.  (1984)  Case  study  research:  design  and  methods  (1st  Ed.)  Beverly  Hills,  California:  Sage  Publications.  

Yin,  R.  (1994)  Case  study  research:  Design  and  methods  (2nd  Ed.)    Beverly  Hills,  California,  Sage  Publications.    

Yin,  R.  (2014)  Case  sudy  research:  design  and  methods.  (5th  Ed).  Thousand  Oaks,  California,  Sage  Publications.