Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional...

38
Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to Social Security and Welfare Policy DOI 10.1515/rle-2014-0005 Published online January 26, 2016 Abstract: In this paper we construct an index of constitutional commitment to social security (CCSS) in seven areas: Old Age, Survivors, Disability, Unemployment, Sickness, Work Injury, and Income Support. We have found a positive connection between our measure of constitutional commitment to social security and the extent and coverage of actual measures of social security laws. The constitutional text of each nation seems to play a role in explaining the large variations in welfare state coverage around the world. Key words: welfare policy, social security, social rights, constitution 1 Introduction The share of spending on social security varies considerably around the world. Even advanced countries exhibit significant variation in such social insurance policies as old-age pensions, unemployment insurance, and work injury com- pensation. In 2010, Denmark spent 25.4 % of GDP (the highest) on social protec- tion expenditures, while in South Korea (the lowest) it was only 3.8 % of GDP (OECD.stat). The academic effort to explain this observed large difference in redistribu- tion policy spans political science, economics and sociology. Three main the- ories are offered to account for the variability. According to the Power Resource approach, the cross-country variation in social policy is explained by conflict between various social groups. Countries with left-wing ruling parties and powerful labor unions tend to have a highly developed welfare state as com- pared to countries with rightist political parties in governing coalitions (Korpi, 1983, 1989; Esping-Andersen, 1990; Hicks et al., 1995; Korpi and Palme, 1998; Bradley et al., 2003). *Corresponding author: Momi Dahan, School of Public Policy, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Jerusalem, Israel; Israel Democracy Institute, Jerusalem, Israel, E-mail: [email protected] Avi Ben-Bassat, Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Jerusalem, Israel; Hamaslool Haakademi Shel Hamichlala Leminhal, Isreal, E-mail: [email protected] Rev. Law Econ. 2016; 12(1): 165201

Transcript of Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional...

Page 1: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan*

Constitutional Commitment to SocialSecurity and Welfare Policy

DOI 10.1515/rle-2014-0005Published online January 26, 2016

Abstract: In this paper we construct an index of constitutional commitmentto social security (CCSS) in seven areas: Old Age, Survivors, Disability,Unemployment, Sickness, Work Injury, and Income Support. We have found apositive connection between our measure of constitutional commitment to socialsecurity and the extent and coverage of actual measures of social security laws.The constitutional text of each nation seems to play a role in explaining thelarge variations in welfare state coverage around the world.

Key words: welfare policy, social security, social rights, constitution

1 Introduction

The share of spending on social security varies considerably around the world.Even advanced countries exhibit significant variation in such social insurancepolicies as old-age pensions, unemployment insurance, and work injury com-pensation. In 2010, Denmark spent 25.4% of GDP (the highest) on social protec-tion expenditures, while in South Korea (the lowest) it was only 3.8% of GDP(OECD.stat).

The academic effort to explain this observed large difference in redistribu-tion policy spans political science, economics and sociology. Three main the-ories are offered to account for the variability. According to the Power Resourceapproach, the cross-country variation in social policy is explained by conflictbetween various social groups. Countries with left-wing ruling parties andpowerful labor unions tend to have a highly developed welfare state as com-pared to countries with rightist political parties in governing coalitions (Korpi,1983, 1989; Esping-Andersen, 1990; Hicks et al., 1995; Korpi and Palme, 1998;Bradley et al., 2003).

*Corresponding author: Momi Dahan, School of Public Policy, The Hebrew University ofJerusalem, Jerusalem, Israel; Israel Democracy Institute, Jerusalem, Israel,E-mail: [email protected] Ben-Bassat, Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Jerusalem,Israel; Hamaslool Ha’akademi Shel Hamichlala Leminhal, Isreal, E-mail: [email protected]

Rev. Law Econ. 2016; 12(1): 165–201

Page 2: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Alesina et al. (2001) provide a somewhat similar argument, and claim thatrace fragmentation or conflict is a major reason for the observed differences inwelfare states between the two sides of the Atlantic. Voters will support awelfare state if they believe that low income is the result of circumstancesoutside the power of individuals and they will dislike redistribution if it isperceived as a consequence of lack of effort, mainly by an individual fromanother race.

The Logic of Industrialism, which is associated with Wilensky (1975), isanother significant approach in explaining why some countries redistributemore than others. Several studies have shown that those countries with higherGDP per capita and a larger share of elderly population account for part or mostof the cross-country differences in the generosity of social programs (Hicks,1999; Huber and Stephens, 2001; Swank, 2002).

A third approach examines the role of political institutions such as electoralsystems and constitutional veto points.1 The constitutional structure has beenused quite extensively in this strand of the literature to explore how politicalinstitutions affect differences in welfare state coverage.2 Huber et al. (1993) werethe first to find a strong effect of constitutional structure on welfare state effort.One of the main focuses of their work was on the degree to which specialinterests or veto players can block or delay legislation.

In a more recent paper, Iversen and Soskice (2006) argue that central partiesare likely to form a coalition with left-wing parties in proportional representationsystems, implying more redistribution, while in majoritarian systems centralparties are expected to join the right for coalition partners, meaning lowerredistribution. A central result of their paper is that countries with proportionalrepresentation systems redistribute more than countries with majoritarian sys-tems. They also found that the number of constitutional veto points tends toreduce the degree of income redistribution.3 The implication of this result is thatthe constitutional text has more than a declarative role in the development ofthe welfare state.

1 The Veto Points measure is a composite index of federalism, presidentialism, electoralsystem, bicameralism, and the frequency of referenda.2 There is also extensive literature on the consequences of electoral rules and forms ofgovernment as outlined in the constitution on economic policy outcomes. For example,Persson and Tabellini (2004) found that constitutional rules have a significant effect on bothkey fiscal policies and corruption. See Persson and Tabellini’s (2003) book for an excellentsurvey of the empirical evidence.3 See also Congleton and Bose (2010) and Bradley et al. (2003) who also use constitutionalstructure as a key variable to explain the development of the welfare state.

166 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 3: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

While constitutional structure has been used to analyze the impact ofpolitical institutions, the constitutional text regarding social security rights isalmost completely overlooked. That is probably because of a lack of comparativedata on the degree of constitutional commitment to social rights. In order toexamine the effect of constitutional rights on redistribution policy we haveconstructed new indices of the degree of constitutional commitment to sevenfeatures of social security.

The goal of this paper is to explore whether the constitutional text regardingsocial security rights plays a role in shaping social security policy. Ben-Bassatand Dahan (2008) found a positive relationship between the degree of constitu-tional commitment to social security and transfer payments. However, thatpositive association should be seen as a reduced form result. The currentstudy examines the channel through which social rights impact social expendi-tures, i. e., the laws that specify the social programs, the entitled populations,and their coverage. We study here whether social security rights have an effecton actual measures of social security laws.

A society’s preferences are expected to shape social policy and one possiblepolitical mechanism is to express those preferences in a country’s constitution.Most countries include the first generation of rights in their constitution (civicand political rights), but they differ significantly in the scope and degree ofcommitment to social rights. In some countries there is not even a mention ofsocial rights in the constitution.

Whatever pressures are exerted on redistribution policy, they are filteredthrough the constitutional text. The capacity of a government to change socialpolicy is affected by the degree of constitutional commitment to social rights andwhether that commitment is binding in practice. The constitution may functionas a mere statement of social preferences, or it may work as a guardian of thosepreferences.4

In a heterogeneous society, a gap between social rights that have beenentrenched in the past and the current desired social policy is likely to emergeover time. Given such a gap, the current decision makers, that represent certaingroup(s), may decide to comply with the constitution in spite of that gap toavoid future retaliation by other social groups when they assume politicalpower. Due to this tit-for-tat strategy, we expect to find positive relationsbetween constitutional social rights and social security policy. That relationdepends also on the balance of power between the executive, the judiciary

4 Dahan and Strawczynski (2013) show that a change in the composition of governmentexpenditures is less likely to occur as a result of fiscal rules (expenditure cap) if the constitutionis a binding tool.

Constitutional Commitment 167

Page 4: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

system, domestic institutions and international organizations. While constitu-tional veto points may grant small groups or special interests a legal device toblock redistributive legislation, constitutional social rights might play the oppo-site role and make it harder to consolidate welfare expenditures.5

The two main contributions of this paper are the following. First, we find thatconstitutionally enumerated social security rights may account (partially) for theobserved cross-country variation in social security policy. Second, our analysiscontributes to the empirical literature on the efficacy of de jure constitutionalrights. While this literature examines the effectiveness of entrenching human rightsin the constitution on the observed rights in practice,6 our paper focuses on theeffects of constitutional social security rights on actual social security policy.

In the next section we present a conceptual framework that sketches therelationship between constitutional social rights and welfare policy, and in thesubsequent section we describe the criteria used to translate the constitutional textinto quantitative indices that reflect an individual nation’s constitutional commit-ment to social security. In Section 4 we look at the effect of constitutional text onthe extent and coverage of social security laws. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2 A conceptual framework: why mightthe constitution matter

This section presents a conceptual framework that may help to clarify the condi-tions under which the entrenchment of social rights in a constitution affects socialpolicy in practice. The analysis here is based on cost/benefit considerations thatan executive branch may have while deciding on whether economic and socialpolicy should be consistent with the constitutional commitment to social rights.The preferences of voters and countries may differ regarding the desired level ofsocial security, and those differences may be translated into various levels ofconstitutional commitment to social security rights.

5 In fact, Jensen (2009) shows that the degree of sudden changes in welfare policy dependspartly on the institutional friction in a given country.6 The general picture that emerges from this literature is that de jure human rights areineffective against state repression (Pritchard 1986; Blasi and Cingranelli 1996; Davenport,1996; Cross 1999; Keith 2002; Keith et al., 2009; Powel and Staton, 2009; Hafner-Burton et al.2011). In contrast, recently Melton (2012) has shown that entrenching a human right in theconstitution can significantly improve the likelihood that a country will comply with that rightin practice. See also Law and Versteeg (2013) who documented the prevalence of constitutionalnoncompliance around the world over the last three decades.

168 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 5: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

It is more likely that those societies which attribute higher value to socialequality/insurance considerations would tend to take more risks associated withthe entrenchment of social rights in the constitution while others would prefer toexclude those rights from their constitutions. Countries that choose to includesocial rights in their constitution may favor a general statement that expressestheir genuine hopes and aspirations with respect to the desired level of socialsecurity. In contrast to political and civil rights, the constitution might stateexplicitly that social rights should be within the limits of its economic capacityand development.

The alternative model of social rights entrenchment is the pragmatic model,according to which the inclusion of social rights in the constitution in concreteterms is considered to be a tool to shape social and economic policy in practice.7

The expectation is that constitutional social rights would be perceived as amoral guide for policy makers in the conduct of present and, more importantly,future social policy. According to this constitutional model, the role of theconstitution is to limit the capacity of future governments to make significantchanges in social programs that are not in line with central values based on abare and transient majority.

The underlying assumption of both the pragmatic and (to a lesser extent)symbolic models is that policy makers will comply with the constitutional texteven if there is a gap between the desired economic policy and the constitution.In a heterogeneous society, the desired redistribution policy is inherentlyunstable, and this instability may be translated into frequent shifts in politicalpower.8 Therefore, the more fragmented the society is, the higher the probabilityof a gap between social rights that have been entrenched in the past and thecurrent desired social policy. This potential gap between political power and thedesired social policy is particular to social rights.

Given such a gap, decision makers may follow one of three policy options:compliance, noncompliance or a change of the constitution. The current policymakers, representing certain social groups, may choose to comply with theconstitution in spite of that gap in order to avoid future retaliation by othersocial groups when they assume political power. As explained in Ordeshook(1992), the likelihood of use of a tit-for-tat strategy that may yield a mutuallydesired equilibrium (compliance with the constitution) is increased by publiciz-ing the constitutional limits. The specified social rights provide concrete

7 We follow here the typology used by Sunstein (2005) who explains why the Americanconstitution lacks social rights.8 We recommend reading the section on redistributive politics in Ordeshook (1992) whichelaborates on the expected unstable outcome.

Constitutional Commitment 169

Page 6: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

standards against which social policy can be assessed by other parties. Thepotential retaliation, in cases where the current ruling power has deviated fromthe constitutional limits (i. e., social rights), works as a self-generating incentiveto comply. Thus, the constitution serves as a coordination device, as suggestedby Hardin (1989), Przeworski (1991), Ordeshook (1992), Weingast (1997), Carey(2000), and Elkins et al. (2009).

We should expect positive relationships between social security rights in theconstitution and social security policy if indeed the constitution works as acoordination device. This is our central testable hypothesis. However, it is anopen empirical question that will be addressed in the empirical section whetherthe degree of constitutional commitment to social security rights or the mereexistence of social rights in the constitution plays a role in explaining thevariation in social security policy around the world. While the first shouldlead to a linear effect, the latter implies a nonlinear impact.

In addition, the likelihood of compliance or noncompliance depends on theactual balance of power between the executive, the judiciary system, domesticinstitutions and international organizations. Unlike negative rights, such as thefreedom of expression, it is less clear what constitutes noncompliance withregard to constitutional commitment to social rights. The question of who isgranted the authority to interpret the constitution becomes very important withgreater ambiguity. Policy makers would be more reluctant to deviate from theconstitution if they expected that this inconsistency would likely be brought tocourt. We hypothesize that the positive relations between de jure social rights andactual social policy would be enhanced by constitutional review.

To avoid the risk of shifting the decision making from the executive to thecourts, some countries rule out judicial review. The potential large budgetaryimplications and the uncertainty of what constitutes a constitutional violationare two unique features of social rights that generate such risk. For example, anadditional significant budget dedicated to one activity (for example, health) as aresult of a court order must come at the expense of other items (for example, lawand order) or be financed by a rise in taxes.

In the absence of constitutional review, the incentives for the executive todeviate from the constitution depend more heavily on local non-governmentalorganizations and international institutions to the extent that they are respectedby the general public.9 These institutions need the help of a free press to providepublic coverage in the event of any alleged inconsistency between policy and thewritten constitution. We expect that the stronger these organizations are, the higherthe expected positive correlation between social security rights and social policy.

9 See Epp (1998) for the importance of NGOs in promoting a rights revolution.

170 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 7: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

In addition to compliance and noncompliance, policy makers may choose toamend the constitution to accommodate a shift in social preferences (or politi-cians’ interests). The odds of this policy choice increase the lower are thepolitical costs of constitution amendment. Therefore, we expect a larger positivecorrelation between social policy and constitutional commitment to social securityrights if the costs of amendment are low.

To summarize, the likelihood of effective constitutional social rights is posi-tively related to the degree of judicial independence, the ease of amendment andthe power of NGOs and international organizations. In our empirical analysis wealso test the previous three hypotheses by incorporating interactions between theabove variables and constitutional commitment to social security rights. The actualextent and coverage of social security in practice depends on other importantfactors that were alluded to in the introduction, such as the level of economicdevelopment, demographic composition, and political orientation and institutions.

3 Indices of constitutional commitmentto social security

3.1 Constructing constitutional commitmentto social security (CCSS)

In this section we construct constitutional indices of social security rights basedon formal constitutions, and ignoring court review. Our dataset consists of 68countries where 64 countries have a formal written constitution and four have alegal document with a superior standing to that of ordinary law. In Canada, NewZealand and Israel there are basic laws that have a legal status like that of aconstitution. England does not have basic laws, but it does have a Human RightsAct that has superior status to that of ordinary law.10 The dataset covers allcountries with English translations of their constitution that appeared in the ICLand Confinder web sites in the year 2003, which is the time our research projecton social rights started.

A constitutional social security right is defined as one that gives a personalentitlement to financial benefits and such right may impact individuals’ welfare.

10 From Section 3 in the English Human Rights Act it can be inferred that ordinary laws aresubject to the Human Rights Act. Any law should be examined in the light of the Human RightsAct. In case a suggested law is in contradiction to the Human Rights Act, the law may still bepassed, provided the parliament is aware of this.

Constitutional Commitment 171

Page 8: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Social security rights aim to provide social insurance and may have a positiveeffect on income inequality. We cover here seven constitutional rights related tosocial security policy where the first three represent core social security programs:1. Old Age2. Survivors of deceased workers3. Disability4. The right to live in dignity, usually expressed by income support to the poor5. Unemployment insurance6. Sickness insurance7. Work injury insurance

There is sizeable variation in the degree of constitutional commitment to socialsecurity rights, ranging from detailed policy instructions in certain countries to ageneral statement indicating a fuzzy commitment in others. We rank the degreeof constitutional commitment for each feature of social security on a scale from0 to 3, with a rank of 0 denoting a right that is absent from the constitution.

A rank of 1 is set if the constitution contains a general statement regarding acertain social security right. In such cases it is clear that it is possible tointroduce a law concerning that right. A country is given a rank of 2 if theconstitution promises a minimal level with wording like “a minimum standardof living,” or “a life of dignity,” in the case of income support and “adequateinsurance” in the case of unemployment. A score of 3 is given if the constitutionspecifies a detailed social security right. For example, a commitment “to main-tain the real value” of social security benefits justifies a rank of 3 (Table 1).

Table 1: Criteria for ranking the constitutional commitment to old age, survivors and disability(OASDI).

rank

The right is absent from the constitution

General statementThe state “guarantees” or “promotes” social security insurance, or “every personis entitled to social security”

Weak commitmentOld aged, disabled and survivors are entitled to a “minimum standard of living,”“basic income,” “adequate income” or “to live in dignity”

Strong commitmentIn addition to the guarantee of “adequate income,” the constitution specifies theelements of what is adequate income in terms of food, housing etc., or a periodicadjustment mechanism such as COLA.

172 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 9: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

We employ two summary measures to represent the degree of constitutionalcommitment to social security. First, a simple average of the seven features ofsocial security rights, and second a subset of the three core characteristics ofsocial security: a simple average rank of Old Age, Survivors and Disability(OASDI). The constitutional commitment to all social security rights was rankedaccording to these criteria and the dataset for each characteristic is presented inTable 2.

Table 2: Indices of constitutional commitment to social security.

Summaryindex ofSocial

Security

IncomeSupport

Unemployment Sickness WorkInjury

OldAge

Survivors Disability

Albania .

Argentina .

Australia

Austria

Bahrain .

Belgium .

Bolivia .

Brazil

Bulgaria .

Cameroon

Canada

Chile .

China .

Colombia .

Cyprus .

Czech Republic

Denmark .

Dominican Republic .

Ecuador .

Egypt .

El Salvador .

Fiji

Finland .

France .

Germany

Greece

Hungary .

Iceland .

India .

Indonesia

Iran .

Ireland .

Israel

(continued )

Constitutional Commitment 173

Page 10: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table 2: (continued )

Summaryindex ofSocial

Security

IncomeSupport

Unemployment Sickness WorkInjury

OldAge

Survivors Disability

Italy .

Japan .

Jordan

Kenya

Malta .

Mexico .

Nepal .

Netherlands .

New Zealand

Nicaragua .

Norway

Panama .

Paraguay .

Philippines

Poland .

Portugal

Romania .

Sierra Leone .

Singapore

South Africa .

South Korea .

Spain

Sri Lanka

Sweden .

Switzerland .

Syria .

Taiwan .

Thailand

Trinidad

Tunisia .

Turkey .

United Kingdom

United States

Uruguay .

Zambia

Mean . . . . . . . .

Standard deviation . . . . . . . .

No. of countrieswith positivevalue

Mean for countrieswith positivevalue only

. . . . . . . .

174 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 11: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

We use the two most common constitutional social security rights – the rightto a pension in old age and the right to unemployment insurance – to illustratethe ranking process.

3.1.1 The right to old age, survivors and disability insurance (OASDI)

Each of the three features constituting the right to OASDI was ranked asshown in Table 1. The overall rank is a simple average across all three features.The most popular rights are old age pensions (41 countries), and assistance tothe disabled (39 countries), while support to survivors is less frequent(28 countries).

We use the constitution of Switzerland as an example of a country thatreceives a rank of 3 as regards OASDI rights. To quote the Swiss constitution:“The confederation shall take measures for adequate social security for the elderly,survivors, and disabled persons. The insurance shall be mandatory. The pensionsmust cover basic living expenses appropriately. The maximal pension shall notexceed twice the minimal pension. The pension shall at least be adapted to thedevelopment of prices.” The key elements that are responsible for its high rankare: the insurance is mandatory, there are limits on minimal amounts, and thepension is adjusted to prices.

The constitution of Italy guarantees support to only two of the groupsusually included in OASDI (the elderly and the disabled), as may be seen fromthe following quote: “Workers shall be entitled to adequate insurance for theirneeds in case of accident, illness, disability, old age, and involuntary unemploy-ment.” The constitution assures that workers will receive adequate insurance,but it does not mention any further details such as periodic adjustment. Becauseof this weak commitment it is assigned a rank of 2 for each group covered, butsince only two out of three potential groups are covered, the overall rank is1.333.

India’s constitution contains a general statement concerning the two fea-tures of the right to OASDI; each of them earns a rank of 1, as is indicated by thefollowing quote: “The state shall, within the limits of its economic capacity anddevelopment, make effective provision for securing the right to public assistance incases of unemployment, old age, sickness and disablement.” Introducing thecondition within the limits of its economic capacity and development providesthe government with wide room to choose almost any welfare policy and that isthe reason for the low rank.

Constitutional Commitment 175

Page 12: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

3.2 CCSS around the world

There is wide variability in constitutional social security rights, ranging from theU.S. and Australia, where social security rights are absent, to Switzerland andBrazil, which have a high constitutional commitment to social security. Almost50 countries incorporate a constitutional commitment to social security in theirconstitution with an average score of 0.57. Brazil, Finland, Portugal, andSwitzerland, which do not share obvious common features, are the countrieswith an exceptionally high level of constitutional commitment to social security.The most prevalent social security right in the constitutions is OASDI (at leastone feature), which appears in 43 countries, while Work Injury insuranceappears in only 11 countries.

At first glance it is hard to find common economic, cultural or othercharacteristics among countries that share a similar degree of constitutionalcommitment to social security (Table 2). For example, the Scandinavian coun-tries are spread all over the scale. Finland is closer to Latin-American countries,Sweden has the same constitutional commitment as South Korea, while Norwaybelongs to a group of countries in which social security is absent from theconstitution.

4 The constitution and the extent of socialsecurity

This section examines the empirical correlation between our indices of constitu-tional commitment to social security and the generosity of social security policy.If the constitutional text with respect to social insurance has any practicalmeaning it should appear in the actual extent and coverage of social securitylaws.

4.1 Methods and empirical analysis

In general, expenditures such as transfer payments are a complex combinationof the extent of social security coverage as determined by social security lawsand “exogenous variables” such as take-up rate, demographic composition andmacroeconomic conditions (aggregate unemployment rate in the case of unem-ployment expenditures).

176 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 13: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

That measure may be shaped and affected by the constitutional commitmentto social security as well as important factors such as court interpretation incountries with judiciary review and the power of domestic and internationalorganizations. To guide our empirical analysis we use the following structuralform model:

Lawsj = b0 + b1Xj + b2CCSSj + b3Zj + b4Zj *CCSSj + uj [1]

where X is a vector of various control variables (including GDP per capita anddemographic composition) and CCSS stands for constitutional commitment tosocial security. Z represents a vector of several factors that might influence thesize effect of CCSS on actual social security policy such as judiciary review, NGOpower and ease of amendment. This type of econometric model assumes that ameasure of actual social security laws is a linear combination of social securityrights and exogenous variables.

In addition to (1), we could also write the following “reduced form” relationsbetween constitutional commitment to social security and expenditure on transferpayments:

TRj = c0 + c1Gj + c2CCSSj + c3Zj + c4Zj *CCSSj + ej [2]

where G is a vector that includes X as well as other variables. The problem withestimating eq. [2] is that we cannot know the channel or channels through whichthe constitution affects (if any) social security policy as in eq. [1].

4.1.1 The key explanatory variable

We use our indices of CCSS that were constructed in the previous section as ourkey explanatory variables. Our focus here is on exploring the mechanism chan-nel through which CCSS may affect social security policy (eq. [1]) in addition toestimating the reduced form relations (eq. [2]). In particular, we are interested inb2, which captures the conditional effect of social security rights for countrieswith Z = 0 and on b4, which signifies the interaction effects. We should expect tohave a positive association between social security policy indicators and ourindex of constitutional commitment to social security if the constitutional texthas any practical meaning (b2 + b4Z > 0).

Unlike civil and political rights, social security rights might be less bindingbecause of the reasons outlined in the conceptual framework, and thus variouspolicies might be consistent with the same constitutional commitment to socialsecurity. Thus, the alternative hypothesis is that no relations exist between the

Constitutional Commitment 177

Page 14: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

constitutional text and welfare policy which may reflect the fact that the con-stitution has a solely declarative role (b2 + b4Z = 0).

11

Using interactions allows us to test whether the effect of constitutionalcommitment to social rights on the generosity of welfare policy is higher orlower in countries that differ in judicial independence, the ease of amendment,the power of the international environment regarding social rights, and socialstructure. The incentives of the executive to deviate from the constitutiondepend on constitutional review, the strength of local NGOs, freedom of thepress and international institutions to the extent that they are respected by thegeneral public in addition to the traditional rigidity of the constitution.

The measure of constitutional review that we employ here is taken fromMaddex (1995). That measure takes the value of 2 in case of full constitutionalreview, 1 for countries with limited review, and zero otherwise. This may capturethe likelihood of compliance that increases with the power to review the con-stitutionality of laws.12

The power of NGOs that may condition the effect of constitutional commit-ment to social security is based on the international NGO Network score for theyear 1998 that was introduced by Hughes et al. (2009) and measures the con-nectedness of local NGOs to the world polity. The score ranges between 0 (lowconnectedness) and 1 (high connectedness).

The effect of constitutional commitment to social security on public policydepends also on the freedom of the press. The press is an important mediator inrevealing inconsistency between policy and the written constitution and thus weexpect that countries with a free press would be more likely to show positivecorrelation between social security rights and social policy. We use the averagenumerical rankings of the Freedom of the Press index, which is based on anannual survey of media independence done by Freedom House in a cross section

11 In fact, b2 could also be negative (a cynical constitution), which means that the constitutionaltext reflects the very opposite of the true beliefs that determine welfare policy. In such cynicalregimes the constitutional text serves a propaganda purpose.12 The results remain the same using other measure of constitutional review taken fromGutmann, Hayo and Voigt (2013). We thank Jerg Gutmann for sending us the data on constitu-tional review index for 2005. Following Powell and Staton (2009), we employ also a measure ofjudicial independence based on Cingranelli and Richards (2008) for the years 1990–1999. This isa dummy variable that takes on the value of one if the judiciary is partially independent orgenerally independent and zero if not independent. We thank Jeffrey Staton and Emilia Powellfor providing us with data on five measures of judicial independence including those of Howardand Carey (2003) and Tate and Keith (2007). For space consideration, we report on Cingranelliand Richards’ measure only.

178 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 15: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

of countries. We calculated the average numerical rankings for the years 1993–1999 (0–30 = “Not Free”; 31–60 = “Partly Free” and 61–100 = “Free”).

It is very difficult to find a convincing indicator for the ease of amendment.Nevertheless, the length of the constitution as measured by the number of wordsis used here as a proxy for the ease of amendment or adaptability as suggested byElkins et al. (2009).13 Given the findings of Berkovwitz and Clay (2005) on thehigher likelihood of endurance of shorter constitutions in states, the constitutionsare expected to be more flexible in countries with less detailed constitutions. Inaddition, we employ an indicator for the rigidity of a constitution taken fromMaddex (1995) for the most recent year. The scale goes from 1 (if the approval of amajority of the legislature, the chief of state and a referendum is required tochange the constitution) to 4 (if, in addition, the legislature has to approve theamendment by more than 66% of votes in both houses of the legislature in twoconsecutive legislative terms). Our model also includes an interaction of CCSS anda measure of ethnic fractionalization (defined below). The likelihood of compli-ance is reduced in a more fragmented society. The basic and solid intuition is thatethnic fractionalization increases the probability of a gap between the constitutionand the desired policy. In contrast, we are skeptical that the ratification of theInternational Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (ICESCR) treatyhas any practical meaning for compliance. We nevertheless include in the model adummy variable for ratification of the treaty before 2000 (the year is chosen to beconsistent with CCSS timing) and its interaction with CCSS. There are sevencountries in our sample that had not ratified the ICESCR treaty as of 2000,including the United States and South Africa. Given our sample size, we haveadded one control variable at a time to the baseline estimated model.

4.1.2 The dependent variables

It is difficult to find one single variable that represents accurately the degree ofsocial security generosity. Therefore, we use four different measures of socialsecurity policy to examine the relationship between constitutional commitmentto social security and welfare policy where each measure may capture a differentdimension of the actual extent of social security.

Our first dependent variable is the share of actual spending on transferpayments relative to GDP in the ‘1990s.14 Using transfer payments as a dependent

13 Elkins et al. (2009) use other measures for the ease of amendment but they seem to us evenless persuasive.14 This is a similar model as in Ben-Bassat and Dahan (2008).

Constitutional Commitment 179

Page 16: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

variable captures the actual outlays and also should be seen as a reduced formassociation between social rights and social security policy (eq. [2]).15

The three other measures allow us to focus on the channel through whichsocial rights may impact social expenditures, i. e., the laws that specify thesocial programs, the entitled populations and its coverage. If the constitutiondoes have an effect on welfare policy, this should be first translated into apositive connection between the degree of commitment to social security inthe constitution and the extent and coverage of social security laws. Thatmight be seen more as a structural estimation of the effect of constitutionalcommitment to social security on the extent and coverage of social security laws,which complements the reduced form estimation.

The empirical challenge to exploring such a channel is to construct a mean-ingful index that captures the extent and coverage of social security laws. Notethat the generosity of social security laws may be related to the size of theeligible population, perhaps taking account of demographic factors, such as agedistribution, ethnic composition, and the percentage of the eligible populationin the total population. Social entitlements may be more generous with a largereligible population because of political considerations through a median votereffect, or less generous due to budget considerations.

In estimating eq. [1], we have employed three additional different dependentvariables to capture the actual extent and coverage of social security. The seconddependent variable is a measure of social security coverage that has been con-structed by Botero et al. (2004) for 85 countries. Most social security programs areformulated as entitlements, a fact that helps to quantify the extent and coverageof social security programs in a relatively meaningful way. We use their summaryindex of social security coverage instead of transfer payments as a proxy for socialsecurity coverage (52 countries exist both in their and our samples).

That indicator has certain advantages over actual public spending on redis-tribution policy. It is less sensitive to cross country differences in macroeconomicconditions (unemployment), demographic composition (elderly population), andtake-up rates of social benefits.16 It is important to the extent that the error term iscorrelated with the omitted variables, as the coefficient of CCSS is biased if we donot control for all of the relevant factors.

15 Ben-Bassat and Dahan (2008) found a positive relationship between the degree of constitu-tional commitment to social security and transfer payments (as a share of GDP).16 Several papers have also worked with the difference between gross income inequality (pretax-transfers) and net income inequality (post tax-transfer). We do not employ that indicatorbecause of data limitations. The data on the reduction of income inequality as a result ofgovernment intervention is available mainly for developed countries.

180 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 17: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Moreover, transfer payments include social security expenditures in addi-tion to other government transfers. International institutions that collect andpublish budgetary data are always careful to add footnotes regarding the limita-tions of comparing fiscal data across countries. In fact, we found large discre-pancies between various sources in the data on actual social securityexpenditures or transfer payments.

The third dependent variable is the contribution rate made by employersand workers as a percentage of earnings (payroll tax rate) to all social securityprograms (taken from Social Security Throughout the World 2004). The contri-bution rate as an indicator for the extent and coverage of social securityprograms might be more comparable across countries than transfer payments.Nonetheless, the limitation of that proxy is clear: social security benefits may bemore generous than what is implied by the contribution rate in countries thathave experienced long and substantial actuarial deficits. However, Mulligan andSala-i-Martin (2004) report a relatively large correlation between the amount ofrevenue collected by payroll taxes and social security expenditures.

The fourth dependent variable is the contribution rate for OASDI, whichrepresents core social security programs. The disaggregated social security rightsthat are constructed here allow us to explore the effect of core social securityrights, in addition to all rights, on core social policy. Naturally, the constitu-tional commitment to a particular right must be examined in terms of theassociated social security law and therefore we should replace our key explana-tory variable (i. e., summary index of social security rights) by a subset indicatorof core social security rights (constitutional commitment to OASDI). This type ofdetailed examination provides a more stringent test of the importance of con-stitutional rights on social policy.

4.1.3 The control variables

We estimate the effect of constitutional commitment to social security on welfarepolicy, controlling for a list of control variables. The most common controlvariables are GDP per capita and demographic composition.17 These two vari-ables encapsulate the Logic of Industrialism approach (Wilensky, 1975).Therefore our baseline statistical model includes, in addition to CCSS, thesetwo control variables.

17 For example, Rodrik (1998), Hicks (1999), Huber and Stephens (2001), Taveres and Wacziarg(2001), Mulligan et al. (2002) and Swank (2002).

Constitutional Commitment 181

Page 18: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

We use the average share of the population over age 65 for years 1990–1999(taken from the World Bank Database on World Development Indicators) to capturethe fact that a large share of social security expenditure goes to that age group. Thedata for GDP per capita is an average for 1990–1999 taken from the Penn WorldTables (the data are not available for Taiwan). Income per capita serves as anindicator of the level of economic development, which may affect preferences forpublic expenditure, as well as a more advanced tax-collection system.

We test other control variables to allow for competing theories such as PowerResources and political institutions (as mentioned above) to explain the crosscountry variation in welfare policy. The first additional control variable is ameasure of political orientation for the years 1990–1999 (an average). This vari-able ranges from 1 to 3 where 1, 2 and 3 represent “Right,” “Center,” and “Left,”respectively. Following Korpi (1983) and others, we expect that countries withleftist government would tend to redistribute more, other things being equal. Weuse also a political system indicator that assigns a value of 1 to a country with aparliamentary system in 1998, and zero otherwise. It is more likely that a countrywith a parliamentary system would lead to a more generous welfare system (SeeIversen and Soskice, 2006). The data for the two above political indicators aretaken from the World Bank Database on Political Institutions.

The well-known indicator of ethnic fractionalization is also tested as acontrol variable. The measure of ethnic fractionalization is defined as the like-lihood of selecting two individuals with different ethnicities when drawingrandomly from the general population (taken from Alesina, 2003). FollowingAlesina (2003) and others, we expect a less generous welfare system in countrieswith a higher degree of ethnic fractionalization.

4.2 Results

Before turning to regression results, Table 3 presents a simple matrix for fourdifferent features of social security: Old age, Unemployment, Work Injury, andSickness. The rows describe whether a particular feature exists in the constitu-tion (regardless of its degree of commitment), and the columns representwhether that same feature appears in the regular laws as they are documentedin Social Security Throughout the World 2004.

Panels A and C of Table 3 show that Old Age (including survivors anddisability) and Work Injury laws exist in all countries. Those countries that havenot mentioned Old Age (25 countries in our sample) and Work Injury (57 countriesin our sample) in their constitution still provide these social insurance features.This simple matrix implies that the lack of constitutional commitment to a certain

182 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 19: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

social security feature is not translated to an absence of that particular featurefrom social security law.

The other off-diagonal cells in four panels of Table 3 are even more inter-esting. They answer the question of whether there are countries that haveexpressed commitment to particular features of social security and yet do notprovide coverage at all. We find five such countries in the case ofUnemployment and two countries in the case of Sickness. However, it is hardto draw conclusions from this finding due to data limitations. Unfortunately, theSocial Security Throughout the World publication pooled together countries thatdo not have a particular feature of social security with countries for which thedata are unavailable.

It seems that the mere existence of social security laws is not related to theirabsence or presence in the constitution. However, the main goal of this paper is to

Table 3: A simple matrix of social security laws and constitutional rights.

Constitutional Right Social Security Law Total

Yes No

Panel A: Old Age, Disability and Survivors (number of countries)Yes

No

Total

Panel B: Unemployment (number of countries)Yes *

No

Total

Panel C: Work Injury (number of countries)Yes

No

Total

Panel D: Sickness (number of countries)Yes **

No

Total

* The five countries are Bolivia, Dominican Republic, Panama, Nicaragua, and Bahrain. SocialSecurity Throughout the World publication pooled together countries that do not have aparticular feature of social security with countries for which the data is unavailable.** The two countries are Syria and Bahrain. Social Security Throughout the World publicationpooled together countries that do not have a particular feature of social security with countriesfor which the data is unavailable.

Constitutional Commitment 183

Page 20: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

examine whether those countries that do include social rights in their constitutionare different in terms of generosity of social security laws from those who do not,and within the group of countries that have social security rights in their consti-tutions, if countries with higher degrees of constitutional commitment to socialsecurity are also more generous as expressed by social security laws.

Table 4 presents our baseline results for four various indices of the generosity ofsocial security. In the first column we provide the reduced form estimation,which replicates the Ben-Bassat and Dahan (2008) regression. The summaryindex of constitutional commitment to social security was found to be positivelyassociated with the share of transfer payments in GDP. The estimated coefficientreflects a substantial quantitative effect. An increase of one standard deviationin the constitutional commitment to social security would induce a rise of 1.8percentage points in the share of transfers in GDP if this correlation reflects acausal relationship. Note that the coefficient of CCSS is positive and significant(at 5%), even when countries with a rank of 3 on the constitutional commitmentindex are excluded (not reported here).

Table 4: Generosity of social security laws and constitutional commitment to social security.

The dependent variable

() () () ()

TransferPayments(% GDP)

Social SecurityLaws Index

(Botero et al.)

ContributionRate (All

programs)

ContributionRate (OASDIprograms)

Constant –. –. .*** .***(–.) (–.) (.) (.)

Log GDP per-capita –. .** –.** –.**(–.) (.) (–.) (–.)

Population + .*** .* .*** .***(.) (.) (.) (.)

CCSS .*** . . .*(.) (.) (.) (.)

Adj.R² . . . .Observations

Notes: CCSS stands for our summary index in columns 1–3 and core index in column 4. The variableCCSS is measured according to ranking procedure that is explained in the text. The t statistics arereported in parentheses. *** Significant at 1%; ** Significant at 5%; * Significant at 10%.

184 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 21: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

As expected, the effect of the share of the population over age 65 on transferpayments is positive and significant. We do not find a significant impact of GDPper capita on transfer payments but this result is sensitive to the inclusion ofelderly population variables. The coefficient of GDP per capita becomes positiveand significant when the share of the population over age 65 is not included.These results reflect the positive and high correlation (0.79) between the share ofthe population over age 65 and GDP per capita. This correlation implies that theshare of elderly population may also serve as proxy for the level of economicdevelopment.

In the second column we use as our dependent variable an index of socialsecurity coverage that was constructed by Botero et al. (2004) for 85 countries.The coefficient of constitutional commitment to social security is againpositive, but it is not significant at an acceptable level. In columns 3 and 4(Table 4) we run regressions in which the dependent variables are the con-tribution rates both for all social security programs and for core social securityactivities (taken from Social Security Throughout the World 2004). The coeffi-cient of constitutional commitment to social security implies a positive effecton the social security contribution rate. However, it becomes significant at the10 percent level when the contribution rate on core social security activity isused.

We rerun all of the regressions allowing for a non-linear effect of CCSS usingordinal coding of the CCSS variable with three categories for none (CCSS = 0),minimal (0 < CCSS ≤ 1), and maximal (1 < CCSS ≤ 3) and the general picture thatemerges is essentially the same. The results show that the positive impact ofCCSS on the share of transfer payments in GDP is significant only when CCSS isgreater than one (Table 5). This finding is consistent with the pragmatic modelaccording to which the constitution should matter if social rights are written inconcrete terms. However, the positive effect of CCSS on the other three measuresof social security laws is significant both for countries with minimal and withstrong constitutional commitments to social security rights (Table 5). This resultsuggests that both the symbolic and pragmatic models outlined in Section 2affect social policy in practice.

Given that the CCSS variable is essentially bi-modal, as many countries(26) have not included social security rights in their constitution or have onlya minimal constitutional guarantee of social security (29 countries) and onlya few countries (11) have a strong commitment, it is important to test thesensitivity of our results to our choice of coding CCSS. The binary summaryindex of constitutional commitment to social security was found to be posi-tively associated with all three measures of social security laws (Table 6).Interestingly, the effect of CCSS on the actual share of transfer payments

Constitutional Commitment 185

Page 22: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

in GDP is still positive, but it is not significant anymore at an acceptablelevel.

Thus, while the sign of our key coefficient is robust to the choice ofcoding, the degree of significance is sensitive to the chosen dimension ofsocial security extensiveness. The ambiguity regarding the policy implicationsof constitutional social rights could be one possible justification to favor binarycoding. Policy makers are less likely to overlook CCSS completely but theyhave more room to choose the level of social policy generosity regardless of the(positive) level of constitutional commitment in cases where there is a lack ofclarity regarding the concrete meaning of constitutional social rights. While itis easy to check whether a country has unemployment insurance, it is farharder to find a yardstick to measure whether the level of generosity ofunemployment benefits is in line with the constitutional commitment to sucha right. In the following sections we use a binary coding of CCSS (instead ofthe original scale) to keep the interpretation of the results relatively simple andcomparable.

Table 5: Generosity of social security laws and constitutional commitment to social security(Non-linear effect of CCSS).

The dependent variable

() () () ()

TransferPayments(% GDP)

Social SecurityLaws Index

(Botero et al.)

ContributionRate (All

programs)

ContributionRate (OASDIprograms)

Constant –. –. .*** .***(–.) (–.) (.) (.)

Log GDP per-capita –. .*** –.** –.**(–.) (.) (–.) (–.)

Population + .*** .* .*** .***(.) (.) (.) (.)

<CCSS ≤ . .** .*** .**(.) (.) (.) (.)

<CCSS ≤ .*** .** .* .(.) (.) (.) (.)

Adj.R² . . . .Observations

Notes: CCSS stands for our summary index in columns 1–3 and core index in column 4. The tstatistics are reported in parentheses. *** Significant at 1%; ** Significant at 5%; * Significantat 10%.

186 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 23: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

4.3 The endogeneity problem

The positive coefficient we found may not reflect causal relations because unob-served social preferences may shape both constitutional social rights and socialpolicy. While we could not rule out the potential risk of endogeneity, there areseveral reasons to believe that the danger of endogeneity is lower in our case.

First, there is an inherent time lag between the timing of the writing ofconstitutional social rights, which may represent mostly past preferences, andthe current social policy that is influenced by current social priorities. Somecountries have not made any changes in social rights for decades or evencenturies, as is the case in the United States, while others have made significantmodifications throughout their history. Nevertheless, one possible direction forfuture research is to construct panel data sets on constitutional social rights,which might serve to further elucidate the reason for changing the scope andefficacy of social rights.

Second, the risk of endogeneity arises if there is a systematic bias in thesense that countries that provide more generous social policy tend to include

Table 6: Generosity of social security laws and constitutional commitment to social security(Binary CCSS).

The dependent variable

() () () ()

TransferPayments(% GDP)

Social SecurityLaws Index

(Botero et al.)

ContributionRate (All

programs)

ContributionRate (OASDIprograms)

Constant –. –. .*** .***(–.) (–.) (.) (.)

Log GDP per-capita –. .*** –.** –.**(–.) (.) (–.) (–.)

Population + .*** .* .*** .***(.) (.) (.) (.)

Binary CCSS . .*** .*** .**(.) (.) (.) (.)

Adj.R² . . . .Observations

Notes: CCSS stands for our summary index in columns 1–3 and core index in column 4. Thevariable CCSS is a dummy that take the value of one if a country includes social security rightsin its constitution and zero otherwise. The t statistics are reported in parentheses. ***Significant at 1%; ** Significant at 5%; * Significant at 10%.

Constitutional Commitment 187

Page 24: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

social rights in the constitution. However, it could be that social policy in somecountries is shaped by social preferences that are not (yet) in the constitutionand may never be. Third, the social rights that are included in the constitutioncould be just the opposite of the true social preferences that dictate governmentpolicy. In those cynical regimes the constitution is merely of propaganda value.Thus, the potential omission of an important variable such as social preferencesor norms should necessarily lead to positive relations as has been found in ourempirical analysis.

4.4 Interaction effects

As suggested in the conceptual framework, the effectiveness of constitutionalsocial rights depends on the strength of several political and social institutionssuch as the degree of constitutional review, the ease of amendment and thepower of NGOs and international organizations, in addition to ethnic fractiona-lization. We test these effects by incorporating interactions between the aboveinstitutional characteristics and our index of constitutional commitment tosocial security rights.

Table 7 displays the results of regressions that include an index of constitu-tional review. In addition to our baseline model we add an interaction term tocapture the potential impact of judicial review on the compliance with constitu-tional commitment to social security rights. The coefficient of the interactionterm is insignificant, which implies that the effect of CCSS on the actual socialsecurity coverage is not affected by the degree of constitutional review. We findsimilar results using other measures of judicial review and judicial indepen-dence (not reported here). It might be that those measures do not represent thetrue power of the judiciary system with respect to social rights.

The same general picture emerges when testing the potential effect on thecoefficient of CCSS of ratification of the International Covenant on Economic,Social and Cultural Rights (ICESCR) treaty, as well as the international connect-edness of local NGOs to the world polity. The coefficient of the interactionbetween CCSS and ICESCR came out as insignificant (Table 8). The interactioneffect between CCSS and NGOs is also not significant (Table 9). We find the sameresult for the interaction of freedom of the press and constitutional commitmentto social security (Table 10).

The interaction of the length of the constitution and CCSS is not significant(Table 11), while the coefficients of CCSS keep their sign and significance (exceptfor the social security coverage index). We should be cautious in interpreting theeffect of the interaction term in light of our doubts regarding the length in words

188 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 25: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table7:

Gen

eros

ityof

social

security

lawsan

dcons

titution

alcommitmen

tto

social

security

(withpo

litical

orientation,

political

institutions

and

ethn

icfraction

alization).

Thede

pend

entvariab

le

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

Tran

sfer

Paym

ents

(%GDP)

SocialSecurityLawsInde

x(Boteroet

al.)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(Allprog

rams)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(OASDIprog

rams)

Con

stan

t–

.

–.

–.

–.

.***

.***

.***

.***

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

LogGDPpe

r-capita

–.

–.

.***

.**

–.***

–.***

–.***

–.**

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Popu

lation

+

.***

.***

.

.

.***

.***

.***

. ***

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

CCSSSum

maryInde

x

dummy

.

.

.**

.

.**

.

.**

.

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

political

orientation

–.

.

.

.

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

parliamen

tary

system

–.

–.

–.

.

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

Ethn

icFraction

..

.

–.

–.

–.

–.

–.*

–.

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

CCSS*Ethn

ic–

.

.

.

.

Fraction

alization

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Sum

ofmainan

d

interactioneffects

.

.**

.**

.*

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Adj.R²

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

Obs

ervation

s

Notes:Th

evariab

leCCSSstan

dsforou

rsu

mmaryinde

xin

columns

1–6an

dcore

inde

xin

column7–

8.C

CSSis

adu

mmythat

take

sthevalueof

oneifacoun

tryinclud

es

social

security

righ

tsin

itscons

titution

andzero

othe

rwise.

Thesu

mof

mainan

dinteractioneffectsrepresen

tstheestimated

margina

leffect

ofCCSSon

thede

pend

ent

variab

leat

themea

nvalueof

Ethn

icFraction

alization.

Thetstatistics

arerepo

rted

inpa

renthe

ses.

***Significant

at1%;**

Significant

at5%;*Significant

at10

%.

Constitutional Commitment 189

Page 26: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table8:Gen

eros

ityof

social

security

lawsan

dcons

titution

alcommitmen

tto

social

security

(withjudicial

inde

pend

ence

interaction).

Thede

pend

entvariab

le

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

Tran

sfer

Paym

ents

(%GDP)

SocialSecurityLaws

Inde

x(Boteroet

al.).

Contribu

tion

Rate(All

prog

rams).

Contribu

tion

Rate

(OASDIprog

rams)

Con

stan

t–

.

–.

–.

–.

.

.**

.

.**

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

LogGDPpe

r-capita

–.

–.

.***

.***

–.**

–.**

–.**

–.*

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Popu

lation

+

.***

.***

.*

.*

.***

.***

.***

.***

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

CCSS

.

–.

–.

.

.

.

.

.

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Judicial

Inde

pend

ence

.

–.

.

.

(.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

CCSS*Jud

icialInde

pend

ence

–.

.

.

–.

–.

.

–.

.

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(–.)

(.)

Sum

ofmainan

dinteractioneffects

.

.

.**

.***

.***

.***

.**

.**

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Adj.R²

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

Obs

ervation

s

Notes:Th

evariab

leCCSSstan

dsforou

rsu

mmaryinde

xin

columns

1–6an

dcore

inde

xin

column7–

8.CCS

Sis

adu

mmythat

take

sthevalueof

one

ifacoun

tryinclud

esso

cial

security

righ

tsin

itscons

titution

andzero

othe

rwise.

Themea

sure

Judicial

Inde

pend

ence

isaccordingto

Cingran

ellian

dRich

ards

(2008

).Th

esu

mof

mainan

dinteractioneffectsrepresen

tstheestimated

margina

leffect

ofCCSSon

thede

pend

entvariab

leat

themea

nvalueof

Judicial

Inde

pend

ence.Th

etstatistics

arerepo

rted

inpa

renthe

ses.

***Significant

at1%;**

Significant

at5%;*Significant

at10

%.

190 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 27: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table9:

Gen

eros

ityof

social

security

lawsan

dcons

titution

alcommitmen

tto

social

security

(withRa

tification

ofICES

CRinteraction).

Thede

pend

entvariab

le

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

Tran

sfer

Paym

ents

(%GDP)

SocialS

ecurityLawsInde

x(Boteroet

al.)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(Allprog

rams)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(OASDIprog

rams)

Con

stan

t–

.

–.

–.**

–.

.***

.**

.***

.**

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

LogGDPpe

r-capita

.

–.

.***

.***

–.**

–.**

–.**

–.*

(.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Popu

lation

+

.***

.***

.

.*

.***

.***

.***

.***

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

CCSS

–.

–.

.

.

–.

–.

–.**

–.

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Ratific

ationof

ICES

CR

.

.

–.*

–.**

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

CCSS*R

atificationof

ICES

CR

.

.

–.

.

.**

.

.**

.*

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Sum

ofmainan

dinteractioneffects

.

.

.**

.***

.***

.**

.**

.*

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Adj.R²

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

Obs

ervation

s

Notes:Th

evariab

leCCSSstan

dsforou

rsu

mmaryinde

xin

columns

1–6an

dcore

inde

xin

column7–

8.CCS

Sis

adu

mmythat

take

sthevalueof

one

ifacoun

tryinclud

esso

cial

security

righ

tsin

itscons

titution

andzero

othe

rwise.

Thedu

mmyvariab

leforRa

tification

ofICES

CRrefers

toratification

priorto

theyear

2000.Cou

ntries

that

ratified

theICES

CRafter20

00wereassign

edavalueof

0(Ind

onesia,Bah

rain,Tu

rkey

andChina

).Th

esu

mof

mainan

dinteractioneffectsrepresen

tstheestimated

margina

leffectof

CCSSon

thede

pend

entvariab

leat

themea

nvalueof

Ratific

ationof

ICES

CR.

Thetstatistics

arerepo

rted

inpa

renthe

ses.

***Significant

at1%;**

Significant

at5%;*Significant

at10

%.

Constitutional Commitment 191

Page 28: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table10:Gen

eros

ityof

social

security

lawsan

dcons

titution

alcommitmen

tto

social

security

(withLeng

thof

Con

stitutioninteraction).

Thede

pend

entvariab

le

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

Tran

sfer

Paym

ents

(%GDP)

SocialSecurityLaws

Inde

x(Boteroet

al.)

Contribu

tion

Rate(All

prog

rams)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(OASDIprog

rams)

Con

stan

t–

.

–.

–.

–.

.**

.***

.*

.**

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

LogGDPpe

r-capita

– .

–.

.**

.**

–.**

–.**

–.

–.*

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Popu

lation

+

.***

.***

.**

.*

.***

.***

.***

.***

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

CCSS

.

.

.

.***

.**

.**

.**

.

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Leng

thof

Con

stitution

–.

–.

.

.*

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

CCSS*Len

gthof

Con

stitution

.

.

.

–.

–.

.

–.

.

(.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(–.)

(.)

Sum

ofmainan

dinteractioneffects

.

.

. ***

.***

.**

.**

.*

.**

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Adj.R²

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

Obs

ervation

s

Notes:Th

evariab

leCCSSstan

dsforou

rsu

mmaryinde

xin

columns

1–6an

dcore

inde

xin

column7–

8.CCS

Sis

adu

mmythat

take

sthevalueof

one

ifacoun

tryinclud

esso

cial

security

righ

tsin

itscons

titution

andzero

othe

rwise.

Theleng

thof

cons

titution

ismea

suredin

words

divide

dby

10,000.

Thesu

mof

mainan

dinteractioneffectsrepresen

tstheestimated

margina

leffectof

CCSSon

thede

pend

entvariab

leat

themea

nvalueof

Leng

thof

Con

stitution.

Thetstatistics

arerepo

rted

inpa

renthe

ses.

***Significant

at1%;**

Significant

at5%;*Significant

at10

%.

192 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 29: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table11:G

enerosity

ofsocial

security

lawsan

dconstitutiona

lcom

mitm

entto

social

security

(With

interactionbe

tweenCC

SSan

dLeng

thof

Constitution).

Thede

pend

entvariab

le

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

Tran

sfer

Paym

ents

(%GDP)

SocialSecurityLaws

Inde

x(Boteroet

al.)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(Allprog

rams)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(OASDIprog

rams)

Con

stan

t–

.

–.

–.

–.

.**

.***

.*

.**

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

LogGDPpe

r-capita

–.

–.

.**

.**

–.**

–.**

–.

–.*

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Popu

lation

+

.***

.***

.**

.*

.***

.***

.***

.***

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

BinaryCCSS

.

.

.

.***

.**

.**

.**

.

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Leng

thof

Con

stitution

–.

–.

.

.*

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

BinaryCCSS*Len

gthof

Con

stitution

.

.

.

–.

–.

.

–.

.

(.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(–.)

(.)

Sum

ofmainan

dinteractioneffects

.

.

.***

.***

.**

.**

.*

.**

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Adj.R²

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

Obs

ervation

s

Notes:Th

evariab

leCCSSstan

dsforou

rsu

mmaryinde

xin

columns

1–6an

dcore

inde

xin

column7–

8.C

CSSis

adu

mmythat

take

thevalueof

oneif

acoun

tryinclud

esso

cial

security

righ

tsin

itscons

titution

andzero

othe

rwise.

Theleng

thof

cons

titution

ismea

suredin

words

divide

dby

10,000.

Thesu

mof

mainan

dinteractioneffectspresen

ttheestimated

margina

leffect

ofCCS

Son

thede

pend

entvariab

leat

themea

nvalueof

Leng

thof

Con

stitution.

Thetstatistics

arerepo

rted

inthepa

renthe

ses.

***Significant

at1%;**

Significant

at5%;*Significant

at10

%.

Constitutional Commitment 193

Page 30: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

as a good indicator for the degree of flexibility of the constitution. Moreover, thelength is a defendable proxy to the extent that compliance is more likely underdurable constitutions. We also employ Maddex’s index of constitutional rigidity,given the disagreement regarding the length of the constitution as a reliableindicator of constitutional flexibility. The results are generally the same withthat alternative measure of rigidity (not reported).

Next, we test whether the effect of CCSS is smaller in more fragmentedsocieties. As can be seen, the coefficient of CCSS is positive in all specificationsbut significant, as before, in three out of four measures of social security cover-age. Also, the sign and significance of GDP per capita and demographic compo-sition are not affected by the inclusion of these three control variables. Incontrast, we find that the coefficient of the interaction term is insignificant(Table 12).

In Table 12 we add three important control variables to our baseline speci-fication that represent political institutions and social structure. The coefficientsof political orientation and the parliamentary system are not significant, whilethe coefficient of ethnic fractionalization is significant only when the dependentvariable is the contribution rate to core social security programs. Its sign isnegative, as expected.

The general picture that emerges from Tables 7–12 is that the magnitude ofthe estimated impact of CCSS on social security coverage is not affected sig-nificantly by the various institutional characteristics, which is not in line withthe theoretical prediction. However, the marginal effect of CCSS (at the mean) isstill significant except in the case of transfer payments as the dependent variable(as before). Note that an F test shows that the sum of coefficients of CCSS andthe interaction term is positive and significant in all six tables (the bottom rows).Thus, the positive effect of constitutional commitment to social security onactual social security coverage is very robust, which is consistent with themain hypothesis of the conceptual framework.

4.5 Sensitivity analysis

The various models presented in Section 2 are based on the assumption of ademocratic society, in which leaders are more accountable than in undemocraticcountries such as Syria or Iran. We have rerun our regressions excludingcountries that were classified by Freedom House in the year 2003 as not free(the countries that were excluded are Syria, Iran, Egypt, Tunisia, Cameroon andChina). As can be seen from Table 13, the coefficients of CCSS remain positiveand significant with the limited sample of free or partly free countries.

194 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 31: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Table12:Gen

eros

ityof

social

security

lawsan

dcons

titution

alcommitmen

tto

social

security

(Withinteractionbe

twee

nCCSSan

dEthn

icFraction

alization).

Thede

pend

entvariab

le

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

()

Tran

sfer

Paym

ents

(%GDP)

SocialSecurityLaws

Inde

x(Boteroet

al)

Contribu

tion

Rate(All

prog

rams)

Contribu

tion

Rate

(OASDIprog

rams)

Con

stan

t–

.

–.

–.

–.

.***

.***

.***

.***

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

LogGDPpe

r-capita

– .

–.

.**

.***

–.***

–.**

–.**

–.**

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

Popu

lation

+

.***

.***

.

.

.***

.***

.***

.***

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

BinaryCCSS

.

.

.

.***

.

.***

.

.**

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Ethn

icFraction

alization

.

–.

–.

–.

(.)

(–.)

(–.)

(–.)

BinaryCCSS*EthnicFraction

.–

.

–.

.

–.

.

–.

.

–.

(–.)

(–.)

(.)

(–.)

(.)

(–.)

(.)

(–.)

Sum

ofmainan

dinteractioneffects

.

.

.**

.***

.**

.***

.*

.**

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

(.)

Adj.R²

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

.

Obs

ervation

s

Notes:Th

evariab

leCCSSstan

dsforou

rsu

mmaryinde

xin

columns

1–6an

dcore

inde

xin

column7–

8.C

CSSis

adu

mmythat

take

thevalueof

oneif

acoun

tryinclud

esso

cial

security

righ

tsin

itscons

titution

andzero

othe

rwise.

Thesu

mof

mainan

dinteractioneffectspresen

ttheestimated

margina

leffectof

CCSSon

thede

pend

entvariab

leat

themea

nvalueof

Ethn

icFraction

alization.

Thetstatistics

arerepo

rted

inthepa

renthe

ses.

***

Significant

at1%;**

Significant

at5%;*Significant

at10

%.

Constitutional Commitment 195

Page 32: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

As we have mentioned, Persson and Tabellini (2004) explore the effect ofelectoral rules and forms of governments on the size of government. In theirTable 4, they had investigated the impact of these two political dimensions onthe generosity of welfare payments. In Table 14 we test whether our results aresensitive to the inclusion of all PT’s covariates (majoritarian system and pre-sidential executive). The estimated effect of constitutional commitment to socialsecurity survives this test.

5 Conclusion

In this paper we have constructed for 68 countries seven indices of constitu-tional commitment to social security rights: Old Age, Survivors, Disability,Unemployment, Sickness, and Work Injury insurance, and Income Support.

Table 13: Generosity of social security laws and constitutional commitment to social security(Democratic countries).

The dependent variable

() () ()

TransferPayments(% GDP)

Social SecurityLaws Index

(Botero et al)

ContributionRate

(All programs)

ContributionRate (OASDIprograms)

Constant . –.** .*** .***(.) (–.) (.) (.)

Log GDP per-capita –. .*** –.** –.**(–.) (.) (–.) (–.)

Population + .*** .** .*** .***(.) (.) (.) (.)

Binary CCSS . .** .** .*(.) (.) (.) (.)

Sample Free and partly free countries at Adj.R² . . . .Observations

Notes: CCSS stands for our summary index in columns 1–3 and core index in column 4. Thevariable CCSS is a dummy that take the value of one if a country includes social security rightsin its constitution and zero otherwise. The sample includes countries that were classified byFreedom House as either Free or Partly Free at 2003. The t statistics are reported in theparentheses. *** Significant at 1%; ** Significant at 5%; * Significant at 10%.

196 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 33: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

The new detailed data on constitutional social security rights can be used infuture research on the welfare state. A commitment to OASDI appears in theconstitution of 43 countries while only 11 countries have a constitutional com-mitment to Work Injury insurance.

Twenty-one countries preferred not to include any social security rights intheir constitutional text, but nevertheless in practice they do provide socialsecurity. In general, in countries that have social security rights in their con-stitutions the degree of commitment is relatively low; some countries lower itfurther by adding that those rights should be in accordance with the law. Thismay reflect the fear that constitutional commitment might undermine the flex-ibility of economic policy to adjust to environment changes such as macroeco-nomic fluctuations or preferences toward government involvement.

Table 14: Generosity of social security laws and constitutional commitment to social security(With Majoritarian Countries & Presidential Executive).

The dependent variable

() () () ()

TransferPayments(% GDP)

Social SecurityLaws Index

(Botero et al)

ContributionRate (All

programs)

ContributionRate (OASDIprograms)

Constant –. –.** .*** .***(–.) (–.) (.) (.)

Log GDP per-capita –. .*** –.** –.**(–.) (.) (–.) (–.)

Population + .*** .* .*** .***(.) (.) (.) (.)

Binary CCSS . .** .** .**(.) (.) (.) (.)

Majoritarian Countries –. –. . .(–.) (–.) (.) (.)

Presidential Executive . . –. –.*(.) (.) (–.) (–.)

Adj.R² . . . .Observations

Notes: CCSS stands for our summary index in columns 1–3 and core index in column 4. Thevariable CCSS is a dummy that take the value of one if a country includes social security rightsin its constitution and zero otherwise. The dummy variables for Majoritarian Countries andPresidential Executive are according to the Database of Political Institutions and refer to theyear 1998. The t statistics are reported in the parentheses. *** Significant at 1%; ** Significantat 5%; * Significant at 10%.

Constitutional Commitment 197

Page 34: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Our work suggests that the chosen indicator to represent the generosity ofwelfare states can influence the results on the big question of why somecountries redistribute more than others. In general, we find a positive effectfor all four measures of social security policy with respect to constitutionalprotections of that security, but the significance of their coefficients is sensitiveto the chosen coding of CCSS. The impact of CCSS on the actual share ofexpenditure on transfer payments is significant only when we use the originalscaling of social security rights, but it becomes insignificant with binary coding.The reverse is true for the other three different indexes for the coverage of socialsecurity.

We have found significant coefficients for CCSS with social security con-tribution rates and social security coverage index as independent variables. Theambiguity regarding the policy implications of constitutional social rights couldbe one possible explanation for the success of binary coding. Policy makers areless likely to overlook CCSS completely, but they have more room to choose thelevel of social policy generosity regardless of the (positive) level of constitutionalcommitment.

These results imply a positive connection between the degree of commit-ment to social security in the constitution and the extent and coverage of socialsecurity laws. It provides support for the hypothesis that the constitutional textis meaningful for social security policy.

It is not clear why the more structural estimation does not generate the sameresults as the reduced form estimation. The data that we have used are a naturalcandidate to explain that discrepancy. The contribution rates and the index ofsocial security coverage we have borrowed from Botero et al. (2004) may capturedifferent features of the extent of social security laws.

The general picture that emerges from the findings of this paper is that whilethe translation of social rights such as social security may be expressed byvarious levels of generosity, the degree of constitutional commitment doeshave practical implications for social security policy. Thus, constitutional com-mitment to social rights seems to play a role in explaining the large variation inwelfare state coverage around the world.

Acknowledgment: We thank the Israel Democracy Institute that has initiated thisresearch project. We wish to thank Margit Cohen, John Gal, Sharon Gilad, YishayMishor and Andrei Shleifer for their helpful comments. We also thank ArielGoldstein, Muli San and Liza Teper for research assistance.

Funding: We thank the Minerva Center for Human Rights for financial support.

198 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 35: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

References

Alesina, A., E. Glaeser, and B. Sacerdote. 2001. “Why Doesn’t the United States Have aEuropean-Style Welfare State?” 2 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 187–254.

Alesina, A., A. Devleeschauwer, W. Easterly, S. Kurlat, and R. Wacziarg. 2003. Fractionalization.8 Journal of Economic growth 155–194.

Ben-Bassat, A., and M. Dahan. 2008. “Social and Economic Rights in the Constitution and inPractice,” 36 Journal of Comparative Economics 103–119.

Berkowitz, D., and K. Clay. 2005 “American Civil Law Origins: Implications for StateConstitutions,” 7 American Law and Economics Review 62–84.

Blasi, G.J., and D.L. Cingranelli 1996. “Do Constitutions and Institutions Help Protect HumanRights,” In D.L. Cingranelli (ed.) Human Rights and Developing Countries Greenwich JAIPress: 223–237.

Botero, J., D. Dimeon, L.-P. Rafael, F.C. Lopez-de-Silanes, and S. Andrei. 2004. “The Regulationof Labor,” 119 Quarterly Journal of Economics 1339–1382.

Bradley, D., E. Huber, S. Moller, F. Nielsen, and J.D. Stephens. 2003. “Distribution andRedistribution in Postindustrial Democracies,” 55 World Politics 193–228.

Carey, J.M. 2000. “Parchment, Equilibria, and Institutions.” 33 Comparative Political Studies735–761.

Cingranelli, D., and R.L. David. 2008. “The Cingranelli-Richards (CIRI) human rights data projectcoding manual.”.

Congleton, R.D., and F. Bose. 2010. “The Rise of the Modern Welfare State, Ideology,Institutions and Income Security: Analysis and Evidence,” 144 Public Choice 535–555.

Cross, F.B. 1999. “The Relevance of Law in Human Rights Protection,” 19 International Review ofLaw and Economics 87–98.

Dahan, M., and M. Strawczynski. 2013. “Fiscal Rules and the Composition of GovernmentExpenditures in OECD Countries,” 32 Journal of Policy Analysis and Management484–504.

Davenport, C.A. 1996. “Constitutional Promises” and Repressive Reality: A Cross-National Time-Series Investigation of Why Political and Civil Liberties are Suppressed,” 58 Journal ofPolitics 627–654.

Elkins, Z., T. Ginsburg, and J. Melton. 2009. The Endurance of National Constitutions.Cambridge University Press.

Esping-Andersen, G. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, vol. 6. Cambridge: PolityPress.

Epp, C.R. 1998. The Rights Revolution: Lawyers, Activists, and Supreme Courts in ComparativePerspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Gutmann, J., B. Hayo, and S. Voigt. 2013. “9 Determinants of Constitutionally SafeguardedJudicial Review,” In Y.-c. Chang (ed.) Empirical Legal Analysis: Assessing the Performanceof Legal Institutions 216–254.

Hafner-Burton, E., L. Helfer, and C. Fariss. 2011. “Emergency and Escape: Explaining Derogationfrom Human Rights Treaties.” 65 International Organization 673–707.

Hardin, R. 1989. “Why a Constitution?’ in B. Grofman and D. Wittman, eds. Federalist Papersand the New Institutionalism, 100–120. New York: Agathon Press.

Hicks, A., J. Misra, and T.N. Ng. 1995. “The Programmatic Emergence of the Social SecurityState.” 60 American Sociological Review 329–349.

Constitutional Commitment 199

Page 36: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Hicks, A.M. 1999. Social Democracy & Welfare Capitalism: A Century of Income Security Politics.Cornell University Press.

Howard, R.M., and H.F. Carey. 2003. “Is an Independent Judiciary Necessary for Democracy,” 87Judicature 284.

Huber, E., C. Ragin, and J.D. Stephens. 1993. “Social Democracy, Christian Democracy,Constitutional Structure, and the Welfare State,” 99 American Journal of Sociology711–749.

Huber, E., and J.D. Stephens. 2001. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties andPolicies in Global Markets. Chicago USA: University of Chicago Press.

Hughes, M.M., L. Peterson, J.A. Harrison, and P. Paxton. 2009. “Power and Relation in the WorldPolity: The INGO Network Country Score, 1978–1998,” 87 Social Forces 1711–1742.

Iversen, T., and D. Soskice. 2006. “Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: WhySome Democracies Redistribute More Than Others,” 100 American Political ScienceReview 165.

Jensen, C. 2009. “Policy Punctuations in Mature Welfare States,” 29 Journal of Public Policy287–303.

Keith, L.C. 2002. “Constitutional Provisions for Individual Human Rights (1977–1996): Are TheyMore than Mere “Window Dressing?” 55 Political Research Quarterly 111–143.

Keith, L.C., C.N. Tate, and S.C. Poe. 2009. “Is the Law a Mere Parchment Barrier to HumanRights Abuse?” 71 Journal of Politics 644–660.

Korpi, W. 1983. The Democratic Class Struggle. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Korpi, W. 1989. “Power, Politics, and State Autonomy in the Development of Social Citizenship:

Social Rights During Sickness in Eighteen OECD Countries Since 1930,” 54 AmericanSociological Review 309–328.

Korpi, W., and J. Palme 1998. “The Paradox of Redistribution,” 63 American Sociological Review661–687.

Law, D.S., and M. Versteeg. 2013. “Sham Constitutions,” 101 California Law Review 863–952.Maddex, R.L. 1995. Constitutions of the World. Arlington, Virginia USA: CQ Press.Melton, J. 2012. “Do Constitutions Matter? The Relationship between De Jure and De Facto

Human Rights Protection.”Mulligan, C.B., R. Gil, and X. Sala-i-Martin. 2002. “Social Security and Democracy,” NBER

Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA.Mulligan, C.B., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. “Internationally Common Features of Public Old-Age

Pensions, and Their Implications for Models of the Public Sector,” 4 Advances in EconomicAnalysis & Policy 1–35.

Ordeshook, P.C. 1992. “Constitutional Stability,” 3 Constitutional Political Economy 137–175.Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2003. The Economic Effect of Constitutions. Cambridge, MA:MIT

Press.Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2004. “Constitutional Rules and Fiscal Policy Outcomes,” 94

American Economic Review 25–45.Powell, E.J., and J.K. Staton. 2009. “Domestic Judicial Institutions and Human Rights Treaty

Violation,” 53 International Studies Quarterly 149–174.Pritchard, K. 1986. “Comparative Human Rights: An Integrative Explanation.” 13 Politikon:

South African. Journal of Political Studies 24–37.Przeworski, A. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe

and Latin America. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press, 1991.

200 A. Ben-Bassat and M. Dahan

Page 37: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Rodrik, D. 1998. “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?” 106 Journal ofPolitical Economy 997–1032.

Social Security Throughout the World. 2004.Sunstein, C.R. 2005. “Why Does The American Constitution Lack Social and Economic

Guarantees,” 56 Syracuse Law Review 1–25.Swank, D. 2002. Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare

States. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.Tavares, J., and R. Wacziarg. 2001. “How Democracy Affects Growth,” 45 European Economic

Review 1341–1378.Tate, C.N., and L.C. Keith. 2007. “Conceptualizing and Operationalizing Judicial Independence

Globally,” Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, Illinois,August.

Weingast, B.R. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law.” 91American Political Science Review 245–263.

Wilensky, H. 1975. “The Welfare State and Equity.” Berkeley: University of Califomia.World Bank, World Development Indicators Database, various years.World Bank, Political Institutions Database, various years.

Constitutional Commitment 201

Page 38: Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional …public-policy.huji.ac.il/.upload/segel/MomiDahan/CCSSandWelfare... · Avi Ben-Bassat and Momi Dahan* Constitutional Commitment to

Copyright of Review of Law & Economics is the property of De Gruyter and its content maynot be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder'sexpress written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles forindividual use.