Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer...

83
Farm level policy scenario analysis EUR 24787 EN - 2011 Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer Editors: Pavel Ciaian and Sergio Gomez y Paloma

Transcript of Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer...

Page 1: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

Far

m le

vel p

olic

y sc

enar

io a

naly

sis

LF-N

A-24787-E

N-N

ISBN 978-92-79-19920-2

Farm level policy scenario analysis

EUR 24787 EN - 2011

9 789279 199202

Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer

Editors: Pavel Ciaian and Sergio Gomez y Paloma

Page 2: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 3: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

Farm level policy scenario analysis

Authors:

Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz

and Marcel Adenäuer

Editors:

Pavel Ciaian and Sergio Gomez y Paloma

2011

EUR 24787 EN

Page 4: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

European CommissionJoint Research Centre

Institute for Prospective Technological Studies

Contact informationAddress: Edificio Expo. c/ Inca Garcilaso, 3. E-41092 Seville (Spain)

E-mail: [email protected].: +34 954488318Fax: +34 954488300

http://ipts.jrc.ec.europa.euhttp://www.jrc.ec.europa.eu

Legal NoticeNeither the European Commission nor any person acting on behalf

of the Commission is responsible for the use which might be made of this publication.

Europe Direct is a service to help you find answersto your questions about the European Union

Freephone number (*):00 800 6 7 8 9 10 11

(*) Certain mobile telephone operators do not allow access to 00 800 numbers or these calls may be billed.

A great deal of additional information on the European Union is available on the Internet.

It can be accessed through the Europa serverhttp://europa.eu/

JRC 64334

EUR 24787 ENISBN 978-92-79-19920-2

ISSN 1831-9424doi:10.2791/57250

Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union

© European Union, 2011

Reproduction is authorised provided the source is acknowledged

Printed in Spain

The mission of the JRC-IPTS is to provide customer-driven support to the EU policy-making process by

developing science-based responses to policy challenges that have both a socio-economic as well as a

scientific/technological dimension.

Page 5: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

3

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisAcknowledgments

The project team would like to acknowledge the advice and assistance they received from Sergio

Gomez y Paloma and Pavel Ciaian (DG JRC/IPTS). We would also like to thank Maria Espinosa for her

final editorial comments on the draft (DG JRC/IPTS). On 25th January 2011, the results of this project were

presented at the Expert Workshop in Brussels. We are indebted to the participants of this workshop for

their constructive and helpful comments and recommendations.

Dr. Alexander Gocht, vTI Braunschweig, March 2011

Page 6: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

4

Tabl

e of

Con

tent

s Acronyms

AGLINK OECD Partial Equilibrium Model

BuR Bulgaria and Rumania

CAP Common Agricultural Policy

CAPRI Common Agricultural Policy Regionalised Impact Modelling System

(www.capri-model.org)

ESU Economic Size Unit

ESC Economic Size Class

EU European Union

EUROSTAT Statistical Office of the European Communities

EU-02 Bulgaria and Romania

EU-10 Member States that joined the European Union on 1 May 2004

EU-15 Member States of the European Union before 1 May 2004

EU-25 Member States of the European Union before 1 January 2007

EU-27 European Union after the enlargement on 1 January 2007

FADN Farm Accountancy Data Network

FSS Farm Structure Survey

GAEC Good agricultural and environmental condition

IPTS Institute for Prospective Technological Studies

LU Livestock Standard Unit

LDC Least developed countries

EBA Everything-But-Arms Initiative

ACP African, Caribbean, and Pacific states that are associated with the European Union

through the Lomé Convention

MS Member State(s)

NMS New Member State(s)

NPK Nitrogen, Phosphate and Potassium

NUTS Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics

Nuts1 Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics Level 1

Nuts2 Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics Level 2

REGIO Abbreviation for the regional domain at EUROSTAT

UAA Utilised Agricultural Area

SAPS Single Area Payment Scheme

SPS Single Payment Scheme (synonym includes SAPS, historic and regional SPS)

WTO World Trade Organisation

GSP General System of Preferences

Page 7: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

5

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisGlossary

CAPRI farm type layer: Synonym for the CAPRI model system when applied using the 1823 farm type

supply models instead of the 270 regional Nuts2 supply models.

A farm type is a single supply model in the CAPRI. With the exception of the residual farm type, each

farm type is characterised by one particular type of farming (13 aggregates) and economic size class (3

aggregates). A farm type also has a regional dimension, which refers to the MS and sub-regional level of

Nuts2.

A MS-aggregated farm type is an aggregate of farm types for one particular MS by type of farming and

economic size class.

An EU-aggregated farm type is an aggregate of farm types in the EU-25/15/10 by type of farming and

economic size class.

The baseline is the comparison point for counterfactual scenario analysis. For the current study, the

baseline is calibrated for the year 2020 based on trend estimation using ex-post data and projections.

The base year is the most recent year available from official statistics.

Bound tariffs are those tariffs that beyond which a country – particularly in the World Trade Organization

(WTO) context – has agreed to not increase the rate of duty. These tariffs are also known as Most Favoured

Nations (MFN) tariffs.

Applied tariffs are those that are actually applied by the country concerned. They may be the bound rate,

but frequently they are not.

Page 8: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 9: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

7

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisTable of Contents

Executive Summary 13

I. Introduction 17Project objective 17

Background 17

Characteristics of the farm type layer in CAPRI 18

Limitations of the approach 21

Scenario application with the farm type layer in this study 21

II. The Baseline 23Special characteristics of farm types 24

III. Scenario Analysis 29III.1. Direct Payment Scenario 29

Description 29

Results 30

Redistribution of decoupled payments among EU aggregated farm types 30

Redistribution of decoupled payments between regions 37

Impacts on land use and herd sizes 40

Impact on the agricultural market 40

Impact on income 48

Conclusion 53

III. 2. WTO Scenario 53

Description 55

Results 56

Conclusion 64

III.3 Macroeconomic Environment Scenario 65

Description 65

Results 66

Conclusions 72

IV. General Conclusions 75

References 77

Page 10: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 11: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

9

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisList of Tables

Table 1: Overview of CAPRI - farm type model characteristics 19

Table 2: Types of farming and economic size classes for the farm types 20

Table 3: Comparison between base year and baseline 23

Table 4: Policies included at baseline 24

Table 5: Overview of pillar 1 payments at baseline for different EU aggregates 24

Table 6: Indicators for different EU-25 aggregated farm types 25

Table 7: Overview of the sub-scenarios for the direct payment scenario 29

Table 8: Single payment scheme implementation (baseline and scenarios) 31

Table 9: Redistribution of decoupled payments among EU aggregates 31

Table 10: Redistribution of decoupled payments across EU-25 aggregated farm types 32

Table 11: Redistribution of decoupled payments across EU-15/EU-10 aggregated farm types 33

Table 12: Redistribution of decoupled payments at the MS leve 38

Table 13: Redistribution of decoupled payments at the Nuts2 level for all MS 39

Table 14: Summary of redistribution effects at the farm type, Nuts2 and MS levels 40

Table 15: Land use changes for different EU aggregates and MS countries 41

Table 16: Land use change in the EU for aggregated farm types 42

Table 17: Cropping changes for EU-25 aggregated farm types and EU aggregates 43

Table 18: Cropping changes for EU-25 aggregated farm types and EU aggregates (continued) 44

Table 19: Herd size changes for the EU-25 aggregated farm types, EU aggregates and MS 45

Table 20: Price changes for different EU aggregate 46

Table 21: Domestic demand and production changes for different EU aggregates 47

Table 22: Income changes for different EU aggregates 48

Table 23: Income changes at the MS level 49

Table 24: Aggregated income changes in the EU-25 by farm type 52

Table 25: Tariff reduction formula in the Falconer proposal 55

Table 26: Changes of TRQs and tariffs aggregated for all imports into the EU-27 56

Table 27: EU-27 welfare position changes in million € 57

Table 28: Land use changes for different EU aggregates and MS in the WTO scenario 58

Table 29: Herd-size changes for different EU aggregates and MS in the WTO scenario 59

Table 30: Income change in € per head for all activities in the WTO scenario 60

Table 31: Aggregated income change in the EU-25 by farm type in the WTO scenario 62

Table 32: Input categories dependent on crude oil price and transmission elasticities 64

Table 33: Overview of the macroeconomic environment scenario 65

Table 34: Price effects for different EU aggregates 66

Table 35: Market balance for different EU aggregates 68

Table 36: Production effects for EU-25 aggregated farm types 71

Table 37: Income effects for EU-25 aggregated farm types 73

Page 12: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 13: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

11

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisList of Figures

Figure 1: Cropping pattern for EU-25 aggregated farm types and EU-25 total 26

Figure 2: Herd sizes for EU-25 aggregated farm types and EU-25 total 26

Figure 3: Distribution of decoupled payments at baseline at the Nuts2 level in €/ha UAA 28

Figure 4: Redistribution of decoupled payments across farm types and scenarios 34

Figure 5: Redistribution of decoupled payments for the specialised cereals, oilseed and protein crops farm type 35

Figure 6: Redistribution of decoupled payments for the general field cropping and mixed cropping farm type 35

Figure 7: Redistribution of decoupled payments for specialised dairy farm types 36

Figure 8: Redistribution of decoupled payments for sheep, goats and other grazing livestock farm types 36

Figure 9: Redistribution of decoupled payments for residual farm types 37

Figure 10: Regional redistribution of decoupled payments in €/ha UAA 39

Figure 11: Cereal supply change in % relative to the baseline 48

Figure 12: Income changes in €/ha UAA 49

Figure 13: Income changes in the Nuts1 flat-rate scenario 50

Figure 14: Income changes in the MS flat-rate scenario 51

Figure 15: Income changes in the EU flat-rate scenario 52

Figure 16: Trade blocks in the CAPRI global market model 54

Figure 17: Changes of producer prices in the WTO scenario 57

Figure 18: Density of beef meat activity and change of income by Nuts2 region (WTO) 61

Figure 19: Income distribution in the WTO scenario 63

Figure 20: Change of income in €/ha UAA for important EU-25 farm types (WTO) 63

Figure 21: Area effects for selected EU-25 farm type aggregates 69

Figure 22: EU-27 aggregate land use shares for selected farm types 70

Figure 23: Relative stocking density changes in the ME-full scenario 72

Page 14: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 15: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

13

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisExecutive Summary

Section 1: Introduction

1. This study presents a quantitative policy impact analysis of alternative policy and macroeconomic

assumptions in the agricultural farming sector. Three scenarios are considered: direct payment

scenario, macroeconomic environment scenario and WTO scenario. The impact analyses are based

on the partial equilibrium CAPRI model. Unlike other CAPRI studies, we use the specific farm module

of CAPRI called CAPRI farm type (CAPRI FT) to complement the regional scenario analyses with

farm-level analyses. A unique characteristic of the farm-type component is its full integration into

the CAPRI modelling chain, which ensures price feedback based on sequential calibration with the

global, large-scale market model.

2. The CAPRI farm type comprises a maximum of nine of the most important farm types per Nuts2 region

plus a residual farm type that altogether represents the total regional production as well as input

use. The nine farm groups are characterised along two dimensions: “type of farming”, determined by

the farm’s production specialisation and “economic size class” of the farm, represented in terms of

“European size units”. This scheme results in 1823 farm supply models.

3. Equalisation of the large differences in decoupled payments between farms in the form of a flat-rate

scheme within the EU Member States and across the EU as a whole is currently being extensively

discussed in the context of the ongoing debate on the post-2013 Common Agricultural Policy (CAP).

The objective of the first direct payment scenario is to investigate the potential distributional and

market impacts of the implementation of more equitable decoupled payment schemes.

4. The food crisis in 2007/2008 demonstrated that agricultural prices are responsive to macro-level

pressures, such as crude-oil price changes and economic growth. In the second macroeconomic

environment scenario, we investigate the impact of recovery from the economic crises on the farming

sector.

5. Liberalisation of international trade is the major topic of the current WTO round, and although the

negotiations appear to be far from reaching an agreement, the third WTO scenario aims to quantify the

impact of a proposal made by the chair of the WTO’s agriculture negotiations, Ambassador Crawford

Falconer, in December 2008 (WTO, 2008).

Section 2: Baseline

6. The CAPRI baseline in 2020 is used as the comparison point for the scenarios, and its construction

relies on a combination of three information sources: the AGLINK baseline, an analysis of historical

trends and expert information. The CAPRI baseline includes recent assumptions about macroeconomic

drivers, such as GDP, population, oil price and the evolution of the CAP, in particular the expiration

of the milk quota system.

Page 16: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

14

Exec

utiv

e Su

mm

ary

Section 3: Direct payment scenario

7. The first scenario assumes equalisation of decoupled payments – a regional flat-rate scheme – at the

Nuts1 level. In addition, we simulate a flat-rate payment scheme at the MS and EU levels.

8. The study shows relatively minor allocative market responses and thus small price effects for all three

sub-scenarios. The market effects are mostly limited to adjustment of land use for those regions loosing

premiums, and slight substitution effects were observed in regions where premiums are differentiated

for arable land and grassland. Regions where the premiums increase are bounded by the entitlement

constraint; therefore, minor market implications exist.

9. Given that the historical and regional SPS models are strictly linked to coupled Pillar I support granted

under the Agenda 2000, the value of farm payments under these two SPS models reflects to a larger

extent the production specialisation and productivity of regions. A uniform flat rate tends to reduce

the support level in more productive regions and increase it in more marginal regions. Income effects

result mainly from the redistribution of decoupled payments because production and price effects of

the flat-rate scheme are small, having only minor impacts on farm income.

10. The value of payments reallocated between farms in the EU increases from 9% (3.7 billion €) of the

total CAP budget in the Nuts1 scenario (in which it mainly occurs in the EU-15 and is driven by MS,

which implements the historical SPS) to 19% (8.2 billion €) in the EU flat-rate scenario.

11. The scenario analyses show strong heterogeneous impacts of the introduction of the flat rate among

farm types. Particularly negatively affected categories are large and medium-sized farms and

dairies, mixed crops and livestock, general field and mixed cropping, olives, cereals and oilseeds

and permanent crops. Small farms tend to be less affected. However, sheep, goats and grazing, the

residual farm category and mixed livestock farms realise higher premiums and incomes.

12. The results reveal substantial redistributional effects within each farm type. Although a farm type

may lose payments on aggregate, not all individual farms included within this group may suffer. For

example, dairy farms lose 23.1% (1.133 billion €) of decoupled payments on aggregate in the EU

flat-rate scenario in the EU-25. Disaggregating this figure, 60% of the farms represented in the group

realise payment decreases equal to -1.4 billion €, whereas 40% of farms realise a payment increase of

0.27 billion €.

13. By assumption, the Nuts1 and MS flat rate has minor payment redistributional effects between MS.

On the contrary, the EU flat-rate scenario has a considerable impact on the redistribution of payments,

particularly between the old and new MS. In relative terms, the Netherlands (48%), Belgium (45%)

and Greece (44%) experience the highest relative losses, whereas the highest gains are observed in

new MS with large land endowments: Latvia (149 %), Romania (92%), Estonia (82%), Bulgaria (55%)

and Lithuania (54%). However, Portugal (43%) and Spain (35%) also gain considerable additional

payments through a EU-wide flat-rate scheme because of low initial support levels.

Page 17: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

15

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisSection 4: WTO Scenario

14. The focus of this scenario is the unique link between a spatial global market model and the farm

type supply models. This scenario aims to quantify the impact of a proposal made by the chair of the

WTO’s agriculture negotiations, Ambassador Crawford Falconer, in December 2008. He proposed

a general tariff reduction based on a tiered formula, a reduction of the TRQ in quota tariffs and the

possibility to exclude certain products, called sensitive products, at the cost of the extension of tariff

rate quotas for the sensitive-product imports.

15. The simulation results show that tariff reduction increases consumer welfare in the EU by 8.5 billion €,

whereas agricultural income decreases by 6.8 billion € (-3%), mainly driven by losses realised in the

animal sector that account for 5.5 billion €.

16. Reduced trade protection increases imports and decreases producer and market prices in the EU, in

particular for sugar (14%) and beef (13%) but also for butter (10%), cream (5%) and other fruits (5%).

17. The simulation shows that these price reductions translate into relatively small changes in agricultural

production of between 0% and -4% relative to the baseline level. Despite the moderate production

change, price reductions directly affect the farm income available to pay for the primary factors such

as land and labour.

18. The analysis shows sizable impacts on farm income for different farm types. Generally, farm types

specialised in livestock production lose the most. The largest negative income effects were observed

for cattle; dairying, rearing and fattening; dairy; mixed crops, livestock; and sheep and goat farm

types.

Section 5: Macroeconomic Environment Scenario

19. The macroeconomic environment is an important factor in determining the agricultural sector’s

development. We simulate the farm-level effects of a hypothetical economic recovery scenario that

may lead to higher GDP growth and higher oil prices. We assume two shocks: an increase in the

crude oil price by 50% and an annual world GDP growth rate increase of 1% (or 16% cumulative)

compared to baseline.

20. In general, the considered shocks lead to higher commodity prices, and the oil price shock also

causes higher production costs. An increase in the annual world GDP growth rate by 1% relative to

baseline causes stronger price effects than does the 50% increase in the oil price.

21. With the oil price shock, farmers are affected by two opposing market effects: an increase in production

costs and an increase in revenues. In most cases, increasing costs dominate such that the overall farm

income declines.

Page 18: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

16

Exec

utiv

e Su

mm

ary

22. The effect of higher GDP on income across farm types is generally positive due to the increasing

demand for agricultural products, which generates an increase in the prices of agricultural commodities.

Farmers react to the new macro environment with adjustments of their production. Thus, the effect

of the increased GDP leads to an increase in arable land and intensification of crop and animal

production activities. Furthermore, a tendency to substitute grassland for arable land can be observed,

particularly in farms other than those specialised in cattle or sheep and goat production.

Page 19: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

17

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisI. Introduction

Project objective

Consistent with the invitation to tender IPTS-

2009-J05-54-RC-AMI, three policy scenarios are

evaluated in this report. First, the direct payment

scenario is simulated. This scenario investigates

the impact of changing from the historical/

hybrid SPS model to a regional SPS model. In the

second macroeconomic environment scenario,

the recovery from the economic crises and its

impact on the agricultural sector are analysed.

The third scenario investigates the impact of a

WTO proposal. In addition to scenario analysis,

the modelling of the CAPRI farm type layer is

improved, and the base year data is updated

using the most recent available FSS and FADN

data. The baseline has been updated for the year

2020, and it is used as a counterfactual situation

for the scenario analysis. The report begins with

the background description of the CAPRI farm

type development conducted within this project,

followed by an overview of its characteristics

and limitations. Chapter 2 introduces the CAPRI

baseline. In Chapter 3, the three scenarios are

described, results presented and conclusions

drawn.

Background

The CAPRI modelling system was originally

developed to analyse policies at the regional

level in Europe. Mathematical programming (MP)

models were chosen to model policy-induced

production changes. Since then, these supply

models have been extended continually, now

covering the EU-27, Norway, the Western Balkans

and Turkey with 273 mathematical programming

(MP) models. They are defined at the level of

administrative units (Nuts2). The mathematical

programming models are conceptually an

effective device for explicitly modelling policy

interventions at the farm level, but policies at the

market level, such as tariffs, are modelled with

the spatial, global, multi-commodity model for

agricultural products. This market model covers

60 countries in 28 trade blocks worldwide. Three

trading regions cover the EU, namely the EU-15,

EU-10 as well as Bulgaria and Rumania (BuR).

The market model is a partial equilibrium

model, whereas the supply for the three

European regions is simulated by the 273 supply

programming models. To link the supply and

the market models, the behavioural parameters

for supply and feed demand for the countries

covered by the supply model are sequentially

updated based on the results of the market

model. This design makes it possible to explicitly

define policies in the mathematical programming

models for the EU while allowing for endogenous

for agricultural products. One should note that

the market model also simulates the demand in

the EU and supply, feed and processing demand

and human consumption based on specific

functional forms for all non-EU regions modelled.

An iterative approach is used to balance supply

and demand. It starts by using a given price,

simulating an EU-wide supply and introducing

the supply changes in the form of shocks in the

supply part of the market model to obtain a

new price. The price is used as an input for the

mathematical supply models, and this process is

repeated until supply and demand are balanced.

The shift from market to direct payment

support starting with the 1992 reform and

the introduction of farm-specific premium

schemes (e.g., stocking densities and decoupled

payments) motivated the development of a tool

that is disaggregated at the farm level and is

thus able to capture these changes in policies. A

farm type module was introduced in the CAPRI

model using the FADN (Farm Accountancy Data

Page 20: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

18

I. In

trod

ucti

on Network) and the FSS (Farm Structure Survey).

The FADN is the database most frequently used

to source EU farm type models. It comprises

single-farm observations of commercial farms

on production and sales values, production

activity levels, yields for selected activities

and input costs as well as information about

prices, subsidy payments, farm income and

other financial and economic variables. The

definitions in FADN are harmonised by EU

legislation, which also requires yearly updates

of the survey from the EU Member States.

The FADN, however, only covers a sample of

farms with aggregation weights attached, with

a somewhat low representativeness for less

frequent farm types and production activities.

The second data source, the FSS, mainly reports

data on the production activities based on a

sub-survey every third year and a complete

survey every tenth year. Both data sets exclude

small farms based on minimum economic

thresholds that vary among Member States, with

lower thresholds in the FSS and thus, better

representation compared to the FADN. Similarly,

some enterprises, such as highly commercialised

farms, are not obligated to provide accounting

information to the FADN but are included in the

FSS. The access to FADN and FSS data and the

support of several previous research projects1

made it possible to successfully develop farm

group supply models within the CAPRI modelling

framework. The farm groups are called “farm

types”, and the module is called the CAPRI

farm type layer (CAPRI-FT), which consists of

1823 farm supply models. The farm type layer

mainly aims to capture heterogeneity in farming

specialisation and economic size within a region

to reduce aggregation bias in the response of the

agricultural sector to policy and market signals.

This model extension is especially important

when the simulated policy instruments are farm

specific, as is the case of the historical SPS, or

when the instruments are modulated depending

on farm characteristics. Additionally, the farm

1 http://www.capri-model.org/projects.htm

type layer might allow future extension of the

model to account for farm structural change.

Characteristics of the farm type layer in CAPRI

One important characteristic of the CAPRI-

FT is its full integration in the CAPRI modelling

chain, which ensures that price feedback is based

on sequential calibration with the global, large-

scale market model (Table 1).

Endogenous prices in the CAPRI-FT are

an important advantage relative to other farm

models used in the literature. In general, other

EU farm models, such as the AROPAj system

(Baranger et al., 2008), FARMIS (Offermann et

al., 2005) and LUAM (Jones et al., 1995), are

representative models for a given EU region.

They are simulated based on mathematical

modelling and are sourced from the FADN

database (similar to CAPRI-FT), but an important

weakness is that these models are stand-alone

supply models in which prices are assumed to be

exogenous. Linking the farm models to existing

market models is a challenging task due to data

gaps, differences in product definitions, and the

mismatch between data sets that are available

at the farm level and the underlying market-

level data. The strict and consistent top-down

consistency of the farm type layer available in

CAPRI-FT ensures a harmonised data set across

regional scales and farm types.

The farm type supply module in CAPRI

consists of independent aggregate nonlinear

programming models for each farm type

aggregated over all activities belonging to a given

farm type and a specific administrative regional

unit at the Nuts2 level. In this approach, there is

a compromise between a pure LP approach and

the fully econometrically estimated one. The

compromise is achieved by combining a Leontief

technology for variable costs, covering low- and

high-yield variants for the different production

activities, with a partly econometrically estimated

Page 21: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

19

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

behavioural function (Jansson and Heckelei,

2011) based on the positive mathematical

programming (PMP) approach (Howitt, 1995).

The nonlinear cost function captures the effects

of labour and capital on farmers’ decisions. Its

advantage is that it allows perfect calibration

of the supply models and smooth simulation of

responses to policy changes. The farm models,

similar to the regional models, capture the

premiums paid under the CAP in great detail;

they include NPK balances and a module with

feeding activities that accounts for the nutrient

requirements of animals. In addition to the feed

constraint, other model constraints relate to

land supply and subsitution between grass and

arable land. Prices are exogenous in the supply

module, but they are endogenously determined

by the market module in an iterative process

solved between the supply and market modules

until convergence is reached. Grass, silage

and manure are assumed to be non-tradable

and are assigned internal prices based on their

substitution values and opportunity costs.

The CAPRI farm type module comprises

a maximum of nine of the most important farm

types per region plus a residual farm type,

altogether representing total regional production

as well as input and primary factor use. The

nine farm groups are characterised along two

dimensions (Table 2): (i) by the “type of farming”,

determined by the farm production specialisation,

as defined by the relative contributions of

different production branches to the gross margin

Table 1: Overview of CAPRI - farm type model characteristics

Type of model Independent aggregate non linear programming models

Components of the model Compromise between a pure LP approach and the fully econometrically estimated one, extending PMP

Objective function Maximizing differences between revenues plus premiums minus variable cost and a cost component from the quadratic cost function

Capital and Labour Effects of labour and capital on farmers decisions caught by the cost function

Land Endogenous land supply function consists of a three-tier land allocation model that allocates between agricultural land and land for other uses (e.g., grassland versus arable land) and allocates by land use based on various crop and grassland intensities

Nutrient balance NPK balances; feeding activities covering nutrient requirements of animals

Constraints Feed block, total land use, set-aside obligations and quotas

Prices

tradable products Are exogenous in the supply module and are provided by the market module, with which they are solved sequentially until convergence.

non-tradable products Grass, silage and manure are assumed to be non-tradable and receive internal prices based on their substitution value and opportunity costs

Calibration of the base year The cost function allows both for perfect calibration of the models and a smooth simulation response

Farm Types in CAPRI

Total No. EU-25 1823

Total no.of supply models 1888

No.per Nuts2 Maximum of nine of the most important farm types per region plus a residual farm group

Integration into CAPRI

Methodology Full integration in the CAPRI modelling chain, which ensures price feedback based on sequential calibration with the global, large-scale market model, strict and consistent top-down disaggregation approach in the baseline; obtaining a harmonised data set across regional scales and farm types

IT Where possible, CAPRI-FT uses the same GAMS routines as the regional supply models

Page 22: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

20

I. In

trod

ucti

on

of the farm (European Commission, CD 85/377/

EEC, Article 6) and (ii) the “economic size class”

of the farm, represented in terms of “European

size units” (ESU). The EU classification scheme

allows for a far more detailed characterisation

of a farm’s specialisation. The choice of 13 farm

specialisations is a compromise between model

complexity, robustness of the result, reporting

limitations and data constraints. In particular, the

data confidentiality issues that are highlighted

when using more disaggregated types in regional

aggregates render it suitable to adhere to the

classification shown in Table 2. Additionally,

higher farm disaggregation would increase the

complexity of the results without adding value in

terms of policy-relevant reporting of the model

results. Similar arguments support the use of only

three economic farm size classes (ESC), defined

as ESC 1 for farms smaller than 16 ESU, ESC 2 for

farms of at least 16 ESU but less than 100 ESU,

and ESC 3 for farms of 100 ESU or larger. In total,

this leads to 13*3=39 cells in the overall farm

typology.

From these 39 possible farm types, up to

9 of the most important farm types are selected

in each Nuts2 region. The farm selection is

based on two criteria: livestock units (LU) and

utilised agricultural area (UAA). Both criteria

were assigned equal priority (equal weights) in

determining the importance of each farm type.

Compared to other weighting systems based

on the number of farms, economic indicators,

area farmed or livestock numbers, this approach

provides a compromise between the economic,

social and environmental aspects of farming. For

further information on the methodology of the

construction of the farm type layer, see Gocht

(2010a), (2010b) and Gocht and Britz (2011).

The farms that are not represented by the 9 most

important farm types are included in the residual

farm type. The restriction to 10 farm groups

(the 9 most important groups plus the residual

farm group) per region is based on storage and

computing time considerations as well as the

need to keep the database and model outputs at

a manageable size for quality control and result

analysis.

The CAPRI supply module covers 27 EU

Member States and nine non-EU countries, each

of which are split into several Nuts2 sub-regions.

With the introduction of the farm type layer,

a Nuts2 region has at most 10 farm types. The

CAPRI-FT covers the EU-25, whereas BuR, due to

missing FADN statistics, are represented only by

the Nuts2 supply models. In summary, there are

1,888 mathematical supply models for the EU-27

in total; 1,823 are farm type models for the EU-

25, and 65 are Nuts2 supply models for BuR.

Table 2: Types of farming and economic size classes for the farm types

Type of farming Economic size class

Specialist cereals, oilseed and protein crops 13 ESC 1 < 16 ESU

General field cropping + Mixed cropping 14_60 ESC 2 ≥ 16 ≤ 100 ESU

Specialist horticulture 20 ESC 3 > 100 ESU

Specialist vineyards 31

Specialist fruit and citrus fruit 32

Specialist olives 33

Various permanent crops combined 34

Specialist dairying 41

Specialist cattle + dairying rearing, fattening 42_43

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 44

Specialist granivores 50

Mixed livestock holdings 70

Mixed crops-livestock 80

Page 23: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

21

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisLimitations of the approach

One of the main drawbacks of the CAPRI-

FT approach is the use of structurally identical,

stylised and relatively simple template models in

which differences between farm types and regions

are expressed solely by parameters. This approach

might not completely capture the full diversity

of farming systems in Europe. In particular, the

evaluation of policy measures that impact farm

management decisions, such as manure handling

or feeding practices, demands models that

include these factors as decision variables. The

relatively simple representation of agricultural

technology in CAPRI compared to approaches

that are parameterised based on biophysical

models narrows the scope of extensions in that

direction. The potential of the current template

has not yet been fully exploited in CAPRI,

although the dichotomy between increased detail

for specific activities, regions and farm types and

a structurally identical template model remains.

Updating and maintaining a regional database

with an additional breakdown by farm type

requires more resources, as does the application

of the enlarged simulation tool.

Scenario application with the farm type layer in this study

The scenarios make use of the farm type

layer with respect to the explicit and detailed

implementation of the SPS (single payment

scheme) at the farm type level. Farm-related

premium, income and cost effects can thus be

analysed also with respect to the type of farming

and the economic size. The top-down Pillar 1

distribution, considering the ceilings values from

the regulatory texts, across the sector, regions and

farm types, provides a complete picture of the

premium distribution. In addition, the economic

model available behind each farm type ensures

that policy impacts on land rents and land-

use changes can be analysed. This capability is

particularly relevant for the flat-rate scenario.

In addition, the unique link between the farm

supply models and the agricultural trade model

is used to analyse the full range of tariff cuts and

CAP measures in the macroeconomic and WTO

scenarios at the farm level. For example, in the

macroeconomic scenario, impacts of higher GDP

growth world wide on global and EU agricultural

markets are simulated. This effect, in turn, affects

income, production, and input use at the farm

level. Note that the response behaviour of the

CAPRI farm type model also changes as compared

to the CAPRI Nuts2 regional model due to a

reduced aggregation error. Farm supply models

behave more restrictively than the Nuts2 supply

models. Typically, each individual farm type

model comprises less activities and thus a smaller

production possibility set compared to the more

aggregated NUTS2 models. For example, a farm

type specialised in cereals, oilseed and protein

cannot easily change production specialisation

(e.g., to a sheep and goat farm type) due to

restrictions in land endowment, education,

machinery and other farm resources, even in

the presence of price and/or policy incentives.

However, if modelled at the regional Nuts2 level,

the farm would be less restricted in its ability

to adjust its production behaviour because the

constraints are aggregated over all farms in the

region, thus making more resources available for

all of the production activities in the region.

Page 24: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 25: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

23

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisII. The Baseline

An important component of the scenario

analysis is the CAPRI baseline. The baseline is

used as a comparison point for the scenarios.

Assumptions underlying and information

included in the baseline are discussed in

this chapter. First, we briefly motivate the

methodology and provide an overview of

the different policy and macroeconomic

assumptions. A detailed description can be

found in Britz & Witzke (2009). The CAPRI

baseline construction relies on a combination

of three information sources: the AGLINK

baseline2, an analysis of historical trends

and expert information. The most relevant

information is a preliminary AGLINK baseline

prepared for this project at the IPTS in

October 2009. It includes recent assumptions

on macroeconomic drivers, such as GDP,

population, oil price and the evolution of the

CAP, in particular the expiry of the milk quota

system. Important economic variables from

the baseline are summarised in Table 3.

2 BLANCO FONSECA, M., ET AL.: IPTS Agro-Economic Modeling Platform: Bio fuel Modeling (AGLINK, ESIM, CAPRI). JRC - IPTS, Seville, 2009

Table 3: Comparison between base year and baseline

Base year 2005 Baseline 2020

Political variables

Milk Quota EU-25 in million tonnes 133 -

Sugar Quota EU-27 in 1.000 tonnes 17.000 12.400

Macroeconomic Assumptions (EU-27)

Population growth in % p.a. - 0,04%

Crude oil price in $ per barrel 38 104

Inflation in % p.a. - 1,90%

Other Trends (EU-27)

New energy crops second generation in 1.000 hectares 0 1.500

Prices for important products (EU-27, €/t)

Cereals 104 140

Oilseeds 202 224

Beef 1.714 2.507

Dairy products 1.282 1.393

Struktural change

EU-25 No. of Holdings in Mio 10,2

constant EU-15 No. of Holding in Mio 6,6

EU-10 No. of Holding in Mio 3,6

Land Use (EU27, 1000 ha)

Used Agricultural Area 191.272 187.419

Pasture 65.309 64.910

Arable land 125.962 122.509

Page 26: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

24

II. T

he B

asel

ine

Because the regional resolution of the

AGLINK baseline is limited to EU aggregates, the

baseline draws additionally on national expert

information. Furthermore, the baseline includes

specific expert information from the PRIMES

energy model for the bio-fuel sector and expert

projections from the seed manufacturer KWS for

the sugar sector. Trends and expert information

combined might be inconsistent and might violate

basic technical constraints, such as crop area

and/or young animal balances. Consequently,

all expert information is usually provided in the

form of target values. For consistency reasons

(such as production quantity equalisation with

activity levels and yields), deviations from target

values are allowed; however, to avoid large

deviations, they are penalised during the model

estimation process. Another important input into

the baseline constructions is detailed information

on policy measures. The policy assumptions

complete the definition of the CAPRI baseline

and, together with other data, form the basis of

parameter calibration. The baseline represents the

starting point (the counterfactual situation) for the

subsequent scenario analysis. Table 4 provides an

overview of the policy reforms implemented in

the baseline for this study.

Table 5 summarises the total direct payments

on gross value added amongst MS aggregated

according to baseline farm types.

Special characteristics of farm types

We now briefly discuss additional

assumptions made for the farm type baseline.

Generally, it would be desirable to distinguish two

different forms of development in the baseline

projections for particular farm types: production

development (crop allocation and animal herd

size) of each farm type and composition, which

is the number of farms in a group. This distinction

is not possible with the current version, but the

Table 4: Policies included at baseline

Baseline 2020

Common Agriculturel Policy Reforms

.. of the Milk Market milk quota removed

.. of Mid Term Review historical SPS, flat-rate and SAPS for new MS

.. of the Sugar MarketReform of the CMO sugar of 2006 implemented. Sugar quotas fixed on the 2009 values. Ethanol beets introduced

.. Helth Check further decoupling of payments for olive and hops; beef and veal, protein crops, rice; removal set aside obligation; increase of modulation distributed over four steps beginning in 2009;

Table 5: Overview of pillar 1 payments at baseline for different EU aggregates

EU-27 EU-25 EU-15 EU-10 Bulgaria Romania

€ Million

Sum of Pillar I Payments 42.919 40.406 33.918 6.489 810 1.703

coupled (partially)

Wine sector 352 352 352

Suckler cow premium 1.171 1.171 1.171

Sheep and goat 394 394 394

decoupled

Single area payment scheme SAPS 8.855 6.342 6.342 810 1.703

Regional flat rate premium flat-rate SPS 9.018 9.018 9.018

Farm specific payment historical SPS 22.746 22.746 22.600 146

Hybrid premium farm flat-rate + historical SPS 382 382 382

Page 27: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

25

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisdevelopment of a structural change module that

will address these shortcomings is foreseen within

the medium-term development of the system.

The main constraint for this development is the

missing time-series data for the evaluation of farm

groups and their production structures to build

trend forecasts and expectations for baseline

routines. Accordingly, a different approach has

been chosen in the current version. The prior

information is obtained by multiplying the base

period value of a variable of interest (e.g., hectares

for a crop, herd sizes, input-output coefficients)

for a given farm type by the ratio between the

projected value at the Nuts2 level and the Nuts2

base year value of the variable. The following

consistency conditions are imposed during the

projection, similar to those used at the Nuts2 level:

(1) production and total input use are derived

from activity levels and input-output coefficients;

(2) the UAA must equal the sum of the crop

area; (3) nutrient requirements (protein, energy,

different types of fibre) for each animal must be

in balance with the deliveries from feeding; (4)

own-produced fodder (grass, silage maize, fodder

root crops, and other fodder from arable land)

must be used within the same farm type; (5) the

sum of the crop area and the animals across all

farm types must equal Nuts2 values; (6) the sum

of the production and input use across all farm

types must be equal to Nuts2 values; and (7) the

weighted average of feed input coefficients must

be equal to those observed at the Nuts2 level. The

Table 6: Indicators for different EU-25 aggregated farm types

EU-25 EU-15 EU-10

No. o

f Far

m S

uppl

y M

odel

s

Utili

zed

Agric

ultu

ral A

rea

No. o

f Hol

ding

s

Live

stoc

k Un

its

No. o

f Far

m S

uppl

y M

odel

s

Utili

zed

Agric

ultu

ral A

rea

No. o

f Hol

ding

s

Live

stoc

k Un

its

No. o

f Far

m S

uppl

y M

odel

s

Utili

zed

Agric

ultu

ral A

rea

No. o

f Hol

ding

s

Live

stoc

k Un

its

Type of Farming No. Million No. Million No. Million

Cereals, oilseed & protein crops 245 32,20 1,00 2,10 173 25,60 0,70 1,90 72 6,60 0,30 0,20

General field & mixed cropping 251 20,00 1,80 3,70 201 14,90 0,90 3,00 50 5,10 0,90 0,70

Dairying 235 16,90 0,50 19,40 205 15,30 0,40 18,50 30 1,70 0,20 0,90

Cattle- Dairying -rearing & fattening 149 11,70 0,40 12,00 133 10,90 0,30 11,60 16 0,80 0,10 0,40

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 172 15,50 0,50 6,90 159 15,10 0,40 6,80 13 0,40 0,00 0,10

Granivores 118 2,70 0,20 10,20 76 1,60 0,00 8,80 42 1,00 0,20 1,40

Mixed livestock holdings 85 5,10 0,50 5,10 53 1,80 0,10 3,00 32 3,30 0,40 2,10

Mixed crops-livestock 276 19,80 0,90 13,00 214 12,70 0,30 11,00 62 7,10 0,70 2,00

Vineyards 22 1,40 0,20 0,10 21 1,40 0,20 0,10 1

Fruit and citrus fruit 13 0,60 0,20 0,10 13 0,60 0,20 0,10

Olives 25 3,60 0,80 0,20 25 3,60 0,80 0,20

Permanent crops mixed 16 0,50 0,20 0,10 15 0,50 0,20 0,10 1

Horticulture 5 0,10 5 0,10

Economic Size Class

<=16 ESU 486 36,60 6,00 11,90 342 22,40 3,20 7,50 144 14,20 2,70 4,40

>16 and <=100 ESU 673 56,80 1,00 36,20 602 52,80 1,00 34,70 71 3,90 0,10 1,50

>100 ESU 453 36,60 0,20 24,80 349 28,80 0,20 22,80 104 7,80 2,00

Residual 211 39,50 3,10 16,60 170 32,70 2,30 15,00 41 6,80 0,80 1,50

Total 1.823 169,40 10,20 89,40 1.463 136,70 6,60 80,00 360 32,80 3,60 9,40

Page 28: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

26

II. T

he B

asel

ine

prior information for the different data elements

at the farm type level is defined from the base

year results of each farm type and the projected

changes over time in the related Nuts2 regions.

Generally, all variables are solved simultaneously

to account for the interactions between crops

and animals in the estimation procedure. The

boundaries surrounding the prior information

help to ensure the plausibility of the obtained

results. Developments in acreage and herd size

based on farm type at baseline are captured by

the set of relative changes projected at the Nuts2

Figure 1: Cropping pattern for EU-25 aggregated farm types and EU-25 total

Figure 2: Herd sizes for EU-25 aggregated farm types and EU-25 total

Page 29: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

27

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysislevel. If no feasible solution is found, the limits

are relaxed. The approach guarantees identical

results for the baseline at the MS and regional

Nuts2 levels from model versions both including

and excluding particular farm types.

Table 6 shows the number of farm types

per type of farming and economic size class

separately for the EU-25, EU-15 and EU-10.

In addition, it presents the utilised agricultural

area (UAA) and the livestock units (LU) of each

farm type at baseline. In addition, the number of

holdings each farm type represents is provided.

This value is obtained from the base year

statistic. Note that the total numbers in the last

row of Table 5 are calculated either by adding

the residual farm type to all type of farming

rows or by adding the economic size classes.

The table shows that specialised cereals, oilseeds

and protein crops are represented in the model

by 245 supply models, which together represent

32.2 million hectares UAA and 2.1 million LU.

In the base year 2005, approximately 1 million

farms were represented by this type of farming.

Table 6 also indirectly shows the stocking

density; in particular, granivores have a very high

stocking density of 3.7 LU per hectare of UAA.

In Figure 1 and Figure 2, the compositions of

the different farm types with respect to cropping

pattern and herd size (in LU) are presented. The

pie chart in Figure 1 shows the total land use for

the EU-25. Almost half of the land (84.2 million

ha) is used for fodder production, which includes

maize silage, grassland and other fodder on

arable land. Another 42 million ha are cultivated

with cereals, 7.9 million ha with fallow land or

set aside, 14.5 million ha with vegetables, 8.7

million ha with oilseed and 8.4 million ha with

other arable crops, such as potatoes, pulses and

sugar beets. In the bar chart, the first twelve bars

present the composition of land use per type of

farming, while the last four present land use with

respect to the economic size class and for the

residual farm type. The land use allocation has a

specific composition in each of the farm types.

For example, the following farm types mainly

have fodder area under cultivation: dairying;

cattle-dairying, rearing and fattening; and sheep,

goats and other grazing livestock. However,

cereals and other crops are mostly cultivated in

specialised cereal farms. Vineyards, fruit, citrus,

horticulture and permanent crops mixed farm

types are not often represented as specific farm

types due to their low importance compared to

other farm types at the Nuts2 level in terms of

land use and animal stocking density. These farm

types are mostly aggregated into the residual farm

type, as is shown by the high share of permanent

cropping areas in this farm type.

Figure 2 characterises animal production

activities measured in livestock units. The total

livestock units in the EU-25 are 89.4 million LU

(se also Table 6). The animal aggregate of cows,

cattle for raising activities and calf fattening,

accounts for almost 33 million LU, followed by

cattle for beef meat production with 23.8 million

LU and veal production, with 22 million LU.

Figure 3 provides an overview of the

distribution of the coupled payments per hectare

of UAA across the EU-27 at baseline. In the EU-

27, all decoupled payments are more than 50 €

per ha (aggregated at the Nuts2 level). Only the

Western Balkans (light green area) have a support

level that is well below this value.

Several Nuts2 regions in Spain, France,

Austria, Latvia and Finland (shown in green) have

payments between 50 and 100 €/ha UAA. Regions

with a low stocking density and low historical

yields (EU-15) receive payments below the EU-

27 average of 227 €/ha. The areas represented in

orange, which are regions with payments greater

than 100 €/ha but less than 200 €/ha, are below

the EU-27 average. Many regions in northern

Spain, the South of France, Scotland, Sweden and

the majority of regions in the new MS (Poland,

Bulgaria, Romania, Estonia and Lithuania)

receive similar levels of payments, indicating that

a EU-wide flat rate will not only affect regions in

the new MS but also some regions in Southern

Europe and Scotland. The blue regions receive

Page 30: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

28

II. T

he B

asel

ine

payments greater than 200 €/ha and lower than

350 €/ha. The turquoise areas receive payments

greater than 350 €/ha and lower than 450 €/ha

UAA. The Netherlands, southern Italy and Greece

(olive support) receive the highest payments, at

more than 450 €/ha.

Figure 3: Distribution of decoupled payments at baseline at the Nuts2 level in €/ha UAA

Page 31: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

29

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisIII. Scenario Analysis

For the current study, three scenarios were

analysed: the direct payment scenario, discussed

in Section III.1; a macroeconomic scenario,

discussed in Section III.2; and the WTO proposal,

discussed in Section III.3.

III.1. Direct Payment Scenario

The first scenario is a regional flat rate

introduced at the Nuts1 level. In addition, we

simulated flat-rate premiums at the MS and EU

levels, as summarised in Table 7. The following

chapter includes a brief methodological

description of how the direct payments are

defined and implemented in the model.

Description

The SPS is a payment obtained from the

decoupling of direct premiums from production

that was introduced as part of the CAP Mid Term

Review 20033. This payment was distributed to

farmers in two different ways: 4

3 The EU flat-rate amount (227 €/ha) is calculated by dividing the total EU-27 SPS payments by the UAA at baseline.

4 COUNCIL REGULATION (EC) No 1782/2003 of 29 September 2003 establishes common rules for direct support schemes under the common agricultural policy as well as certain support schemes for farmers and amending regulations.

• First, single payments are calculated at

the farm level. Under this scheme, the SPS

payments remain farm specific and equal the

value of coupled payments received in the

reference period. Next, the SPS entitlement

value per hectare is calculated by dividing

the reference coupled premium endowment

by the farm reference area. This SPS model is

abbreviated as “historic SPS” in this report.

• Second, the total amount of payments is

averaged over a region on a hectare basis.

The sum of payments received by all farmers

in a particular area during the reference

period is divided by the number of eligible

hectares in that region. This results in a

uniform hectare premium and is abbreviated

in this report as “regional SPS”.

The Member States had to opt for one SPS

category. The regional SPS could be combined

with a farm-specific top-up, which is known as

a hybrid SPS scheme. This scheme can be fixed

or may vary over time, leading to a so-called

Table 7: Overview of the sub-scenarios for the direct payment scenario

Scenario Description Assumptions

Nuts1 flat rate Regional SPS at the Nuts1 level For countries with no Nuts1 region, a regional flat rate is applied at the Nuts2 level.

MS flat rate Regional SPS across the country

EU flat rate 227 € per hectare across the EU-274

Page 32: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

30

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

fixed or dynamic SPS. In the EU-15, ten MS opted

solely for the historical SPS, whereas the rest

opted for the hybrid flat-rate scheme. In the EU-

12, Slovenia and Malta implemented the regional

SPS from the beginning, whereas the other

nations implemented the Single Area Payment

Scheme (SAPS). This is a scheme of a uniform per-

hectare payment similar to the regional SPS but

without a historical reference area. The SAPS was

introduced at 25% from the start of accession

(in 2004 for the EU-10 and 2007 for BuR) and

gradually increased to 100% over ten years.5

The CAPRI farm type layer allows the shift

from a historical SPS to a regional SPS to be

analysed. In countries with a historical SPS, farm

types have different values for their premium

rights depending on the production structure and

coupled payments in the reference period. For

example, a specialised cattle farm could have

received more coupled premiums per hectare due

to higher amounts of coupled cattle premiums

than another farm type in the region. A shift to

a flat-rate scheme in the region would decrease

the payments for the cattle farm but increase

the payments for other farm types in the region,

given that the total amount of SPS in the region

is constant. This result would affect the income

situation and agricultural markets when land use

changes occur. Alongside production and input

effects, the flat-rate scheme also alters prices.

The price changes are iteratively obtained from

the market model in the CAPRI. Thus, the aim

of the scenarios is to analyse the redistribution

effect and resulting production, price and income

changes.

Methodologically, we first calculate

all premiums given to a farm type based on

information from legal documents, which are

mapped onto the production activity units of

5 Note that the new MS are allowed to grant complementary national direct payments (CNDP) to farms up to 30% of the total value of the subsidy ceiling. In the CAPRI model, the CNDP is assumed to be granted until 2013 in the EU-12 and until 2016 in BuR and thus is not included in the 2020 baseline.

the model. The premium amount per production

activity is then adjusted considering the available

direct payment ceiling in a given region/MS in

either monetary terms or in numbers. The SPS

implementation in the model is achieved as

follows. The level of decoupling determines the

total value of SPS in a given region/MS. The total

SPS value is then averaged over the Nuts1, MS

or EU, depending on the sub-scenario. During

the model run, all payments are simulated as

endogenous contributions to the objective

function, where the sum of payments over all

farms is constrained during the iteration to

comply with regional premium ceiling values.

For each farm type, entitlements are defined as

follows: from the reference production in the

case of MS-15 and from the baseline production

in the case of MS-10, Bulgaria and Romania.

If the UAA overshoots the entitlements, the

next marginal hectare will not receive the flat-

rate premium, and the land market will not

be affected by the payment. The entitlements

are assumed to be non-tradable between the

farm types and regions. Table 8 summarises

the SPS implementation at baseline and in the

scenarios.

In the EU-15, all historical SPS are

moved to a uniform flat rate. In the EU-10, the

implementation was not changed for the SAPS,

with the exceptions of Slovenia and Malta.

Results

We begin with the analysis of the

redistribution effects of decoupled payments at

different aggregation levels. Next, we present the

market impacts of the scenarios on herd sizes,

cropping and land use and analyse the effects on

agricultural markets and prices. We finish with

the farm income analysis.

Redistribution of decoupled payments among

EU aggregated farm types

Table 9 presents the redistribution of

decoupled payments between different EU

Page 33: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

31

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

aggregates. At baseline, the spending on

decoupled payments totals 42.8 billion € in the

EU-27. The scenario simulations reveal that this

level of expenditure does not change much at

the EU-27 level in all three flat-rate schemes

(-0.7% Nuts1, -0.6% MS and -1% MS flat rate).

For the Nuts1 and MS flat-rate scenarios, the

respective changes for the EU-25, EU-15, EU-

10 and BuR are also small. In the EU-15, the

changes are driven by market effects (e.g., land

use changes and price changes; see below).

Most new MS already implement a flat-rate

system at baseline (except for Slovenia and

Malta), so there are no redistribution, payment

and/or market effects. For the EU flat-rate

scenario, approximately 3.15 billion € are

redistributed between the EU-15, EU-10 and

BuR.6 The simulations reveal that the EU-15

will lose -3.4 billion €, whereas the EU-10 and

BuR will gain approximately 1 billion € and

1.94 billion €, respectively.

6 This value is obtained as the sum divided by the absolute deviation compared to the baseline and multiplied by 0.5 to obtain the amount of payment flow between regions.

Table 8: Single payment scheme implementation (baseline and scenarios)

CAPRI Baseline2020

Direct payment Scenario

CAPRI Baseline 2020

Direct payment Scenario

Countriesregional

SPShistoric

SPS

Hybrid premium

farm

flat- rate SPS

Countries SAPSregional

SPSSAPS

regional SPS

EU-15 EU-10

Belgium x x Czech Republic x x

Denmark x x x x Estonia x x

Germany x x Hungary x x

Austria x x Lithuania x x

Netherlands x x Latvia x x

France x x Poland x x

Portugal x x Slovenia x x

Spain x x Slovak Republic x x

Greece x x Cyprus x x

Italy x x Malta x x

Ireland x x

Finland x x x x

Sweden x x x x

United Kingdom x x x x

Table 9: Redistribution of decoupled payments among EU aggregates

EU-Aggregates and MS

Baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

EU-Aggregate Million € change to Baseline % to Baseline

EU-27 42.834 -320 -244 -430,0 -0,7 -0,6 -1,0

EU-25 40.419 -320 -244 -2.371,6 -0,8 -0,6 -5,9

EU-15 33.953 -318 -243 -3.365,5 -0,9 -0,7 -9,9

EU-10 6.466 -1 -1 994,0 -0,0 -0,0 15,4

Bulgaria 755 0 0 415,1 0,0 0,0 55,0

Romania 1.660 0 0 1.526,4 0,0 0,0 91,9

Page 34: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

32

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

In Table 10, the redistribution effects are

analysed by farming type for the EU-25.7 Note

that each farm type has a type of farming and

an economic size class attribute, except for the

residual farm type. Thus, we can analyse the

changes by aggregating different types of farming,

notwithstanding the economic size class, and

vice versa. The total effects can be obtained

by considering either all types of farming or all

economic size classes together with the residual

farm type.

The level of redistributed payments

increases with the increasing regional scope

of the implementation (i.e., Nuts1-MS-EU). In

relative terms, the biggest gainers are sheep,

goats and other grazing livestock, vineyards

and residual farm types. These types receive,

on average, low levels of initial support per

7 Bulgaria and Romania have no farm types in the CAPRI-FT; thus, they are not included in tables where results for farm types are presented.

hectare. The biggest losers are olives and

permanent crops mixed because of their high

level of initial support. Other farms that lose

support are those specialised in cereals, oilseeds

and protein crops, general field cropping, dairy

farms and mixed crops and livestock as well as

large farms. Small farms (less than 16 ESU) are

affected little by the flat rate, whereas big farms

lose.

Table 11 further disaggregates the results

for the EU-15 and EU-10. For the Nuts1 and

MS flat-rate scenarios, the value of redistributed

payments is almost zero in the EU-10 because

of the SAPS, which is also based on a flat-rate

payment system. The exceptions are Slovenia

and Malta, which implement the historical

SPS; thus, small effects are observed in the EU-

10. In the EU-15, the redistributional effects

are significant because payments vary greatly

between farms under the SPS. The redistribution

effects for the EU-15 are similar to the figures

reported in Table 10.

Table 10: Redistribution of decoupled payments across EU-25 aggregated farm types

EU-25

Baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Type of Farming Million € change to Baseline % to Baseline

Cereals, oilseed & protein crops 7.729 -403 -615 -502,9 -5,2 -8,0 -6,5

General field & mixed cropping 5.423 -415 -580 -963,0 -7,7 -10,7 -17,8

Dairying 4.912 -471 -588 -1.133,1 -9,6 -12,0 -23,1

Cattle- Dairying -rearing & fattening 2.898 124 339 -255,2 4,3 11,7 -8,8

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 2.539 560 1.168 971,2 22,1 46,0 38,3

Granivores 640 -37 -37 -41,7 -5,7 -5,7 -6,5

Mixed livestock holdings 1.131 -34 -38 19,4 -3,0 -3,4 1,7

Mixed crops-livestock 5.141 -296 -362 -718,9 -5,8 -7,0 -14,0

Vineyards 196 111 186 112,5 56,6 95,0 57,5

Fruit and citrus fruit 106 9 -20 15,9 8,9 -18,6 15,0

Olives 1.650 -592 -833 -871,7 -35,9 -50,5 -52,8

Permanent crops mixed 203 -51 -58 -86,9 -25,1 -28,8 -42,9

Horticulture 12 4 1 -0,6 29,7 4,3 -5,0

Economic Size Class

<=16 ESU 8.041 -133 101 198,2 -1,7 1,3 2,5

>16 and <=100 ESU 14.471 -803 -582 -1.769,1 -5,6 -4,0 -12,2

>100 ESU 10.068 -555 -956 -1.884,1 -5,5 -9,5 -18,7

Residual 7.839 1.171 1.193 1.083,4 14,9 15,2 13,8

Page 35: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

33

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

Important regional redistributive effects

occur in the EU flat-rate scenario. In the EU-

15, almost all farms lose (except for sheep,

goats and other grazing livestock, vineyards

and fruit and citrus fruit), whereas in the EU-

10 almost all farms gain (except for permanent

crops mixed). In Table 9, we report that

approximately 1 billion € were channelled to

Table 11: Redistribution of decoupled payments across EU-15/EU-10 aggregated farm types

EU-15

Baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Type of Farming Million € change to Baseline % to Baseline

Cereals, oilseed & protein crops 6.375 -403 -615 -657,8 -6,3 -9,6 -10,3

General field & mixed cropping 4.450 -421 -586 -1.143,0 -9,5 -13,2 -25,7

Dairying 4.590 -446 -564 -1.189,4 -9,7 -12,3 -25,9

Cattle- Dairying -rearing & fattening 2.724 124 340 -261,7 4,6 12,5 -9,6

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 2.478 556 1.163 951,0 22,4 47,0 38,4

Granivores 431 -33 -33 -62,1 -7,6 -7,6 -14,4

Mixed livestock holdings 501 -36 -40 -110,9 -7,2 -8,1 -22,1

Mixed crops-livestock 3.728 -300 -366 -919,4 -8,0 -9,8 -24,7

Vineyards 195 111 186 112,4 56,7 95,3 57,6

Fruit and citrus fruit 106 9 -20 15,9 8,9 -18,6 15,0

Olives 1.650 -592 -833 -871,7 -35,9 -50,5 -52,8

Permanent crops mixed 198 -51 -58 -85,4 -25,7 -29,5 -43,1

Horticulture 12 4 1 -0,6 29,7 4,3 -5,0

Economic Size Class

<=16 ESU 5.420 -136 99 -411,5 -2,5 1,8 -7,6

>16 and <=100 ESU 13.674 -793 -571 -1.870,8 -5,8 -4,2 -13,7

>100 ESU 8.343 -551 -953 -1.940,4 -6,6 -11,4 -23,3

Residual 6.516 1.161 1.182 857,1 17,8 18,1 13,2

EU-10

Baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Type of Farming Million € change to Baseline % to Baseline

Cereals, oilseed & protein crops 1.355 0 0 154,9 0,0 0,0 11,4

General field & mixed cropping 973 6 6 180,0 0,6 0,6 18,5

Dairying 322 -24 -24 56,4 -7,5 -7,5 17,5

Cattle- Dairying -rearing & fattening 173 -0 -0 6,5 -0,1 -0,1 3,8

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 61 4 4 20,1 7,2 7,2 32,8

Granivores 210 -4 -4 20,5 -1,8 -1,8 9,8

Mixed livestock holdings 630 2 2 130,3 0,3 0,3 20,7

Mixed crops-livestock 1.413 4 4 200,5 0,3 0,3 14,2

Vineyards 1 -0 -0 0,1 -0,0 -0,0 16,3

Permanent crops mixed 5 0 0 -1,5 0,0 0,0 -34,0

Economic Size Class

<=16 ESU 2.621 3 3 609,7 0,1 0,1 23,3

>16 and <=100 ESU 796 -11 -11 101,7 -1,3 -1,3 12,8

>100 ESU 1.725 -4 -4 56,3 -0,2 -0,2 3,3

Residual 1.323 10 10 226,3 0,8 0,8 17,1

Page 36: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

34

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

the EU-10. In particular, big gainers in the EU-

10 are mixed crops and livestock (200 million

€), general field and mixed cropping (180

million €), cereals and oilseeds (155 million €)

and dairy farms (56 million €). Overall, farm

types in the size class less than 16 ESU in the

EU-10 benefit, gaining 610 million €. In the

EU-15, large farms and farms specialised in

dairying, mixed crops and livestock, general

field and mixed cropping, olives and cereals

and oilseeds lose substantially in absolute and

relative terms.

Table 10 and Table 11 present the net

redistribution effects across farm types.

However, these aggregate changes might hide

sizable redistribution effects within the farm

type groups. To gain more insight, Figure 4 to

Figure 9 report the redistribution of decoupled

payments within the farm types. The figures show

the changes in decoupled payments relative

to the baseline in million € (left panel) and in

€ per hectare (right panel) for the EU-25. The

x-axis shows farm groups normalised to 100.

The left panel is calculated by placing farms in

ascending order and accumulating the payment

change compared to the baseline. For the last

farm, the cumulated value represents the net

value of redistributed payments over all farms

considered. The right panel shows the changes

in the per-hectare value relative to the baseline,

which, as before, are sorted in ascending order.

We first show the total effects for all farms (Figure

4) and then the type of farming that loses most,

followed by the farm types that benefit (Figure

5-Figure 9).

First, we consider the distribution for all

farms. Figure 4 shows that in the Nuts1 scenario,

almost 30% of all farm types lose payments,

approximately 30% are not affected (mainly

those located in new MS and Germany, which

already implements a flat-rate scheme at baseline)

and the remaining 30% gain payments. Overall

(at the endpoint of the curve in Figure 4), farms

lose 320 million € (which corresponds to the

figure reported in Table 9 for the EU-25) in this

scenario. It can also be observed that for the

other two sub-scenarios (MS and EU flat rate), the

net redistribution loss is higher (end points), and

more farms are affected by the redistribution of

decoupled payments (the horizontal part of the

curve is smaller; for the EU flat-rate sub-scenario,

it almost disappears). In particular, the EU flat-

rate sub-scenario reveals that almost 40% of the

farm types lose payments, whereas 60% gain

payments.

The right panel complements the left panel

by presenting the distribution on a per-hectare

basis. The area between the x-axis and the

distribution function shows the total amount

of redistributed payments. When the line is

below zero, it represent a loss in payments, and

Figure 4: Redistribution of decoupled payments across farm types and scenarios

Page 37: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

35

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

when it is above zero, it represents a gain in

payments.

Next, the distributional effects for the

farm types that lose payments (oilseed, cereals

and protein crops, general field cropping and

mixed cropping and dairying) are discussed.

The distribution for specialised olives, mixed

crops and livestock and permanent crops

mixed, which also lose, is provided in the

Annex.

Figure 5 shows that almost 40% of farms

specialised in cereals, oilseed and protein

crops lose payments in the Nuts1 sub-scenario,

whereas approximately 35% are not affected,

and the remaining 15% gain payments. Overall

(at the endpoint of the curve in Figure 5), these

farms lose 403 million €. For the other two

sub-scenarios (MS and EU flat rate), the net

redistribution loss is higher (i.e., the endpoints

are lower), more farms are affected by the

redistribution of SPS payments (i.e., the linear

part of the curve is smaller, and for the EU

flat-rate scenario, it almost disappears), and

more money is redistributed (the curves are

deeper) compared to the Nuts1 sub-scenario. In

particular, the EU flat-rate sub-scenario reveals

that almost 60% of the farms specialising in

cereals, oilseed and protein crops lose payments,

whereas 40% gain payments.

Figure 5: Redistribution of decoupled payments for the specialised cereals, oilseed and protein crops farm type

Figure 6: Redistribution of decoupled payments for the general field cropping and mixed cropping farm type

Page 38: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

36

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

In Figure 6, the farm type specialised in

general field cropping and mixed cropping is

shown. For the first two scenarios, the curves have

a similar shape as those for the cereals, oilseed

and protein crops farm type. The percentages of

farms that lose and gain, respectively, are similar,

whereas the curve for the EU flat-rate scenario

reveals that 30%, compared to 60% for the

general field cropping and mixed cropping farm

type, lose payments. This result is more evident

from the right panel in Figure 6, where some

farms experience a huge per-hectare value of the

payment losses.

In Figure 7, dairy farms are presented. As

reported in Table 10, they lose on aggregate in all

three scenarios (Nuts1: 10%; MS: 12%; and EU:

23%). Only olives and permanent crops mixed

lose more decoupled payments in percentage

terms (Table 9).

We now consider the farm types that benefit

from the flat rate. In Figure 8 and Figure 9, the

farms specialised in sheep, goats and other grazing

livestock, and residual farm type, respectively,

are presented. Note that the residual farm type

includes those farms that are not considered

among the nine most important farming types in a

Nuts2 region. The figures reveal that even though,

on aggregate, both of these farm types gain from

the flat-rate schemes, a sizable number of farms

experience a reduction in payments (up to 20%).

Figure 7: Redistribution of decoupled payments for specialised dairy farm types

Figure 8: Redistribution of decoupled payments for sheep, goats and other grazing livestock farm types

Page 39: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

37

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

Redistribution of decoupled payments between

regions

We now address the differences in the

redistribution effects between regions. Here,

the advantage is that we can use maps for

visualisation. We start with Table 12, which reports

the redistribution effects between the MSs in the

EU-27. The first column shows the total value of

decoupled payments at baseline, followed by

the total value of payments obtained in the three

considered sub-scenarios. The absolute and the

percentage change compared to the baseline are

presented in the remaining columns.

By definition, the redistribution effects

between the MS for the Nuts1 and MS flat-rate

sub-scenarios are relatively small in the EU-10, as

mentioned above; however, some changes occur

in Slovenia and Malta due to their historical

SPS. The endogenous land-use adjustment is

responsible for the effects in the EU-15 MS.

The EU flat-rate scenario has a considerable

impact on the redistribution of payments between

the MS. In relative terms, the Netherlands (48%),

Belgium (45%) and Greece (44%) have the

highest loss rates, whereas the largest increases

are observed for Latvia (149%), Romania (92%),

Estonia (82%), Bulgaria (55%) and Lithuania

(54%). Payments also increase in Portugal (43%)

and Spain (35%).

Germany loses, in absolute terms, 1.35

billion €, which represents 38% of the budget

at baseline. France contributes 0.981 billion

€ to the EU redistribution amount, followed by

Italy (0.960 billion €) and Greece (0.956 billion

€). Spain (1.760 billion €) and Portugal (0.260

billion €) gain from the redistribution of payments

in the EU flat-rate sub-scenario. The aggregated

MS effects can differ from the Nuts2-level effects.

Table 13 provides percentage changes in

payments for Nuts2 regions by splitting them into

two groups: those with reduced payments and

those with increased payments. For the Nuts1 and

MS flat-rate scenarios, there are Nuts2 regions

with both increased and reduced payments that

almost compensate each other. In the EU flat-rate

scenario, most of the Nuts2 regions lose in the

EU-15 (with the exceptions of Spain, Portugal,

Sweden, UK and Austria), whereas the vast

majority of the Nuts2 regions win in the EU-10

and BuR.

Figure 10 shows the results for the Nuts1,

MS and EU flat-rate sub-scenarios at the Nuts2

level. The figure demonstrates the change in per-

hectare value of decoupled payments relative

to the baseline. In the Nuts1 and MS flat-rate

scenarios, the deviation relative to the baseline is

very small in the NMS (yellow regions) due to the

SPAS implementation at the baseline, whereas for

the EU flat-rate scenario, the changes (particularly

Figure 9: Redistribution of decoupled payments for residual farm types

Page 40: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

38

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

in Romania and Latvia and Eastland) are greater

than 200 € per ha UAA. The redistribution

within the EU-15 for the MS flat-rate scenario is

considerable, with the exception of Germany.

For many MS in the EU-15, a similar pattern in

the flow of payments from more intensive to more

extensive regions can be observed. France loses

payments in northern regions, whereas the southern

regions gain payments. UK loses payments, whereas

Scotland gains. Similar redistribution effects can be

observed in Italy, Spain and Sweden.

To summarise the effects, Table 14 presents

the net redistributed amounts at different regional

levels. The amount of redistributed payments

increases from the Nuts1 scenario to the EU flat-

rate scenario, and it decreases from the farm

level to the MS level. The payments reallocated

between farms increase from 9% (3.7 billion €) of

the total budget in the Nuts1 scenario to 19% (8.2

billion €) in the EU flat-rate scenario. Similarly,

payments reallocated between MS increase from

1% (0.3 billion €) in the Nuts1 scenario to 13%

(5.5 billion €) in the EU flat-rate scenario. The

Table 12: Redistribution of decoupled payments at the MS level

EU-Aggregates and MS

Baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

EU-Aggregate Million € change to Baseline % to Baseline

EU-15

Belgium 590 -15 -12 -266,0 -2,5 -2,1 -45,1

Denmark 955 -34 -34 -364,4 -3,6 -3,6 -38,2

Germany 5.234 -0 96 -1.356,9 1,8 -25,9

Austria 691 -1 -0 68,1 -0,1 9,8

Netherlands 822 -2 4 -397,6 -0,3 0,5 -48,3

France 7.688 110 78 -983,7 1,4 1,0 -12,8

Portugal 601 -19 -18 256,6 -3,1 -3,1 42,7

Spain 4.977 -81 -91 1.759,9 -1,6 -1,8 35,4

Greece 2.176 -92 -78 -956,7 -4,2 -3,6 -44,0

Italy 4.213 -133 -141 -963,7 -3,1 -3,3 -22,9

Ireland 1.242 -12 13 -269,1 -0,9 1,1 -21,7

Finland 541 -10 -8 4,6 -1,8 -1,5 0,8

Sweden 698 -34 -34 38,6 -4,9 -4,9 5,5

United Kingdom 3.526 3 -16 65,0 0,1 -0,5 1,8

EU-10

Czech Republic 891 -90,8 -10,2

Estonia 101 82,7 81,7

Hungary 1.319 -26,6 -2,0

Lithuania 380 204,5 53,8

Latvia 146 217,7 148,6

Poland 3.045 584,6 19,2

Slovenia 140 -1 -1 -24,4 -0,9 -0,9 -17,5

Slovak Republic 388 64,7 16,7

Cyprus 53 -18,4 -34,4

Malta 2 0,1 -5,8 -5,8 2,5

Bulgaria 755 0 0 415,1 0,0 0,0 55,0

Romania 1.660 0 0 1.526,4 0,0 0,0 91,9

Page 41: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

39

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisTable 13: Redistribution of decoupled payments at the Nuts2 level for all MS

BaselineNuts2 region with reduced

decoupled paymentsNuts2 region with increased

decoupled payments

Scenario Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Country Mio. € % change of decoupled payments relative to baseline

Austria 691 12 19 12 12 19 22

Belgium 590 5 8 45 2 6

Germany 5.234 5 26 6

Denmark 955 4 4 38

Greece 2.176 18 18 46 13 14 2

Spain 4.977 7 16 9 5 14 44

Finland 541 3 3 2 1 2 2

France 7.688 4 12 19 6 13 6

Ireland 1.242 1 5 22 6

Italy 4.213 7 17 28 4 14 5

Netherlands 822 5 7 48 5 8

Portugal 601 15 16 1 12 13 43

Sweden 698 11 11 4 6 6 10

United Kingdom 3.526 17 15 16 17

Czech Republic 891 10

Cyprus 54 34

Estonia 101 82

Hungary 1.319 2

Lithuania 380 54

Latvia 146 149

Malta 2 6 6 3

Poland 3.045 2

Slovak Republic 388 17

Slovenia 140 1 1 17

Bulgaria 755 55

Romania 1.660 92

Figure 10: Regional redistribution of decoupled payments in €/ha UAA

Page 42: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

40

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

differences in the sizes of redistributed payments

between Nuts2 regions lay between the farm and

the MS levels.

Impacts on land use and herd sizes

The introduction of a uniform flat-rate system

leads to adjustments in the value of payments at the

regional and farm type levels. The redistribution

of payments has an allocative response in CAPRI

through land market adjustments in regions that

experience a changed premium and in regions

where premiums are differentiated for arable

versus grasslands. In Table 15, the land use

changes for grass, arable and total agricultural

land are presented.

In the EU-15, the UAA decreases between

-1.1% and -1.7%, depending on the sub-

scenario considered. We observe almost no

change in the UAA for the EU-10 and BuR. The

entitlement endowment limits the amount of

land that benefits from the flat-rate premium, so

no land use expansion occurs. This is based on

the assumption that in the calibration (baseline),

all available premium rights are claimed. That

is consistent with Article 42 of COUNCIL

REGULATION (EC) No 73/2009 which states that

unused premium rights are withdrawn. In the

EU flat-rate scenario, a substitution effect occurs

between grass and arable land. For fallow land

(arable land category), the flat rate increased by

almost 100% because it received a reduced flat-

rate premium at baseline. This increase results

in a 1.4% increase in arable land in the EU-10.

However, it does not affect the UAA because

entitlements constrain the land expansion.

Farm types that could benefit from the re-

allocation of premiums rarely decrease their land

use, whereas those that lose decrease their land

use, driven by the land supply function.

The UAA, in combination with changes in

herds and prices, induces changes in the crop

rotation. This result is presented for the different

farm type aggregates in Table 17 and Table 18.

In general, land use for the main crops,

except fallow land, is rarely affected. This result is

not surprising because the decoupled payments

should have no significant impact on the

production decisions of farmers.

Note that some of the percentage differences

shown in Table 17 and Table 18 are large.

This result is mainly caused by the fact that the

percentage change is calculated relative to a

small amount of land at baseline. Table 19 depicts

the absolute deviation of herd sizes compared to

the baseline. Here, we also observe rather small

changes in herd sizes relative to baseline levels.

Impact on the agricultural market

The full integration of the farm types in the

CAPRI model system allows the farm behaviour

model to interact with the market model. This

interaction between the farm type layer and the

market model allows the supply obtained from

the EU-25 farm types and the regional supplies

from BuR to balance the market demand.

Because the production response of the

farmers is limited to adjustments in land use,

Table 14: Summary of redistribution effects at the farm type, Nuts2 and MS levels

Re-distribution of SPS between

unitflat-rate Scenario

No.Nuts1 MS EU

Farm types% 9% 12% 19%

1.837∆ mio. € 3.673 5.249 8.175

Nuts2% 4% 10% 17%

276∆ mio. € 1.564 4.076 7.344

Member States% 1% 1% 13%

27∆ mio. € 274 313 5.503

Page 43: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

41

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

Tabl

e 15

: La

nd u

se c

hang

es f

or d

iffe

rent

EU

agg

rega

tes

and

MS

coun

trie

s

Gras

s La

ndAr

able

Lan

dUs

ed A

gric

ultu

ral A

rea

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

EU-A

ggre

gate

Mio

. ha

% o

f Bas

elin

eM

io. h

a%

of B

asel

ine

Mio

. ha

% o

f Bas

elin

e

EU-2

763

.387

-3,1

125.

191

-1,2

-1,4

-0,3

188.

578

-0,8

-0,9

-1,2

EU

-25

56.6

93-0

,1-2

,711

2.74

5-1

,3-1

,5-0

,716

9.43

9-0

,9-1

,0-1

,4

EU-1

549

.328

-2,4

87.3

24-1

,7-1

,9-1

,313

6.65

2-1

,1-1

,3-1

,7

U-10

7.36

5-0

,1-0

,1-5

,025

.421

1,4

32.7

86-0

,1

Bulg

aria

2.11

6-1

0,2

3.02

47,

15.

140

Ro

man

ia4.

578

-3,6

9.42

11,

713

.999

EU-1

5

Belg

ium

580

-2,0

-2,1

-7,3

908

-0,6

-0,6

-2,5

1.48

8-1

,2-1

,2-4

,4

Denm

ark

170

-36,

3-3

6,4

-41,

22.

504

1,9

1,9

-0,5

2.67

4-0

,5-0

,5-3

,1

Germ

any

4.44

3-0

,1-0

,7-5

,113

.063

-0,2

-1,9

17.5

06-0

,3-2

,7

Aust

ria1.

789

-1,1

-0,8

-0,9

1.57

7-1

,5-1

,6-0

,83.

366

-1,3

-1,2

-0,9

Ne

ther

land

s69

8-1

,5-1

,6-6

,41.

232

-0,8

-0,8

-1,6

1.93

0-1

,1-1

,1-3

,3

Fran

ce9.

578

-0,6

-0,5

-3,9

20.4

82-1

,7-2

,2-1

,230

.060

-1,4

-1,6

-2,0

Po

rtuga

l1.

792

-1,9

-2,0

-1,0

1.99

1-2

,0-1

,90,

23.

783

-2,0

-2,0

-0,4

Sp

ain

10.4

341,

31,

4-1

,219

.320

-2,9

-3,1

-0,2

29.7

55-1

,4-1

,5-0

,5

Gree

ce1.

841

0,2

0,9

-7,3

3.82

5-4

,8-4

,7-4

,65.

666

-3,2

-2,9

-5,5

Ita

ly4.

526

-0,2

0,1

-2,2

10.0

24-2

,0-2

,0-1

,814

.550

-1,4

-1,3

-1,9

Ire

land

2.78

8-0

,3-0

,3-1

,91.

525

-0,2

-0,2

0,8

4.31

3-0

,3-0

,3-1

,0

Finl

and

549

0,7

0,7

0,3

1.86

3-1

,4-1

,5-1

,02.

412

-0,9

-1,0

-0,7

Sw

eden

450

-0,4

-0,5

-3,1

2.83

2-2

,5-2

,4-1

,13.

282

-2,2

-2,2

-1,4

Un

ited

King

dom

9.69

00,

50,

30,

36.

177

-1,4

-1,7

-1,9

15.8

67-0

,2-0

,5-0

,6EU

-10

Cz

ech

Repu

blic

857

-5,1

2.66

41,

43.

520

-0,2

Es

toni

a22

2-1

,558

60,

680

7

Hung

ary

960

-0,1

-0,1

-5,2

4.71

81,

05.

678

Li

thua

nia

865

-4,8

1.70

32,

42.

568

La

tvia

594

-5,8

1.00

53,

41.

600

Po

land

3.00

6-6

,212

.936

1,4

15.9

42

Slov

enia

313

-1,3

-1,3

-2,3

201

-0,5

-0,5

0,1

514

-1,0

-0,9

-1,4

Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

548

-1,0

1.44

00,

41.

988

0,1

Cy

prus

0,3

-0,1

-6,2

158

-2,3

158

-2,3

M

alta

10-2

,0-2

,0-1

,710

-2,0

-2,0

-1,7

Page 44: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

42

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

Tabl

e 16

: La

nd u

se c

hang

e in

the

EU

for

agg

rega

ted

farm

typ

es

Gras

s La

ndAr

able

Lan

dUs

ed A

gric

ultu

ral A

rea

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

EUNu

ts1

MS

EU

Type

of F

arm

ing

Mio

. ha

% o

f bas

elin

eM

io. h

a%

of b

asel

ine

Mio

. ha

% o

f bas

elin

e

Ce

real

s, o

ilsee

d &

prot

ein

crop

s3.

140

0,6

1,5

-4,5

29.0

64-1

,2-1

,3-1

,132

.204

-460

,6-1

,0-1

,1-1

,4

Ge

nera

l fiel

d &

mix

ed c

ropp

ing

2.71

7-1

,7-1

,8-6

,717

.259

-1,2

-1,3

-1,2

19.9

76-3

86,0

-1,2

-1,4

-1,9

Da

iryin

g8.

496

-0,8

-0,9

-3,1

8.43

2-1

,2-1

,5-0

,816

.927

-326

,6-1

,0-1

,2-1

,9

Ca

ttle-

Dai

ryin

g -r

earin

g &

fatte

ning

8.08

7-0

,5-0

,3-2

,23.

642

-1,6

-1,5

1,5

11.7

29-1

20,4

-0,8

-0,7

-1,0

Sh

eep,

goa

ts a

nd o

ther

gra

zing

live

stoc

k12

.645

0,2

0,2

-0,5

2.84

1-2

,5-2

,70,

015

.486

-66,

6-0

,3-0

,4-0

,4

Gr

aniv

ores

494

-0,5

-0,4

-1,9

2.16

0-0

,9-0

,9-0

,72.

655

-24,

7-0

,8-0

,8-0

,9

M

ixed

live

stoc

k ho

ldin

gs1.

658

-0,3

-0,3

-3,3

3.43

5-0

,6-0

,70,

45.

093

-41,

5-0

,5-0

,6-0

,8

M

ixed

cro

ps-li

vest

ock

5.00

9-0

,8-1

,0-4

,414

.746

-0,8

-0,9

-0,7

19.7

55-3

27,7

-0,8

-0,9

-1,7

Vi

neya

rds

157

-1,5

1,0

-2,4

1.20

5-0

,8-0

,9-0

,41.

362

-8,2

-0,9

-0,7

-0,6

Fr

uit a

nd c

itrus

frui

t18

-35,

3-3

6,6

-37,

654

4-4

,4-5

,2-3

,756

2-2

7,0

-5,4

-6,2

-4,8

Ol

ives

430

-6,5

-9,1

-15,

23.

190

-4,0

-5,0

-4,2

3.62

0-1

99,3

-4,3

-5,5

-5,5

Pe

rman

ent c

rops

mix

ed51

-16,

1-1

4,7

-21,

348

6-4

,7-4

,5-3

,753

7-2

8,8

-5,8

-5,4

-5,4

Ho

rticu

lture

3-7

,8-1

0,6

-10,

848

-2,0

-2,0

-2,0

51-1

,3-2

,3-2

,5-2

,5

Econ

omic

Siz

e Cl

ass

<

=16

ESU

14.6

30-0

,3-0

,2-2

,421

.980

-1,4

-1,3

-0,3

36.6

10-4

16,1

-1,0

-0,9

-1,1

>

16 a

nd <

=10

0 ES

U21

.216

-0,6

-0,5

-2,8

35.5

49-1

,6-1

,7-1

,156

.765

-969

,4-1

,2-1

,2-1

,7

>

100

ESU

7.05

9-0

,5-1

,0-3

,629

.523

-0,8

-1,2

-1,3

36.5

82-6

33,1

-0,8

-1,2

-1,7

Resi

dual

13.7

881,

31,

2-2

,625

.693

-1,5

-1,7

0,3

39.4

81-2

86,7

-0,5

-0,7

-0,7

Page 45: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

43

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

Tabl

e 17

: C

ropp

ing

chan

ges

for

EU-2

5 ag

greg

ated

far

m t

ypes

and

EU

agg

rega

tes

Cere

als

Oils

eeds

Othe

r ara

ble

crop

s

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

1.00

0 ha

% to

Bas

elin

e1.

000

ha%

to B

asel

ine

1.00

0 ha

% to

Bas

elin

e

EU-1

534

.618

0,1

0,1

-2,3

7.03

9-0

,4-0

,6-2

,16.

136

0,5

0,5

-0,7

EU-1

016

.186

-3,5

2.04

60,

1-1

,398

3-0

,1-0

,1-1

,1

Bulg

aria

1.35

50,

10,

1-3

,751

60,

10,

1-4

,225

0-0

,1-0

,1

Rom

ania

4.74

5-1

,688

7-0

,143

6-0

,2-0

,2-1

,5

Type

of F

arm

ing

EU-2

5

Ce

real

s, o

ilsee

d &

prot

ein

crop

s17

.850

0,2

0,4

-2,0

4.70

6-0

,1-0

,4-2

,01.

192

0,6

0,9

-2,1

Ge

nera

l fiel

d &

mix

ed c

ropp

ing

8.61

6-0

,5-0

,7-3

,51.

383

-0,6

-0,9

-2,1

2.61

30,

40,

3-0

,4

Da

iryin

g2.

184

-0,6

-0,8

-2,9

133

-0,3

-0,1

-2,4

135

0,3

0,3

-0,5

Ca

ttle-

Dai

ryin

g -r

earin

g &

fatte

ning

762

-0,3

-0,3

-0,6

61-0

,5-0

,2-2

,310

30,

40,

40,

3

Sh

eep,

goa

ts &

oth

er g

razi

ng li

vest

ock

484

-0,8

-0,3

-4,0

46-0

,9-0

,9-1

,529

20,

10,

2-0

,4

Gr

aniv

ores

1.26

2-0

,5-0

,3-1

,912

0-2

,2-1

,7-2

,613

40,

10,

1-0

,4

M

ixed

live

stoc

k ho

ldin

gs2.

063

-0,2

-0,2

-3,4

68-0

,2-0

,3-1

,213

00,

20,

2-0

,6

M

ixed

cro

ps-li

vest

ock

8.38

1-0

,3-0

,5-2

,51.

459

-0,4

-0,5

-1,3

704

0,1

-0,1

-0,8

Vi

neya

rds

89-1

,2-0

,4-1

,616

0,3

-0,4

39-0

,2-0

,3

Fr

uit a

nd c

itrus

frui

t7

-64,

3-6

4,7

-65,

92

-38,

8-3

8,2

-38,

720

-10,

3-1

0,3

-10,

3

Ol

ives

110

-6,9

-13,

7-1

5,2

24-9

,9-1

9,2

-16,

857

-0,9

-2,2

-2,4

Pe

rman

ent c

rops

mix

ed24

-7,9

-7,9

-15,

42

-23,

5-2

2,8

-13,

53

-1,7

-1,7

-4,6

Ho

rticu

lture

1-1

8,1

-16,

3-2

4,6

20,

90,

80,

2

Econ

omic

Siz

e Cl

ass

<

=16

ESU

10.7

140,

10,

4-3

,878

10,

40,

9-1

,71.

043

0,1

-1,2

>

16 a

nd <

=10

0 ES

U16

.531

-0,3

-0,1

-2,2

3.05

3-0

,5-0

,6-2

,31.

929

0,4

0,5

-0,9

>

100

ESU

14.5

89-0

,3-0

,7-2

,24.

186

-0,4

-0,8

-1,7

2.45

30,

30,

1-0

,7

Resi

dual

8.97

01,

21,

2-3

,01.

065

0,3

0,4

-1,5

1.69

50,

80,

9-0

,3

Page 46: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

44

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

Tabl

e 18

: C

ropp

ing

chan

ges

for

EU-2

5 ag

greg

ated

far

m t

ypes

and

EU

agg

rega

tes

(con

tinu

ed)

Vege

tabl

es &

Per

man

ent c

rops

Fodd

er a

ctiv

ities

Set a

side

& fa

llow

land

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

1.00

0 ha

% to

Bas

elin

e1.

000

ha%

to B

asel

ine

1.00

0 ha

% to

Bas

elin

e

EU-1

512

.936

1,1

0,9

0,5

62.8

49-0

,1-0

,1-2

,48.

718

-18,

8-2

0,6

1,1

EU-1

01.

107

-0,2

8.83

5-0

,1-0

,1-4

,73.

046

-0,1

-0,1

33,1

Bulg

aria

290

-0,2

2.15

7-1

0,1

569

-0,1

-0,3

51,0

Rom

ania

669

5.02

7-3

,675

4-0

,1-0

,235

,0

Type

of F

arm

ing

EU-2

5

Ce

real

s, o

ilsee

d &

prot

ein

crop

s62

60,

50,

50,

23.

862

0,5

1,3

-4,1

2.96

9-1

3,4

-15,

55,

9

Ge

nera

l fiel

d &

mix

ed c

ropp

ing

1.25

90,

80,

90,

53.

943

-1,3

-1,3

-5,7

1.55

4-1

0,5

-11,

411

,4

Da

iryin

g30

61,

31,

31,

312

.791

-0,8

-0,9

-2,5

667

-9,4

-10,

78,

7

Ca

ttle-

Dai

ryin

g -r

earin

g &

fatte

ning

154

0,4

0,5

0,4

10.0

01-0

,5-0

,3-2

,329

3-1

6,4

-16,

339

,1

Sh

eep,

goa

ts &

oth

er g

razi

ng li

vest

ock

408

1,5

1,5

1,4

13.5

680,

10,

1-0

,629

2-2

2,9

-27,

510

,9

Gr

aniv

ores

328

1,4

1,4

1,2

571

-0,6

-0,5

-2,0

177

-8,2

-9,5

5,7

M

ixed

live

stoc

k ho

ldin

gs12

01,

21,

21,

42.

226

-0,4

-0,5

-3,2

387

-3,5

-3,9

26,1

M

ixed

cro

ps-li

vest

ock

484

0,6

0,6

0,4

6.82

8-0

,7-0

,9-3

,81.

123

-6,8

-7,0

15,1

Vi

neya

rds

904

1,1

1,2

173

-1,4

1,0

-2,3

96-1

9,7

-22,

4-2

,8

Fr

uit a

nd c

itrus

frui

t45

17,

56,

56,

728

-38,

8-3

9,4

-44,

553

-86,

8-8

6,9

-70,

9

Ol

ives

2.61

8-0

,9-1

,7-1

,859

2-5

,1-7

,1-1

5,9

211

-43,

3-4

3,8

-17,

1

Pe

rman

ent c

rops

mix

ed39

70,

10,

3-0

,168

-15,

4-1

4,1

-21,

640

-46,

7-4

6,3

-23,

5

Ho

rticu

lture

370,

90,

80,

74

-8,8

-10,

4-1

2,4

7-1

4,4

-14,

8-1

1,3

Econ

omic

Siz

e Cl

ass

<

=16

ESU

3.69

20,

80,

6-0

,117

.059

-0,3

-0,2

-2,5

2.80

1-1

2,1

-12,

816

,1

>

16 a

nd <

=10

0 ES

U2.

663

0,6

0,3

0,3

27.4

24-0

,6-0

,5-2

,73.

204

-15,

6-1

7,6

6,4

>

100

ESU

1.73

70,

50,

10,

210

.171

-0,7

-1,0

-3,2

1.86

3-9

,6-1

0,9

5,2

Resi

dual

5.95

01,

41,

51,

017

.029

1,2

1,2

-2,4

3.89

6-1

6,0

-17,

39,

0

Page 47: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

45

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

Tabl

e 19

: Her

d si

ze c

hang

es f

or t

he E

U-2

5 ag

greg

ated

far

m t

ypes

, EU

agg

rega

tes

and

MS

Cattl

e ac

tiviti

esBe

ef m

eat a

ctiv

ities

Othe

r ani

mal

s

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

1.00

0 he

ads

% to

Bas

elin

e1.

000

head

s%

to B

asel

ine

1.00

0 he

ads

% to

Bas

elin

e

EU-1

573

.041

-0,1

-0,1

-3,0

24.4

12-0

,2-0

,2-5

,033

6.89

3-0

,1-0

,1-0

,7

EU-1

06.

820

1.33

70,

543

.727

-0,3

Bulg

aria

968

-1,5

227

-1,6

1.83

3-1

,4

Rom

ania

3.24

1-0

,384

2-0

,413

.775

-0,8

Type

of F

arm

ing

EU-2

5

Ce

real

s, o

ilsee

d &

prot

ein

crop

s2.

058

-0,1

-0,1

-3,9

883

-0,2

-0,3

-5,7

9.02

20,

10,

1-0

,3

Ge

nera

l fiel

d &

mix

ed c

ropp

ing

2.88

9-0

,2-0

,2-3

,196

8-0

,4-0

,5-4

,820

.969

-0,7

Da

iryin

g24

.135

-0,1

-0,1

-1,5

2.90

4-0

,1-0

,2-2

,27.

950

-0,1

-0,2

-0,4

Ca

ttle-

Dai

ryin

g -r

earin

g &

fatte

ning

16.7

63-0

,2-0

,2-4

,08.

744

-0,2

-0,2

-5,6

3.80

40,

2

Sh

eep,

goa

ts &

gra

zing

live

stoc

k3.

508

-2,4

1.80

9-0

,0-0

,1-2

,963

.956

-0,1

-0,1

-1,8

Gr

aniv

ores

766

-0,4

-0,4

-1,4

213

-0,9

-1,0

-1,8

101.

467

M

ixed

live

stoc

k ho

ldin

gs3.

352

-0,1

-0,1

-2,3

965

-0,2

-0,2

-5,5

29.8

55-0

,1-0

,2-0

,5

M

ixed

cro

ps-li

vest

ock

10.2

45-0

,2-0

,2-2

,93.

039

-0,4

-0,4

-5,0

70.7

44-0

,1-0

,1-0

,7

Vi

neya

rds

78-3

,639

-5,2

205

-0,3

Fr

uit a

nd c

itrus

frui

t23

-6,0

-5,8

-9,7

10-9

,2-8

,7-1

5,0

517

-0,4

-0,4

-1,6

Ol

ives

147

-0,8

-1,1

-8,6

75-1

,1-1

,6-1

4,0

1.32

7-1

,0-1

,0-3

,9

Pe

rman

ent c

rops

mix

ed41

-2,0

-1,7

-6,2

22-2

,8-2

,2-9

,746

9-0

,9-0

,9-1

,3

vHor

ticul

ture

6-0

,5-0

,5-1

,71

-0,2

-0,2

-1,3

282

-0,2

-0,3

-1,0

Econ

omic

Siz

e Cl

ass

<

=16

ESU

10.8

84-2

,34.

397

-0,1

-0,1

-4,2

45.9

05-0

,1-0

,1-0

,9

>

16 a

nd <

=10

0 ES

U35

.550

-0,2

-0,2

-3,1

11.7

85-0

,3-0

,3-5

,413

0.19

5-0

,1-0

,1-1

,1

>

100

ESU

17.5

78-0

,1-0

,2-2

,03.

490

-0,2

-0,3

-3,0

134.

467

-0,1

Resi

dual

15.8

49-3

,26.

077

0,1

-4,9

70.0

530,

1-0

,9

Page 48: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

46

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

Tabl

e 20

: Pr

ice

chan

ges

for

diff

eren

t EU

agg

rega

te

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Euro

pro

t%

to B

asel

ine

Euro

pro

t%

to B

asel

ine

Euro

pro

t%

to B

asel

ine

Cere

als

Oils

eeds

Othe

r ara

ble

field

cro

ps

EU-1

510

9,3

0,3

0,5

1,4

254,

50,

30,

51,

516

8,7

-1,3

-1,2

-1,1

EU-1

085

,80,

10,

12,

926

1,9

0,1

0,1

1,6

90,6

-0,3

-0,3

0,3

Bulg

aria

84,8

0,1

0,2

1,9

233,

20,

10,

11,

619

8,5

-0,4

-0,4

-0,4

Rom

ania

122,

20,

10,

21,

824

2,7

0,1

0,1

1,4

343,

9-0

,4-0

,4-0

,4

Vege

tabl

es a

nd P

erm

anen

tM

eat

Othe

r Ani

mal

EU-1

569

2-0

,7-0

,7-0

,61.

701

0,1

0,1

1,1

624

0,0

0,1

0,7

EU-1

032

4-0

,1-0

,10,

11.

045

0,0

0,1

1,2

712

0,0

0,0

0,5

Bulg

aria

836

-0,1

-0,1

0,0

2.58

10,

00,

00,

986

5-0

,0-0

,00,

3

Rom

ania

427

-0,0

-0,0

0,1

1.50

80,

00,

10,

81.

299

-0,0

-0,0

0,3

Dai

ryOi

lsOi

l cak

es

EU-1

51.

360

0,0

0,0

0,1

1.43

90,

40,

70,

829

10,

20,

4-0

,3

EU-1

059

70,

00,

00,

167

30,

10,

10,

315

30,

10,

30,

2

Bulg

aria

1.08

20,

00,

00,

158

30,

00,

00,

410

80,

10,

21,

5

Rom

ania

846

0,0

0,0

0,2

559

0,0

0,0

0,4

120

0,1

0,2

1,6

Page 49: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

47

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

Tabl

e 21

: D

omes

tic

dem

and

and

prod

ucti

on c

hang

es f

or d

iffe

rent

EU

agg

rega

tes

Dom

estic

Pro

duct

ion

Dom

estic

Dem

and

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

Base

line

Nuts

1M

SEU

1.00

0 to

nne

% to

Bas

elin

e1.

000

tonn

e%

to B

asel

ine

Cere

als

EU

-15

220.

990

-0,2

-0,4

-1,3

200.

514

-0,1

-0,2

-1,1

EU

-10

68.4

270,

00,

1-1

,955

.101

-0,0

-0,0

-0,8

Bu

lgar

ia5.

668

0,1

0,2

-2,9

4.15

0-0

,1-0

,1-1

,1

Ro

man

ia15

.872

0,0

0,1

-1,0

13.8

53-0

,1-0

,1-0

,9

Oils

eeds

EU

-15

22.1

80-0

,4-0

,7-1

,739

.712

-0,0

-0,0

-0,3

EU

-10

5.12

80,

10,

2-0

,84.

393

-0,0

-0,0

-0,5

Bu

lgar

ia96

20,

10,

2-3

,775

9-0

,0-0

,0-0

,2

Ro

man

ia1.

554

-0,0

-0,0

0,2

1.14

5-0

,0-0

,0-0

,2

Oth

er a

rabl

e fie

ld c

rops

EU

-15

42.1

291,

61,

51,

341

.287

1,2

1,1

0,8

EU

-10

5.28

8-0

,4-0

,4-1

,47.

533

-0,0

-0,0

-0,5

Bu

lgar

ia40

7-0

,9-0

,90,

155

2-0

,3-0

,3-0

,4

Ro

man

ia3.

829

-0,5

-0,5

-0,7

4.20

00,

20,

20,

3

Mea

t

EU

-15

38.1

34-0

,0-0

,1-0

,634

.632

-0,0

-0,0

-0,1

EU

-10

6.57

60,

00,

0-0

,26.

285

-0,0

-0,0

-0,3

Bu

lgar

ia18

7-0

,0-0

,0-1

,141

1-0

,0-0

,0-1

,2

Ro

man

ia1.

007

0,0

0,1

-0,4

1.55

0-0

,0-0

,0-0

,7

Page 50: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

48

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

which results in small production changes, price

changes are also moderate, as shown in Table 20.

The redistributions of decoupled payments in the

Nuts1 and MS flat-rate scenarios (which mainly

affect the EU-15) lead to only small price effects.

As expected, the EU flat-rate scenario is the

most responsive to price, with a maximum price

increase for cereals of 1.5% for the EU-15 and

2.9% for the EU-10 (Figure 11).

The market balances for domestic

production and domestic demand are shown in

Table 21. The domestic demand is composed

of human consumption, processing (including

biofuel processing) and feed use. The difference

between production and demand is the net trade

(i.e., exports minus imports). Note that only

commodities with changes over 1% observed at

least in one sub-scenario are presented. Overall,

consumption and production effects are small,

with changes varying between 0% and 4%

relative to the baseline level.

Impact on income

The income indicator in the CAPRI

represents gross value added plus premiums

(prices times production minus variable

costs plus premiums). Given that the price

and production changes are small (Table 20),

the income effects are driven mainly by the

redistributed decoupled payments and to a

lesser extent by land use changes. We start to

analyse the income changes at the aggregated

level. According to Table 22, negligible changes

are observed for the Nuts1 and MS flat-rate

scenarios.

For the EU flat-rate scenario, income

decreases by 2.5% in the EU-15, whereas the

EU-10 (7%), Bulgaria (18%) and Romania (16%)

Figure 11: Cereal supply change in % relative to the baseline

Nuts1 flat rate MS flat rate EU flat rate

Table 22: Income changes for different EU aggregates

EU-Aggregates and MS

baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Million € change from baseline % of baseline

EU-15 178.675 -400 -196 -4.553 -0,2 -0,1 -2,5

EU-10 17.174 -3 2 1.231 -0,0 0,0 7,2

Bulgaria 2.274 -2 -1 419 -0,1 -0,0 18,4

Romania 9.379 -14 -12 1.529 -0,1 -0,1 16,3

Page 51: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

49

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisTable 23: Income changes at the MS level

baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Million € change from baseline % of baseline

Belgium 3.409 -25 -23 -292 -0,7 -0,7 -8,6

Denmark 3.360 -37 -34 -409 -1,1 -1,0 -12,2

Germany 21.740 -57 61 -1.744 -0,3 0,3 -8,0

Austria 3.784 -8 -4 61 -0,2 -0,1 1,6

Netherlands 11.138 2 10 -429 0,1 -3,8

France 33.985 93 85 -1.401 0,3 0,3 -4,1

Portugal 3.456 -33 -32 276 -0,9 -0,9 8,0

Spain 35.101 -98 -106 1.728 -0,3 -0,3 4,9

Greece 10.266 -28 3 -903 -0,3 -8,8

Italy 34.078 -139 -116 -993 -0,4 -0,3 -2,9

Ireland 4.355 -16 11 -308 -0,4 0,3 -7,1

Finland 1.794 -13 -10 -18 -0,7 -0,6 -1,0

Sweden 1.772 -23 -22 -0 -1,3 -1,2

United Kingdom 10.442 -20 -19 -122 -0,2 -0,2 -1,2

Czech Republic 1.836 -64 -3,5

Estonia 400 89 22,2

Hungary 2.966 1 2 19 0,1 0,6

Lithuania 957 215 22,5

Latvia 288 223 77,6

Poland 8.979 -1 2 706 7,9

Slovenia 726 -2 -2 -21 -0,3 -0,3 -2,9

Slovak Republic 822 1 80 0,1 9,8

Cyprus 169 -16 -9,6

Figure 12: Income changes in €/ha UAA

Nuts1 flat rate MS flat rate EU flat rate

Page 52: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

50

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

realise income increases. Compared to Table 9,

this result is approximately equal to the amount

of redistributed payments for the EU-10 and

BuR. The income loss in the EU-15 is higher

than the premium loss as a result of the 1.7%

land use reduction (see also Table 15).

Table 23 shows the income changes at the MS

level. For the Nuts1 and MS flat-rate scenarios, all

income changes are small (up to -1.3%). For the

EU flat-rate scenario, the greatest income losses

in absolute terms occur in Germany, France,

Greece and Italy.

Similar to the effects shown for the

redistribution of payments, Austria, Portugal and

Spain realise income increases in the EU flat-rate

scenario. For the EU-10, income increases in all

MS, with the exceptions of the Czech Republic,

Slovenia and Cyprus.

Figure 12 reports the income change per

hectare relative to baseline at the Nuts2 level.

The income changes are calculated based on the

aggregated value of income over all farm types in

a particular Nuts2 region.

The income changes across Nuts2 regions

for the Nuts1 flat-rate scenario are small. There

are five Nuts2 regions that realise income

decreases below -34 € per ha. The EU-10 and

BuR are not affected in this scenario. Germany

is not affected as it already implements the Nuts1

regional flat-rate system at baseline. The effect of

income redistribution is driven by the payment

redistribution: the income moves from intensive

regions with higher premium levels to marginal

regions. For the EU flat rate in particular, Southern

and Eastern Europe realise income growth.

The distributional issues within the farm types

are analysed in Figure 13, Figure 14 and Figure 15,

where cumulative income changes over all farm

types are reported for the Nuts1, MS and EU flat-

rate scenarios, respectively. On the x-axis, all farms

belonging to the analysed group are normalised to

100% (1=100%). The figures report cumulative

income changes (in ascending order) for all farm

Figure 13: Income changes in the Nuts1 flat-rate scenario

Page 53: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

51

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

types (light-blue dotted curve) and for each type of

farming (all other curves). Note that the unit of the

x-axis corresponds directly to the light-blue curve,

whereas the rest of curves (representing single

types of farming) also add up to 100%. The order

of the curves representing the types of farming has

no special meaning; it was chosen such that the

curves would not overlap. Results are weighted

based on the number of farms involved in each

type of farming. The y-axis is scaled identically

for all farms and for all types of farming to better

illustrate the total income effects.

Farm groups located on the negatively sloped

part of the curve realise income losses, whereas

farm groups located on the positive slope realise

income gains. A flat curve indicates no income

change. Note that the endpoint of each curve

represents the total income change as reported in

Table 24. For all 1824 farms (the light-blue dotted

curve), the values for income change are shown in

rectangles in Figure 13, Figure 14 and Figure 15.

First, taking into consideration the

distributional issues for the Nuts1 scenario, 32%

of the farm types lose income, whereas 35% are

not affected and the rest realise income growth

(light-blue curve). The total aggregated income

of all farm types (the endpoint of the light-blue

curve) drops slightly (0.21%), representing 0.4

billion € (Figure 13).

As shown in Figure 13, the income changes

for the different specialised farm groups

are substantial, mainly due to the premium

redistribution and land abandonment, whereas

price changes have only a moderate impact.

The distribution curves for the Nuts1 scenario

for the eleven farm types show that particularly

extensive production systems, such as sheep

and goats and residual farms, experience an

increase in income. In contrast, field cropping

farm groups (cereals, oilseed and protein crops,

general field cropping and mixed cropping),

dairy farms, mixed crop livestock and olive farms

obtain lower incomes. Vineyards do not receive

direct payments at baseline but benefit from the

flat-rate payments, in contrast to olive farms,

which experience a lower income caused by the

Figure 14: Income changes in the MS flat-rate scenario

Page 54: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

52

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis Figure 15: Income changes in the EU flat-rate scenario

Table 24 Aggregated income changes in the EU-25 by farm type

EU-25

Baseline Nuts1 MS EU Nuts1 MS EU

Type of Farming Million € change from baseline % of baseline

Cereals, oilseed & protein crops 15.435 -358 -524 -497,9 -2,3 -3,4 -3,2

General field & mixed cropping 19.300 -435 -572 -1.007,5 -2,3 -3,0 -5,2

Dairying 30.233 -471 -573 -1.236,2 -1,6 -1,9 -4,1

Cattle- Dairying -rearing & fattening 8.522 114 339 -373,3 1,3 4,0 -4,4

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 10.515 563 1.173 863,4 5,4 11,2 8,2

Granivores 8.026 1 5 32,9 0,1 0,4

Mixed livestock holdings 4.735 -36 -39 34,4 -0,8 -0,8 0,7

Mixed crops-livestock 16.917 -305 -354 -813,2 -1,8 -2,1 -4,8

Vineyards 5.653 128 206 104,8 2,3 3,6 1,9

Fruit and citrus fruit 4.059 9 -20 17,7 0,2 -0,5 0,4

Olives 6.585 -603 -839 -904,1 -9,2 -12,7 -13,7

Permanent crops mixed 1.434 -48 -52 -89,0 -3,4 -3,6 -6,2

Horticulture 1.204 2 -2 -2,7 0,2 -0,1 -0,2

Economic Size Class

<=16 ESU 30.699 -90 175 244,2 -0,3 0,6 0,8

>16 and <=100 ESU 57.952 -805 -527 -2.203,5 -1,4 -0,9 -3,8

>100 ESU 43.966 -544 -898 -1.911,5 -1,2 -2,0 -4,3

Residual 60.357 1.097 1.146 797,9 1,8 1,9 1,3

Page 55: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

53

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisreduction in payments through the introduction

of the Nuts1 flat rate.

As shown in Figure 14 and Figure 15, the

MS and the EU flat-rate scenarios lead to similar

directions of causation as the Nuts1 flat rate, but

with more income change. Overall, more farms

experience income gain or income loss and fewer

farms remain unaffected in the MS flat-rate and

EU flat-rate scenarios. These scenarios result in

aggregated income losses of 0.2 and 3.3 billion

€, respectively, at the EU-25 level. In the EU flat-

rate scenario, a major part of this income loss is

realised as income gains in BuR.

Conclusion

The CAPRI farm type model permits to

analyse SPS implementation options with respect

to the redistribution effects and market effects

on various farm types in Europe. The farm type

supply models adjust the production pattern

and land use endogenously, steered by the land

supply functions and by feedback from the market

module. The implementation of a flat-rate scheme

changes the levels of decoupled payments among

farms and regions, causing important income

effects. Further, this change results in land use

changes and leads to adjustments in production,

supply and prices. However, the binding

entitlement endowments limit the overall market

effects of a flat-rate scheme.

The analysis in this chapter has shown that

the allocative market responses are relatively

minor. These results clearly reflect the fact that

the vast majority of agricultural land in the

new MS was already operating under a uniform

premium scheme at the country level and that

some MS in the EU-15 already applied flat-rate

schemes at the regional level. The allocative

response in CAPRI is mostly limited to changes

in land use for those regions losing premiums

and slight substitution effects where premiums

were differentiated between arable land and

grasslands. Regions where the premiums

increase are bounded by the entitlement

constraint, so the payment changes are not

reflected in market effects.

Given that historical and regional SPS

premiums are strictly linked to coupled payments

and other types of support related to Pillar I and

paid under the Agenda 2000, the historical SPS

better reflects the productivity and specialisations

of the regions. Regions with high historical

yields for cereals and larger ruminant stocking

densities also show higher historical SPS rates.

A uniform flat rate tends to reduce the support

level in more productive regions and increase it

in more marginal regions. The scenario analyses

have shown that there are strong heterogeneous

impacts of the introduction of the flat rate on the

various farm types. Particularly strongly affected

are large farms and farms classified as dairying,

mixed crops and livestock, general field and

mixed cropping, olives, cereals and oilseeds, and

permanent crops. Small farms in both the old and

the new MS tended to be affected little by the

introduction of the flat rate.

One might conclude that as long as the

majority of Pillar I is paid as a flat rate per

hectare (independent of the amount) and the

GAEC (Good Agricultural and Environmental

Conditions) are respected, the definition of the

scheme impacts mostly distributional issues

within the EU agricultural sector. On the other

hand, the impact of a flat rate on commodity

markets is very moderate; therefore, consumers’

welfare and trade in agricultural products are

affected little.

III. 2. WTO Scenario

The focus of this scenario is the unique link

between a spatial global market model and the

farm type supply models. The CAPRI market

module can be characterised as a comparative-

static, deterministic, partial, spatial, global

equilibrium model for most primary and some

secondary agricultural products, fifty commodities

in total. It is deterministic as stochastic effects are

Page 56: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

54

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

not covered and partial as it excludes primary

factors, non-agricultural products as well as some

agricultural products, such as flowers. It is spatial

because it includes bilateral trade flows and the

related trade policy instruments between the

trade blocks. The trade blocks are presented in

Figure 16.

Each pair of regions can trade bilaterally,

simultaneously exporting and importing the same

commodity. This behaviour is based on the so-

called Armington assumption (Armginton 1969):

products of differen geographical origins are

treated as imperfect substitutes on the demand

side. The shares of products of different origins in

the consumption bundle are determined by their

price relations.

All countries have agreed, in the World

Trade Organization (WTO) context, not to

increase the rate of duty beyond a certain

tariff level (bound tariff), also called most

favoured nations (MFN) tariffs. MFN tariffs are

differentiated by tariff line (i.e. product), but

not importer (i.e., countries exporting into the

importing country). The tariffs applied are those

that are actually applied by the country group.

They may take the bound rate, but frequently

they do not. There are exceptions to the rule

that all importers face the same import MFN

tariff. The first, EU specific exemption, is quota

and tariff free access of LDSc to EU markets.

Similarly, the EC-ACP partnership program for

ACP countries, currently 79 countries from

Africa, the Caribbean and the Pacific area,

most of which are former colonies of the EU

Members; these countries face lower tariffs. The

third exception is the free trade areas (bilateral

agreements) with no tariffs. The EU-27 is a

trading block aggregate and itself an example

of a free trade area. The last exception is the

application of tariff rate quotas (TRQs). A TRQ

is a defined quota of an imported good that is

available either bilaterally to a specific trading

partner or globally to all trading partners, where

a so-called lower “in quota tariff” is applied.

For imports beyond the quota, MFN tariffs are

applied. Another exception to the rule of equal

tariffs is the instrument of variable import levies,

which reduces tariffs if the import price (CIF

plus tariffs) is higher than a specified minimum

border price in the EU. A somewhat similar

instrument is the entry price system used in the

fruit and vegetable sectors in the EU. The entry

price relates the applied tariff to a specified

trigger price in a way that encourages imports

at a price (CIF plus tariffs) that is between 92%

and 98% of the trigger price.

Figure 16: Trade blocks in the CAPRI global market model

Page 57: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

55

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisDescription

Liberalisation of international trade is

the major topic of the current WTO round,

and although the negotiations are far from

reaching an agreement, this scenario aims at

quantifying the impact of a proposal made by

the chair of the WTO’s agriculture negotiations,

Ambassador Crawford Falconer, in December

2008 (WTO, 2008). He proposed a general

tariff reduction based on a tiered formula,

a reduction of TRQs in quota tariffs and the

possibility to exclude certain products, called

sensitive products, at the cost of the extension

of TRQs for the sensitive products for imports.

The tariff reductions analysed in this section

are based on tiered formulas with four bands,

implying that tariffs that are high will be cut

more aggressively than tariffs that are low and

thus distort trade less (Table 25). For example,

if the initial tariff, i.e., expressed relative to the

value of imported goods is greater than 75%, the

developed countries will be obliged to reduce

it by 70%. The same initial tariff for developing

countries will be reduced by 38% due to different

thresholds for developed and developing

countries.

The developed countries are the EU-15,

EU- 10, Norway, Bulgaria, Romania, the Western

Balkans, the rest of Europe, Russia, Belarus,

Ukraine, USA, Canada, Japan, Australia and

New Zealand. All other countries are developing

countries.

For TRQs in quota tariffs, the following

reduction is proposed: a reduction by 50%, but

at least to 10%, for developed countries, and all

tariffs that are already below 5% should be set

to zero. For developing countries, in quota tariffs

are reduced by 15%, with no other rules.

It should be noted that CAPRI differentiates

between specific and ad-valorem tariffs. Specific

tariffs represent fixed amounts of Euro/t that are

charged on imports. Ad-valorem tariffs are charged

as a percentage of the value of imports. The

tariff cuts are applied to ad-valorem equivalents

(AVEs). Ad-valorem tariff equivalents have to be

calculated for specific tariffs. This calculation is

done by dividing the specific tariffs by the average

import price of tariffs of the respective product.

The proposal also allows each country to

define certain products as sensitive. Pelikan et

al. (2010) show, by comparing EU cumulated

import values with the percentage of tariff lines

used for the accumulation, that already 1% (5%)

of the tariff lines (6 digits) in the EU can account

for up to 27% (55%) of the total imported value.

Although it is unlikely that the trade value will be

chosen as a criterion to define the product list,

this result shows how the definition of sensitive

products can have serious impacts on the

remaining protection level. If a product is defined

as sensitive, a smaller tariff cut is used at the cost

of an extension of the respective tariff rate quota.

The proposal leaves the options to reduce the

tariff cut in the formula by 33%, 50% or 66%,

with corresponding tariff rate quota extensions of

Table 25: Tariff reduction formula in the Falconer proposal

Reductions for...

... developed countries (in %) ... developing countries (in %)

Thresholds for tariffs 1) cut Thresholds for tariffs 1) cut

0 <= 20 50.00 0 <= 30 33.33

20 <= 50 57.00 30 <= 80 38.00

50 <= 75 64.00 80 <= 130 42,67

> 75 70.00 > 130 46.67

1) Tariffs are translated to Ad Valorem Equivalents (AVEs) to determine which reduction percentage applies.

Page 58: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

56

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

3%, 3.5% or 4% of domestic consumption of that

good in the importing country.

Because, to the best of our knowledge, no

information is yet available on the definition of

sensitive products, we have chosen the lowest tariff

decrease for sensitive products (66%) combined

with the highest tariff rate quota extension of 4%.

For developed countries, the extension is only 2/3

of this 4%. We further assume that the additional

tariff rate quotas are distributed among global and

bilateral TRQs according to their initial shares in

the base year.

We define the following as sensitive products

for developed countries: cheese, butter, beef, pork

and poultry meat, sugar, tomatoes and apples. For

developing countries, the sensitive products are

defined as: beef, sugar, rice, wine and skim milk

powder. The current scenario also assumes that

all export subsidies are removed.

Results

In Table 26, the WTO scenario and its

percentage changes to the baseline for TRQs, MFN

tariffs for each product group and all importers

for the EU-27 are presented. The change for

each product group is the result of the different

tariff regimes for the countries that import into

the EU-15/EU-10 and BuR. For example, the

global TRQs for meat and dairy products and

secondary products increase due to the expansion

mechanics for TRQs. Also, TRQs for beef, pork

and poultry meat increase up to four percent of

domestic consumption, which includes human

consumption, feed use and processing. This result

leads to an increase of 340% for meat and 186%

for dairy products (cheese and butter are sensitive

products in this aggregate).

Among secondary products, sugar is

responsible for a 50% increase to 324 thousand

tonnes of global TRQs and 3051 thousand

tonnes of bilateral TRQs. TRQs for apples and

peaches exist at baseline for bilateral TRQs,

which increased by 50%. Global TRQs for

apples and tomatoes are newly introduced. The

corresponding tariff reductions range between

50% and 70% for products that are not defined

as sensitive. For beef, sugar and dairy products,

the drop is less pronounced.

The welfare measure shown in Table 27

is decomposed into consumer welfare (money

metric), agricultural (primary factor) income,

taxpayers’ costs and profits for processing. Welfare

changes stem from changes in production,

consumption and prices as well as changes in

subsidies and tariff revenues. The absolute values

and differences are shown in Table 26.

It becomes apparent that the implementation

of the Falconer proposal leads to total welfare

Table 26: Changes of TRQs and tariffs aggregated for all imports into the EU-27

Global Quota Bilateral Quotas Ad val. MFN Spec. MFN

WTO Scenario [1000t]

% to Baseline

WTO Scenario [1000t]

% to Baseline

WTO Scenario

[%]

% to Baseline

WTO Scenario [Euro/t]

% to Baseline

Cereals 6181 663 2,6 -65 32 -66

Other arable field crops 0 -100 282 4,3 -50

Vegetables and Permanent crops 1309 +inf 1173 50 2,4 -60 92 -44

Meat 1944 340 444 56 6,8 -41 1362 -28

Other Animal products 135 -100 0,8 -70 208 -70

Dairy products 639 186 126 57 8,1 -27 1100 -30

Oils 6 57 0 2,4 -50 13 -44

Oil cakes 0 -100 -100 -100 0

Secondary products 324 50 3051 30 -100 214 -29

Page 59: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

57

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

gain (+3.1 billion €). The computations indicate

that trade liberalisation constitutes a welfare

gain for the consumer of 8.5 billion €. Consumer

welfare is a metric measure calculated as the

income required to obtain the utility of the

simulation consumption bundle at the prices

of the baseline scenario. Tariff reduction with

lower prices causes a consumer gain in the EU,

a producer loss, and lower tariff revenues due

to efficiency increases when more goods are

produced where the cost of doing so is lowest.

Table 27: EU-27 welfare position changes in million €Baseline WTO

Million € abs change to BAS

Total Welfare a+b+c+d-e 7.755.742 7.758.851 3.109

Consumer Welfare a 7.623.298 7.631.811 8.513

Agricultural Income b 207.502 200.692 -6.810

Profit of Dairies c 31.661 31.661 0

Tariff Revenues d 4.223 3.611 -612

Tax Payers Cost e 110.941 108.924 -2.017

Agricultural income a g-k+f 207.502 200.682 -6.820

Premiums f 53.733 53.659 -74

Gross value added g-k 153.769 147.024 -6.745

EAA Output g h+i 407.887 394.823 -13.064

EAA Input k l+m 254.118 247.799 -6.319

EAA Crops h-1 148.297 146.730 -1.567

Output Crops h 217.767 215.826 -1.941

Input Crop l 69.470 69.097 -373

EAA Animal i-m 83.515 78.052 -5.463

Output Animals i 190.120 178.996 -11.124

Input Animal specific m 106.605 100.944 -5.661

Input others n 78.043 77.758 -285

Figure 17: Changes of producer prices in the WTO scenario

Page 60: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

58

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

Tabl

e 28

: La

nd u

se c

hang

es f

or d

iffe

rent

EU

agg

rega

tes

and

MS

in t

he W

TO s

cena

rio

Cere

als

Oils

eeds

Othe

r ara

ble

crop

sVe

geta

bles

&

Perm

anen

t cro

psFo

dder

act

iviti

esSe

t asi

de a

nd fa

llow

la

nd

Base

line

WTO

Base

line

WTO

Base

line

WTO

Base

line

WTO

Base

line

WTO

Base

line

WTO

EU-A

ggre

gate

1.00

0 he

ctar

e%

1.

000

hect

are

%

1.00

0 he

ctar

e%

1.

000

hect

are

%

1.00

0 he

ctar

e%

1.

000

hect

are

%

EU

-15

34.6

18-0

,77.

039

1,3

6.13

6-1

,612

.936

-0,6

62.8

49-0

,38.

718

1,7

EU

-10

16.1

861,

12.

046

-0,9

983

2,5

1.10

7-0

,98.

835

-1,2

3.04

6-2

,0

Bulg

aria

1.35

5-0

,651

60,

125

0-0

,229

0-0

,02.

157

-0,1

569

1,1

Ro

man

ia4.

745

-0,6

887

0,7

436

-0,7

669

-0,2

5.02

7-0

,275

41,

7EU

-15

Be

lgiu

m26

5-0

,295

0,8

188

-1,4

780,

583

0-0

,616

3,0

De

nmar

k1.

553

-0,4

114

0,5

165

-1,6

18-0

,360

2-0

,122

12,

3

Germ

any

6.42

9-0

,91.

972

1,4

947

-2,5

314

-0,1

5.67

5-0

,348

61,

9

Aust

ria71

8-0

,420

50,

510

9-1

,263

0,1

2.02

6-0

,416

21,

7

Neth

erla

nds

243

0,3

421,

627

0-1

,215

60,

01.

201

-0,2

82,

0

Fran

ce8.

898

-0,8

2.25

21,

597

2-4

,71.

247

-0,1

13.7

74-0

,41.

288

2,3

Po

rtuga

l25

3-0

,326

71,

28

-0,3

791

-0,3

2.29

6-0

,414

71,

7

Spai

n5.

969

-0,8

947

1,1

1.88

70,

15.

788

-0,7

11.4

13-0

,33.

724

1,5

Gr

eece

1.01

8-0

,414

1,2

487

-0,5

1.36

0-0

,92.

203

0,0

584

1,4

Ita

ly3.

931

-0,4

373

1,2

438

-1,9

2.90

4-0

,56.

023

-0,3

769

2,3

Ire

land

291

0,6

30,

926

-0,1

7-0

,23.

946

-0,2

264,

8

Finl

and

1.23

4-0

,310

80,

251

-2,2

32-0

,458

5-0

,234

70,

4

Swed

en1.

002

-0,5

800,

110

9-3

,552

-0,4

1.45

6-0

,852

31,

2

Unite

d Ki

ngdo

m2.

813

-1,0

566

0,8

478

-1,1

125

-0,1

10.8

180,

041

82,

8EU

-10

Cz

ech

Repu

blic

1.57

91,

644

0-1

,314

39,

912

0,2

1.05

0-2

,324

6-3

,6

Esto

nia

423

1,1

58-1

,29

-3,2

3-1

,128

2-1

,213

-1,9

Hu

ngar

y3.

004

1,1

548

-0,6

3917

,242

3-0

,91.

112

-2,5

293

-2,1

Li

thua

nia

802

2,6

161

-1,6

116

-0,2

27-0

,21.

034

-0,7

349

-3,0

La

tvia

450

3,3

93-3

,149

-0,6

20-0

,474

0-0

,524

2-3

,4

Pola

nd9.

012

0,7

465

-0,2

520

0,3

541

-1,0

3.50

2-0

,91.

878

-1,5

Sl

oven

ia77

2,2

110,

77

-0,9

22-0

,038

3-0

,51

-0,2

Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

791

0,7

269

-0,7

924,

014

-0,1

683

-1,0

10-1

,3

Cypr

us49

0,5

09

-0,5

43-0

,844

0,1

120,

2

Mal

ta0,

0388

,91

-1,6

3-0

,55

-0,5

10,

1

Page 61: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

59

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisAgricultural income is reduced by 6.8 billion

€. Tax revenue for the EU-27 decreases. The

reduction of agricultural (primary factor) income

comes mainly from animal production, with 5.4

billion €, compared to 1.5 billion € from crop

production. Agricultural income is calculated as

output minus inputs plus premiums. Premiums

decrease only slightly, by 74 million €, due to

small land use change. These results can be

understood in the light of the price changes shown

in Figure 17, where products with price decreases

of more than five percent are presented.

Almost all agricultural product prices come

under pressure when tariffs are reduced and

the export competition is improved for non-EU

trade partners. A distinctive price reduction can

be observed for sugar of 14%, beef meat 13%,

sheep and goat meat 11%, fruits 11%, butter

10% and cream and rice 5%. As a result, the raw

Table 29: Herd-size changes for different EU aggregates and MS in the WTO scenario

Cattle activities Beef meat activities Other animals

Baseline WTO Baseline WTO Baseline WTO

EU-Aggregate 1.000 heads % 1.000 heads % 1.000 heads %

EU-15 73.041 -2,5 24.412 -4,1 336.893 -1,2

EU-10 6.820 -1,7 1.337 -5,7 43.727 -0,8

Bulgaria 968 -1,3 227 -4,3 1.833 -2,2

Romania 3.241 -0,6 842 -0,5 13.775 -0,7

EU-15

Belgium 2.482 -2,7 695 -5,2 12.872 0,0

Denmark 1.422 -0,7 327 2,2 26.310 -0,2

Germany 9.445 -1,0 1.645 -2,7 51.466 -0,4

Austria 1.812 -1,7 533 -3,6 5.242 -0,5

Netherlands 3.806 -1,7 62 -5,1 18.390 -0,7

France 17.605 -2,8 6.341 -4,6 42.954 -1,1

Portugal 1.494 -2,7 666 -3,3 8.256 -0,9

Spain 8.745 -3,5 4.496 -4,3 80.251 -1,3

Greece 756 -3,2 324 -4,5 17.472 -2,3

Italy 8.038 -2,6 2.598 -4,8 25.927 -0,5

Ireland 5.890 -2,6 2.599 -3,2 7.223 -2,3

Finland 793 -2,9 228 -3,5 2.228 -0,7

Sweden 1.155 -2,2 354 -3,2 3.327 -0,5

United Kingdom 9.597 -2,9 3.546 -4,1 34.975 -3,5

EU-10

Czech Republic 537 -3,0 115 -5,7 4.142 -1,0

Estonia 162 -0,2 22 -1,2 538 -0,8

Hungary 418 -1,7 53 -6,5 5.623 -0,9

Lithuania 629 4,3 59 -0,2 1.414 -0,7

Latvia 314 -1,7 64 -2,2 390 -1,4

Poland 4.049 -2,2 841 -5,9 28.040 -0,6

Slovenia 376 -3,8 122 -7,6 510 -0,9

Slovak Republic 241 -2,9 39 -9,4 1.356 -1,0

Cyprus 77 -2,8 20 -5,6 1.582 -1,2

Malta 17 -2,4 3 -8,4 133 -0,3

Page 62: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

60

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

milk price comes under pressure and decreases

by 3%. Tariff reduction causes additional

demand for imports into the EU. Total imports

into the EU increase, particularly of meat (30%),

dairy products (22%), cereals (7%) and pulses

(10%).

Increasing imports affects the domestic

supply in the EU and, hence, land use and herd

sizes. The effects on plant production for the EU

are rather moderate, as depicted in Table 28. The

increase of cereals from the EU-10 is noticeable

and results from a price increase due to baseline

prices compared to the EU-15. One could also

expect that the fodder area should be significantly

reduced given the price decreases for beef meat

and some other milk products. This is not the

case because the substitution from intensive to

extensive grassland keeps the total land area for

fodder almost unchanged. Because oilseed prices

decrease only moderately and in combination

with decreased competition for land from other

crops, oilseed cropping hectares increase by

1.3% in the EU-15. The increased production

Table 30: Income change in € per head for all activities in the WTO scenario

EU-27 EU-15 EU- 10

Crop activity aggregated € per ha % to Basline € per ha % to Basline € per ha % to Basline

Cereals 290 -2 327 -4 264 4

Oilseeds 424 -0 436 -1 488 1

Vegetables and Permanent crops 6131 0 6549 0 2437 -4

Fodder activities 226 0 216 0 251 -0

Set aside and fallow land 149 1 177 0 102 -0

Animal activity aggregated € per head % to Basline € per head % to Basline € per head % to Basline

All cattle activities 466 -9 490 -8 505 -7

Beef meat activities 129 -34 137 -32 195 -30

Other animals 60 -3 59 -3 49 -3

Meat production activity sorted

Other Cows 54 -66 64 -57 -27 -56

Male adult cattle low weight 56 -43 62 -40 125 -32

Heifers fattening low weight 53 -31 66 -26 52 -39

Heifers fattening high weight 209 -28 248 -25 153 -39

Male adult cattle high weight 339 -23 367 -22 299 -24

Heifers breeding 151 -20 165 -19 46 -22

Sheep and Goat fattening 34 -13 38 -13 26 -13

Raising male calves 173 -12 187 -12 126 -20

Milk Ewes and Goat 52 -10 56 -9 42 -8

Raising female Calves 147 -10 154 -10 157 -8

Poultry fattening * 314 -9 282 -10 269 -9

Dairy Cows low yield 1006 -8 1200 -7 668 -7

Dairy Cows high yield 1760 -6 1946 -6 1187 -5

Fattening female calves 162 -4 171 -4 44 15

Other animals 60 -3 59 -3 49 -3

Pig fattening 25 -2 25 -2 20 -4

Pig Breeding 102 -1 112 -1 46 -5

Fattening male calves 145 -1 156 -1 41 -1

Laying hens * 3771 4 2908 7 5051 0

* Per 1.000 heads

Page 63: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

61

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisalso leads to a small decrease of oilseed imports

to the EU by 2% and a small increase in oilseed

cultivation by 1%.

In Table 29, the effect on animal herd sizes

induced by price reduction and increased imports

is presented. Beef cattle activities are reduced by

4% in the EU-15, 6% in the EU-10 and 4% in

Bulgaria. Consequently, all other cattle activities

(including dairy cattle and raising cattle) are also

reduced. Also, sizeable reductions in some MS,

such as the UK and Ireland, are observed for other

animals, such as sheep and goats, due to the price

reduction. However, the changes, compared

to significant price decreases, are rather small,

particular for beef meat. The main reason is that

part of the loss is passed on to the dairy cows

via the calves. The decreased demand for calves

hence can be satisfied by a smaller number of

suckler cows, so this activity decreases by 4.6%

in the EU. Another, albeit less important, reason

for the conservative reaction is the decreased

demand for fodder, translating into lower feeding

costs and less fodder production.

Income changes in € per hectare or head

for the EU-27, EU-15 and EU-10 are presented

in Table 30. The first five rows depict the

income change per hectare for the crop activity

aggregates. The effects are rather moderate,

whereas the income for meat production

activities decreased for beef meat production

by -34% in the EU-27. The last block in Table

30 divides the effect by presenting all meat

production activities in descending order by

percentage income change. The largest income

loss per head can be observed for suckler cows,

where an income reduction from 54 € to 24 €

per head is calculated. A subsequent decline can

be found for other meat production activities.

Table 30 also exposes the income disparity

between EU-15 and EU-10. Please note that the

total income change depends strongly on the

absolute level of income per head. For example,

dairy cows lose in absolute terms almost 80 €

per head, compared to approximately 19 €

per suckler cow. The effects of income change

aggregated over the production activities and all

farm types in a Nuts2 region are shown in Map

2 of Figure 18.

Figure 18: Density of beef meat activity and change of income by Nuts2 region (WTO)

Page 64: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

62

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

For comparison, Map 1 presents the density

of beef meat production activities in the EU in

heads per hectare UAA. As expected, regions with

intensive beef meat production lose comparably

more income. Overall, the income loss ranges

between 14% and 1%.

Income effects by farm type and economic

size aggregated across the EU-25 are summarised

in Table 31. Absolute income loses are the

largest for the dairy farm type, at 1.8 billion €,

followed by mixed crops livestock at 0.8 billion

€ and cattle, dairying -rearing and fattening at 0.7

billion €. Medium-sized farms are most affected,

at 2.6 billion €, when considering farm size. In

percentage terms, the farm type cattle dairying,

rearing and fattening loses the most income, at

8%, followed by dairy farming at 6%.

The distributional issues within the farm

types are analysed in Figure 19 by specialisation,

where absolute income changes are compared

to the baseline for the WTO scenario. On the

x-axis, all farm groups are normalised to 100%,

and for each single type of farming (small curves),

a curve is derived. These smaller curves are

arranged in ascending order and accumulate the

income change compared to the baseline. For all

farm types, the negative slope dominates, which

means that mainly income losses are realised.

Of all farm types, 95% lose income, whereas 5%

realise income growth (light-blue curve). The total

aggregated income of all farm types (represented

by the endpoint of the light-blue curve) drops off

by approximately 3%, or 5.9 billion €, for the EU-

25. Note that the agricultural income loss in Table

27 of -6.8 billion € is the income loss in BuR,

not based on farm types. The income loss for the

following farm types is noticeable: dairying, mixed

crops and livestock and residual. Note that the

total income effect is indicated by the endpoint of

each curve and is identical to the total income loss

for each farm type shown in Table 31.

Figure 20 shows the income loss evaluated

on a per-hectare basis. The average income loss

Table 31: Aggregated income change in the EU-25 by farm type in the WTO scenario

EU-25

Baseline WTO

Type of Farming Million € change to Baseline % to Baseline

Cereals, oilseed & protein crops 15.435 15.115 -320,2 -2,1

General field & mixed cropping 19.300 18.944 -356,7 -1,8

Dairying 30.233 28.443 -1.790,5 -5,9

Cattle- Dairying -rearing & fattening 8.522 7.856 -665,3 -7,8

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 10.515 9.979 -536,2 -5,1

Granivores 8.026 7.836 -190,3 -2,4

Mixed livestock holdings 4.735 4.502 -232,8 -4,9

Mixed crops-livestock 16.917 16.133 -783,8 -4,6

Vineyards 5.653 5.656 3,7 0,1

Fruit and citrus fruit 4.059 4.139 80,4 2,0

Olives 6.585 6.318 -266,2 -4,0

Permanent crops mixed 1.434 1.408 -25,2 -1,8

Horticulture 1.204 1.194 -10,3 -0,9

Economic Size Class

<=16 ESU 30.699 29.867 -832,6 -2,7

>16 and <=100 ESU 57.952 55.346 -2.605,3 -4,5

>100 ESU 43.966 42.310 -1.655,5 -3,8

Residual 60.357 59.544 -813,6 -1,3

Page 65: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

63

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisFigure 19: Income distribution in the WTO scenario

Figure 20: Change of income in €/ha UAA for important EU-25 farm types (WTO)

Page 66: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

64

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

per hectare is provided in brackets in the legend.

The income of 1.8 billion € for dairy farms is

distributed as follows: 15% of dairy farms lose

more than 150 € and 45% lose between 100 €

and 150 € per UAA. Thus, there is an overall loss

of 100 € for dairy farms per ha UAA in the WTO

scenario compared to the 30 € loss per ha UAA

when considering all farm types.

Conclusion

This chapter analysed a possible WTO

agreement proposed by the chair of the WTO’s

agriculture negotiations, Ambassador Crawford

Falconer. The focus of the analysis is related to

the market and income effects of the proposal for

EU farms. The simulation results show that tariff

reduction increases consumer welfare in the EU

by 8.5 billion €, whereas income decreases for

the agricultural sector by 6.8 billion € (-3%),

mainly driven by the negative income change

in the animal sectors of 5.5 billion €. Reduced

trade protection increases imports and decreases

producer and market prices in the EU, particularly

for sugar (-14%) and beef (-13%) but also for

butter (-10%), cream (-5%) and other fruits

(-5%). The simulation showed that these price

reductions translate into relatively small changes

in agricultural production, for example, for beef

meat at -4% (highest production change). The

same results were found for land use and herd

size changes.

Despite the moderate change in production,

price reductions directly affected the amount of

farm income available to pay for primary factors

like land and labour. The analysis has shown

sizable impacts on farm income for different

farm types. Generally, farm types specialised in

livestock production showed the largest income

reductions. The largest negative income effects

were observed for cattle, dairying, rearing and

fattening, dairy, mixed crops and livestock and

sheep and goat farm types.

An explanation for the rather moderate

production change given the significant price

reduction is that a substantial part of the current

protection and support given to EU agriculture

is capitalised in land values. There will be only

minor redistributions between agricultural sectors

as the price reductions will be absorbed by the

decrease in land values.

Also, agriculture is a sector with many

linkages between production activities. The drop

in beef prices caused only moderate production

decreases because calves for beef production are

derived from the dairy sector. Because the dairy

production does not decrease to any significant

extent (-1%), the dairy sector continue to deliver

the same amount of calves to the beef sector. The

inflow of calves from dairy farmers will dampen

the total output response in beef production and

reduce dairy farmers’ income due to the reduction

in calf prices (-40%).

Another factor limiting the production

response is the farm type model itself. Although

no direct comparison with simulations of the

Table 32: Input categories dependent on crude oil price and transmission elasticities

CAPRI Inputstransission elasticities

CAPRI Inputstransission elasticities

code description code description

NITF Nitrogen fertiliser 0.5 BGAS Heating gas and oil 0.6

PHOF Phospate in fertiliser [P2O5] 0.2 EFUL Fuels 0.6

POTF Potassium in fertiliser [K2O] 0.2 ELUB Lubricants 0.2

PLAP Plant protection 0.3 INPO Others 0.1

REPM Maintenance 0.1 SERI Services 0.1

REPB Maintenance buildings 0.1 IPHA Pharmaceutical 0.1

Source: Own calculations

Page 67: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

65

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

WTO scenario at an aggregated regional level

was done, in general, the farm type supply model

is less reactive to price changes because of its

high specialisation in land endowment/animal

density and crop rotation of the farm types. For

example, a sheep farmer with only grassland can

rarely switch to cash crop production. Hence,

production adjusts less and price changes are

larger.

Compared to other similar studies (e.g.,

Junker et al. 2005, Jansson, 2006) with no

sensitive products considered, the total welfare

gain of 3.1 billion € in our study is low.

III.3 Macroeconomic Environment Scenario

Description

The macroeconomic environment is an

important determining factor in the agricultural

sector’s development. The food crisis in

2007/2008 demonstrated that agricultural prices

are responsive to macro pressures such as crude-

oil price changes and economic growth. In this

scenario, we simulate the farm-level effects of

a hypothetical economic recovery scenario that

may lead to higher GDP growth and higher oil

prices.

The crude oil price in the CAPRI baseline

is taken from the AGLINK baseline. It is equal

to 38 US dollars/barrel in 2005, increasing

to 104 US dollars/barrel in 2020. In the

macroeconomic environment (ME) scenario,

we simulate an increase in the crude oil price

by 50% relative to the baseline. This increase

is translated into increased production costs

for farmers via transmission elasticities. The

implicit oil price elasticities differ among the

input cost categories available in the supply

model, as shown in Table 328.

In addition to the impact of the price of oil

on the supply side, we also need to consider

its impact on the market side. CAPRI assumes

a positive relationship between transport

costs and crude oil prices. Transport costs are

assumed to have a fixed margin and to depend

on the locations of the trading partners.9 An

increase of the oil price is assumed to shift the

fixed margins upward to an extent determined

by the transmission elasticities for fuels (EFUL).

In addition, for all regions with behavioural

functions, a shift in agricultural production costs

8 We planned to derive these elasticities from the AGLINK model, but the goal of attaining compatibility between AGLINK and CAPRI inputs was outside the scope of this project. AGLINK distinguishes the price indices specific for a crop and an animal aggregate for a few countries and with respect to some crops for other countries. An analysis was performed where AGLINK was shocked with oil price changes, and the effect of those shocks on the cost of production index (CPCI) by which most prices in AGLINK are normalised was investigated. The resulting elasticities for most countries were so small that no effect at all would have appeared in the scenario. The only usable elasticity from this exercise was that of the world fertiliser price, which was calculated to be 0.47 and is thus very consistent with our assumption. Lacking any other information on the required elasticities, we finally used the values presented in Table 32, which were already used in the CAPRI system and were selected based only on plausibility considerations.

9 This requirement means that, e.g., if transport costs between country A and country B are increased, the import prices for agricultural goods in country B that are imported from A become higher, so imports will be less attractive for consumers in B.

Table 33: Overview of the macroeconomic environment scenario

Scenario Description Assumptions

1. ME-full Combination of ME-oil and ME-GDP

2. ME-oil Oil price increase of 50%Translation into production and transport costs via

elasticities

3. ME-GDPGlobal additional GDP increase by 1% per

annum = ca. 16% higher GDP compared to the baseline

Consumer expenditures increase by the same percentage.

Page 68: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

66

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

using a price index of all non-agricultural goods is

introduced. The same price index is used to take

into account the impact of oil prices on consumer

non-agricultural/food prices. This consumer price

effect is derived from AGLINK price simulation

scenarios and is afterwards translated into CAPRI.

The ME scenario also includes assumptions

regarding changes in GDP. The yearly growth

rate of the world GDP is assumed to be one

percentage point higher than the rate assumed

at baseline.10 To better identify the impact of the

10 This value was provided by the IPTS.

macroeconomy on farms, we decompose the

ME scenario (ME-full), which comprises both oil

price and GDP effects, into two sub-scenarios:

the first sub-scenario considers only the crude oil

price effect (ME-oil), and the second considers

only the GDP effect (ME-GDP) (Table 33).

Results

To analyse the scenario, we start with an

overview of the impacts on agricultural markets

and prices. Increasing oil prices and higher GDP

growth are likely to increase market prices. A

higher oil price drives input costs up, shifting the

implicit supply curves to the left. Increased GDP

Table 34: Price effects for different EU aggregates

Baseline ME-full ME-oil ME-GDP

Euro / t % to Baseline % to Baseline % to Baseline

Cereals

EU-15 113 22 2,6 20

EU-10 93 26 1,9 25

BuR 128 21 2,9 18

Oilseeds

EU-15 253 18 2,9 15

EU-10 261 19 3,2 16

BuR 243 23 4,9 18

Other arable field crops

EU-15 180 9 1,1 8

EU-10 101 11 1,3 10

BuR 107 12 1,2 10

Vegetables & Permanent crops

EU-15 1175 7 0,6 7

EU-10 434 16 0,2 16

BuR 472 13 0,2 13

Meat

EU-15 2078 30 1,4 29

EU-10 1073 28 1 28

BuR 1485 23 1 22

Other Animal products

EU-15 663 20 0,1 22

EU-10 734 11 0,1 12

BuR 1091 13 0,1 13

Dairy products

EU-15 1345 12 0,2 11

EU-10 764 13 0,3 12

BuR 936 10 0,3 10

Oils

EU-15 1441 28 1,4 26

EU-10 646 22 2,2 20

BuR 541 30 2,3 27

Oil cakes

EU-15 250 31 5,4 26

EU-10 139 25 7,3 19

BuR 117 37 6,6 31

Page 69: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

67

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisgrowth also affects agricultural markets on the

demand side. It enhances demand for agricultural

commodities by shifting the demand curves to

the right. The price effects of the ME scenario

are shown in Table 34 for the EU aggregates. For

all product aggregates, prices increase in each

scenario. The price increases in the ME-full sub-

scenario are larger than the sum of the effects in

the other two sub-scenarios. The most interesting

finding is that the price effect of GDP growth is

much larger than that of the oil price increase.

An annual GDP growth rate that is increased

by 1% increases the total value of GDP by 16%

in 2020 relative to the baseline level. Such

an increase in consumption expenditures is

equivalent to a strong demand increase leading

to price increases of between 5% and 30%.

However, a 50% increase in the crude oil price is

only partially translated into input costs, which, in

turn, are only partially transferred to commodity

prices, causing price increases of between 1%

and 10%. Generally, it has been observed that

increasing input costs in the past did not lead to

considerable output price increases in agriculture.

Comparing the situation in 2009 to the situation

before the price peak in 2007, data reveal that

agricultural prices returned to comparable levels

observed in 2005, whereas the oil price and

especially fertiliser costs were significantly higher

in 2009 relative to 2005.

Table 34 also reveals differences in price

effects between commodities and also between

the three EU aggregates. The latter difference is

due to their handling as different trading blocks

in CAPRI. Each block has its own market price

and thus reacts differently to shocks. Differences

between commodities can be explained partly

through different energy demands. Oilseeds,

for example, are more energy intensive than

cereals, and therefore the prices of the former

increase more strongly in the ME-oil sub-

scenario. Furthermore, differences in the demand

elasticities induce different price effects in the

ME-GDP sub-scenario.

The impact of the ME scenario on supply and

demand of agricultural commodities is shown in

Table 35. Following price effects, stronger supply-

demand effects are found for the ME-GDP sub-

scenario as compared to the ME-oil sub-scenario.

The supply of the illustrated product aggregates

increases between 3% and 20% in the ME-GDP

sub-scenario and between -2% and 6% in the

ME-oil sub-scenario.

For the demand side, we observe demand

increases between 1% and 13% in the ME-GDP

sub-scenario and between -2% and 1% in the

ME-oil sub-scenario. Again, differences in supply

and demand effects across commodities and

country aggregates can be explained through

differences in supply and demand elasticities as

well as the initial quantities and energy demands

of each activity.

Increasing product prices generally change

the production incentives for the different farm

types. We observe two effects. First, because

the price increases are not uniform across

agricultural commodities, shifts occur in the

relative competitiveness of commodities, leading

to varying production effects across farm types.

Second, the increase in agricultural prices

stimulates the intensification and extension of

production on arable land. At the EU-25 level in

the ME-full sub-scenario, arable land expands by

5.5 million ha (3.8%) and grassland is reduced by

2.5 million ha (4.6%). Overall, the UAA increases

by 3 million ha (1.7%). The expansion of the UAA

takes place at the expense of the forestry sector.

This effect differs across farm types depending on

the farms’ specialisation.

As illustrated in Figure 21, the two types of

cropping farms considered (cereals, oilseeds and

protein crops and field cropping and mixed) show

stronger decreases of grassland area compared

to the two livestock farms considered (cattle

dairying, rearing and fattening and sheep and

other grazing livestock). The grassland area at

livestock farms stays almost constant. The relative

Page 70: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

68

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

Tabl

e 35

: M

arke

t ba

lanc

e fo

r di

ffer

ent

EU a

ggre

gate

s

Base

line

ME-

full

ME-

oil

ME-

GDP

Dom

estic

Pr

oduc

tion

Dom

estic

De

man

dNe

t Tra

deDo

mes

tic

Prod

uctio

nDo

mes

tic

Dem

and

Net T

rade

Dom

estic

Pr

oduc

tion

Dom

estic

De

man

dNe

t Tra

deDo

mes

tic

Prod

uctio

nDo

mes

tic

Dem

and

Net T

rade

(100

0 t)

(100

0 t)

(100

0 t)

% t

o Ba

selin

e%

to

Base

line

% t

o Ba

selin

e%

to

Base

line

% t

o Ba

selin

e%

to

Base

line

% t

o Ba

selin

e%

to

Base

line

% t

o Ba

selin

e

Cere

als

EU-1

522

0990

2005

1420

476

13,7

8,7

62,5

-1,1

-0,5

-6,7

14,7

8,9

71,8

EU-1

068

427

5510

113

326

18,4

5,8

70,4

-1,3

0,0

-6,9

19,8

5,9

77,4

BuG

2153

918

004

3536

16,5

8,0

59,8

-1,6

-0,8

-5,5

18,2

7,9

70,3

Oils

eeds

EU-1

522

180

3971

2-1

7532

8,4

5,1

-0,9

0,5

0,3

-0,1

8,0

5,0

-1,1

EU-1

051

2843

9373

412

,02,

767

,62,

8-0

,020

,18,

92,

646

,2

BuG

2516

1904

611

18,4

2,1

69,2

1,3

-0,2

6,2

17,1

2,5

62,5

Othe

r ara

ble

field

cro

ps

EU-1

542

129

4128

784

26,

63,

714

8,6

0,5

0,2

13,4

6,4

3,5

147,

8

EU-1

052

8875

33-2

245

8,0

3,0

8,9

0,1

-0,6

2,1

8,2

3,2

8,6

BuG

4236

4751

-515

10,9

11,8

-19,

2-0

,3-0

,30,

411

,512

,3-1

8,4

Vege

tabl

es &

Per

man

ent

crop

s

EU-1

511

7543

1298

08-1

2265

3,6

2,0

13,3

0,3

-0,2

4,3

3,4

2,2

9,7

EU-1

013

551

1488

7-1

336

5,4

2,8

23,6

0,0

0,0

-0,2

5,3

2,8

23,1

BuG

1229

112

215

763,

52,

024

4,8

0,0

-0,0

5,8

3,5

2,1

232,

0

Mea

t

EU-1

538

134

3463

235

0212

,99,

447

,8-0

,0-0

,10,

912

,99,

546

,0

EU-1

065

7662

8529

111

,18,

076

,6-0

,2-0

,2-1

,011

,48,

280

,7

BuG

1194

1961

-767

6,8

-2,5

16,9

0,2

-0,4

1,2

6,5

-2,1

15,6

Othe

r Ani

mal

pro

duct

s

EU-1

561

6955

7859

111

,78,

046

,3-0

,40,

2-6

,113

,27,

567

,2

EU-1

096

112

55-2

944,

46,

7-1

4,0

-0,1

0,1

-0,9

5,0

6,4

-10,

7

BuG

346

532

-186

3,1

15,9

-39,

80,

00,

4-1

,13,

314

,9-3

6,6

Dairy

pro

duct

s

EU-1

559

996

5839

316

048,

38,

38,

1-0

,10,

0-2

,78,

48,

39,

9

EU-1

098

6594

6539

93,

33,

5-0

,5-0

,2-0

,1-2

,63,

53,

61,

0

BuG

739

736

24,

11,

678

3,1

-0,0

0,0

-14,

84,

01,

577

5,1

Oils

EU-1

514

410

2892

7-1

4517

5,5

-11,

227

,80,

0-1

,02,

05,

6-1

0,5

26,4

EU-1

014

5629

80-1

524

2,2

-6,8

15,4

0,1

1,7

-3,2

2,1

-8,3

18,3

BuG

781

972

-192

4,1

3,4

-0,5

-0,5

1,4

-9,3

4,6

2,2

7,4

Page 71: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

69

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

expansion of arable land, on the other hand, is

quite similar for all four farm types.

Further, the figure reveals that the UAA

of these farm types is decreasing in the ME-oil

sub-scenario because the price increase is not

sufficient to compensate for increased costs.

Similar results are observed for the rest of the

farm types. Figure 22 reports more detailed land

use effects of the ME scenario for the same farm

types depicted in Figure 21.

According to Figure 22, the land cover

change is much less reactive to price changes

for livestock farms than it is for cropping

farms. The two types of livestock farms react

very little in terms of changes in the land

cover, whereas we see sizeable impacts for

the two types of cropping farms in the ME-

full and ME-GDP sub-scenarios. In particular,

cereal production is expanded greatly due

to higher demand for food and feed. Apart

from the substitution effects with grassland

and forestry described in Figure 21, cereal

expansion is also driven by conversion of

fallow land into production.

The unresponsiveness of the two livestock

farms in terms of land use does not imply that

the higher product prices and higher input costs

do not affect their production. Table 36 shows

production effects for the four selected farm type

aggregates at the EU-27 level.

According to Table 36, the two livestock

farm types indeed increase the production of

animal products by approximately 6% in the

ME-full sub-scenario. This production increase is

Figure 21: Area effects for selected EU-25 farm type aggregates

Page 72: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

70

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

mainly achieved via increased stocking densities.

Furthermore, the oil price increase generally leads

solely to production increases for crops, whereas

fodder activities and animal products show only

slight production changes.

Figure 23 shows stocking density changes in

the ME-full sub-scenario relative to the baseline.

The beef activities are a subset of all cattle

activities. The latter include additionally dairy and

breeding animals. Other animal activities include

the pig and poultry sectors as well as sheep

and goats. For all farm types, the beef activities

show stronger stocking density increases than

the aggregated cattle activities. This difference

may be due to the stronger increase in the price

of meat than, for example, for milk products, as

shown in Table 34. The increases in the numbers

of other animals show even a stronger effect for

some farm types. The category “other animals” is

dominated by pig and poultry production, which

are more elastic to price changes than the cattle

sector.

Next, we present the the income effects of

the analysed sub-scenarios. Table 37 shows the

decomposition of income effects into revenue,

cost and direct payment effects on a per-hectare

basis. The total revenues increase for all farm

types in all scenarios. In the ME-oil sub-scenario,

this increase is much smaller than it is in the ME-

GDP sub-scenario, which is related to the price

effects reported in Table 34. Regarding production

costs, the increase is higher in the ME-oil sub-

scenario because the increasing oil price directly

impacts production costs, whereas the increasing

Figure 22: EU-27 aggregate land use shares for selected farm types

Page 73: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

71

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

GDP affects agricultural costs indirectly via

intesification and stronger demand for inputs.

Regarding direct payments, we observe lower

values per hectare than at baseline. This result

is mainly due to the increase in total area while

direct payment ceilings remain fixed, leading to

lower average per-hectare direct payments.

The resulting income effects for all farm

types are positive in the cases of the ME-full

and ME-GDP sub-scenarios, whereas they are

negative for almost all types in ME-oil. This

result is understandable because the GDP effect

only impacts product prices and thus increases

revenues. The oil price increase also yields due to

rising prices, but costs increase simultaneously.

The latter effect dominates the revenue increase

wherefore total income decreases. Only for farm

types dealing with permanent crops does the oil

price increase not have a negative impact on the

Table 36: Production effects for EU-25 aggregated farm types

Type of Farming Baseline ME-full effect ME- oil price ME - GDP

(1000 t) % to Baseline % to Baseline % to Baseline

CerealsCereals, oilseed and protein crops 110.719 14,54 -1,33 15,67

General field cropping & mixed cropping 53.798 12,61 -1,11 13,63

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 4.184 14,07 -1,05 15,30

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 2.193 19,75 -1,17 21,74

OilseedsCereals, oilseed and protein crops 14.160 7,42 0,91 6,39

General field cropping & mixed cropping 4.193 7,28 0,87 6,44

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 158 10,83 0,17 10,62

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 99 12,25 0,22 12,04

Other arable crops

Cereals, oilseed and protein crops 19.173 14,13 0,02 12,54

General field cropping & mixed cropping 86.314 12,57 -0,22 11,69

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 1.330 10,77 0,31 10,34

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 2.077 4,74 -0,04 4,83

Vegetables and Permanent crops

Cereals, oilseed and protein crops 11.040 2,80 0,12 2,71

General field cropping & mixed cropping 12.336 2,59 0,15 2,45

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 4.209 5,48 0,58 4,92

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 8.979 4,95 0,30 4,68

Fodder activitiesCereals, oilseed and protein crops 37.745 -7,63 0,09 -8,14

General field cropping & mixed cropping 54.865 -3,28 -0,54 -3,08

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 315.249 4,96 -0,89 6,14

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 161.644 5,53 -0,75 6,78

All cattle activities

Cereals, oilseed and protein crops 214 4,17 0,48 3,55

General field cropping & mixed cropping 290 3,81 0,35 3,39

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 1.737 6,10 -0,35 6,35

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 324 5,32 -0,53 5,69

Beef meat activities

Cereals, oilseed and protein crops 327 2,58 0,77 1,59

General field cropping & mixed cropping 356 3,54 0,58 2,80

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 3.429 4,53 -0,72 5,11

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 722 2,23 -1,18 3,10

Other animalsCereals, oilseed and protein crops 5.346 13,51 0,01 13,47

General field cropping & mixed cropping 15.491 14,80 0,41 14,36

Cattle-Dairying rearing and fattening 2.246 12,44 -0,19 12,56

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 5.249 8,97 -0,20 9,06

Page 74: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

72

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

total income. This difference might be due to

the fact that permanent crops are more labour

intensive than capital intensive. As a result,

production costs are less reactive to oil price

changes.

Conclusions

In this scenario, we have simulated the

macroeconomic environment scenario by

considering two shocks:

(1) ME-oil: increase in the baseline crude oil

price by 50%, impacting agricultural input

costs and

(2) ME-GDP: increase in the national GDPs by

16% compared to the baseline, inducing

an increase in the demand for agricultural

commodities.

Furthermore, the combined effect of both

hypotheses was simulated. Generally, it is observed

that the considered shocks lead to increasing

commodity prices and thus increasing revenues

for farmers. An increase in the annual world

GDP growth rate by 1% (or a 16% cumulative

increase over the period of 2005-2020) relative

to the baseline causes stronger price effects (up to

30%) than the 50% increase in oil price does (up

to only 7%). This difference exists because the oil

price effect on agricultural commodity prices is

only indirect. It directly impacts production costs,

which lead indirectly to increasing prices. As a

result, in the ME-oil scenario, farmers are affected

by two opposing market effects: an increase in

production costs and a decrease in revenues.

In most cases, increasing costs dominate such

that the farm’s income declines. This result

is, of course, driven by assumptions on price

transmission elasticities. But the observations that

price increases for agricultural commodities stay

far behind the oil price increase and that farmers’

Figure 23: Relative stocking density changes in the ME-full scenario

Page 75: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

73

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysis

income declines with increasing oil prices are not

likely to change if price transmission elasticities

are increased or decreased.

The effect of higher GDP on income across

farm types is generally positive due to the

increasing demand for agricultural products,

which generates an increase in the price of

agricultural commodities. The income increases

the range from approximately 10% for farms

growing permanent crops up to about 70% for

farms producing cattle for milk and meat. Even

crop farms show income increases of about

50%.

Table 37: Income effects for EU-25 aggregated farm types

Type of Farming BaselineFull

effectoil price GDP Baseline

Full effect

Oil price GDP

€/ha% to

Baseline% to

Baseline% to

Baseline€/ha

% to Baseline

% to Baseline

% to Baseline

Reve

nues

Cereals, oilseed and protein crops 755 29 2,5 26

Prem

ium

s

305 -2 0,4 -2

General field cropping & mixed cropping 747 28 2,6 26 342 -1 0,5 -2

Horticulture 772 30 2,2 27 955 5 0,9 4

Vineyards 692 26 2,3 24 276 -2 0,3 -2

Fruit and citrus fruit 386 55 1,4 54 1043 3 0,4 3

Olives 520 27 1,6 25 546 -2 0,3 -2

Permanent crops combined 526 23 2,0 21 622 -1 0,3 -1

Dairying 673 30 3,1 27 385 -1 0,4 -1

Cattle- dairying rearing and fattening 574 30 2,9 27 307 -2 0,3 -2

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 541 31 2,8 28 326 -5 0,4 -6

Granivores 581 33 2,0 31 329 -2 0,2 -2

Mixed livestock 421 33 2,2 31 272 -1 0,5 -1

Mixed crops-livestock 666 31 2,5 28 318 -1 0,3 -1

<16 ESU 449 32 2,0 30 290 -2 0,5 -2

>16 - <100 ESU 719 28 2,7 25 327 -2 0,4 -2

>100 ESU 869 30 2,7 27 332 -1 0,4 -1

Tota

l Cos

t

Cereals, oilseed and protein crops 733 17 13,3 3In

com

e327 26 -23,5 51

General field cropping & mixed cropping 738 17 13,3 4 351 22 -22,0 45

Horticulture 875 19 12,0 6 852 14 -9,3 24

Vineyards 707 16 13,3 3 261 24 -29,5 55

Fruit and citrus fruit 280 21 13,3 7 1150 16 -2,4 19

Olives 350 24 14,1 8 716 6 -5,5 12

Permanent crops combined 441 20 14,2 5 707 4 -7,1 12

Dairying 854 18 13,3 4 204 23 -44,7 69

Cattle- dairying rearing and fattening 721 18 13,3 4 161 26 -48,4 76

Sheep, goats and other grazing livestock 555 19 13,0 5 312 16 -17,9 35

Granivores 714 20 12,3 7 196 21 -38,5 63

Mixed livestock 500 19 12,8 5 193 22 -27,5 51

Mixed crops-livestock 734 18 13,1 4 249 28 -31,3 60

<16 ESU 453 19 13,1 5 287 18 -17,0 36

>16 - <100 ESU 750 17 13,3 4 295 23 -26,9 51

>100 ESU 899 18 13,2 4 302 32 -31,2 65

Page 76: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

74

III. S

cena

rio A

naly

sis

Because the GDP effect on farmers’

income is so strong, the combined effect in the

ME-full scenario is still positive and averages

approximately 20% across farm types.

In all scenarios, farmers react to the new

macro environment with adjustments of their

production programmes. Thus, the effect of

the ME-oil sub-scenario is small, whereas the

ME-GDP sub-scenario leads to an increase in

arable land and intensification of crop and

animal production activities. Furthermore,

a tendency to substitute grassland for arable

land can be observed for farms that do

not specialise in cattle or sheep and goat

production.

Page 77: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

75

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisIV. General Conclusions

The main aim of using the CAPRI farm type

model in this study was to improve policy impact

assessments by considering farm structural

characteristics, such as farm size, crop mix,

stocking density and yields. Consideration of

such characteristics considerably reduces the

aggregation bias and thus improves the reliability

of regional results. This farm modelling approach

also allows the analysis of scenario effects at a

more disaggregated level according to farm

specialisation and farm size. The simulation

analyses at the farm level are particularly

important for the direct payment scenario due to

the farm-specific implementation of decoupled

payments in the CAP.

However, the results presented in this report

must be analysed in the context of the modelling

assumptions used within the CAPRI-FT. The use

of stylised template models that are structurally

identical and express differences between

farm types and regions solely by differences

in parameters might fall short of capturing the

full diversity of farming systems in Europe. In

particular, this is the case for the evaluation of

policy measures that impact farm management

decisions, such as manure handling, feeding

practices and farm demand behaviour, but

this concern is less important for the flat-rate

scenarios.

The relatively simple representation of

agricultural technology in the CAPRI model

compared to approaches that are parameterised

based on biophysical models may understate the

farms’ response to natural and local constraints.

However, the current structure of the approach

provides a good balance between increased

details about the represented farm types and the

robustness of the model results.

The CAPRI farm-type layer provides a

complementary approach to alternative farm-type

approaches. Its strength rests, first, in the fact that

harmonised data sources and assumptions are

applied across Europe; second, the farm layer is

transparently linked with a complex agricultural

trade model so that the full range of CAP measures

and their interactions can be analysed at the farm

level; and third, its maintenance and application

are cheaper compared to alternative approaches

should full coverage of the EU be desired.

Page 78: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge
Page 79: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

77

Farm

leve

l pol

icy

scen

ario

ana

lysisReferences

Armington P (1969) A Theory of Demand for Products Differentiated by Place of Production, IMF Staff

Papers 16, 159-76.

Baranger E, Clodic M, Galko E, Jayet P & Zakharov P (2008) Improvement of the AROPAj model covering

a large range of agricultural activities at wide (UE) and high resolution (mapping of farm types) scales,

paper presented at the 107th EAAE Seminar “Modeling of Agricultural and Rural Development

Policies”. Sevilla (Spain), January 29th -February 1st, 2008.

Britz W, Witzke P (2008) CAPRI model documentation 2008: Version 1 http://www.capri-model.org/docs/

capri_documentation.pdf

European Parliament, (2010) The single payment scheme after 2013: New Approache-New Targets;

Directorate General For Internal Policies, Policy Department, Structural and cohesion policies,

Agriculture and rural development, pp. 133

Gocht A (2010a): Methods in Economic Farm Modelling. Dissertation, University of Bonn.

Gocht A (2010b): Update of a quantitative tool for farm systems level analysis of agricultural policies (EU

FARMS). In: Dominguez, I. P., Cristoiu, A. (eds.). JRC-Scientific and Technical Reports (EUR24321EN).

IPTS Seville, 92 pp.

Gocht A and Britz W (2011) EU-wide farm types supply in CAPRI - How to consistently disaggregate

sector models into farm type models, Journal of Policy Modelling, (33) 146-167.

Jansson T (2007) Econometric specification of constrained optimization models; PhD thesis, University

Bonn.

Jansson T (2006) Impact analysis of different negotiation outcomes in WTO. Technical Paper, July 2006.

University Bonn.

Jansson T and Heckelei T (2011) Estimating a primal model of regional crop supply in the European Union.

In: Journal of Agricultural Economics (forthcoming in vol. 62 issue 1)

Junker F, Britz W, Heckelei T, Perez I, & Wieck C. (2005) How sustainable is the latest CAP Reform under

the possible Trade Liberalisation Outcomes of the Doha Round?, Paper presented at the IATRC

summer meeting 2005, Sevilla, June 16/17 2005: “Pressures for Agricultural Reform: WTO Panels and

the Doha Round Negotiations”

Jayet P-A, Baranger E, Clodic M, Galko E, Zakharov P (2008) Improvement of the AROPAj model covering

a large range of agricultural activities at wide (EU) and high resolution (mapping of farm types) scales,

proceedings of the 107th EAAE Seminar 29 January - 1 February 2008, Seville (Spain)

Page 80: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

78

Ref

eren

ces

Jones P J, Rehman T, Harvey D R, Tranter R B, Marsh J S, Bunce R G H & Howard D. C (1995) Developing

LUAM (Land Use Allocation Model) and modelling CAP reforms. CAS Paper 32. The University of

Reading, Centre for Agricultural Strategy.

Heckelei T, Mittelhammer R, Britz W (2005) A Bayesian Alternative to Generalized Cross Entropy Solutions

for Underdetermined Models, Selected paper presented at the 89th EAAE Symposium Modelling

agricultural policies: state of the art and new challenges, Parma, Italy, February 3-5, 2005

Howitt RE (1995) Positive mathematical programming, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 77(2):

329-342

Offermann F, Kleinhanß W, Hüttel S & Küpker B (2005) Assessing the 2003 CAP reform impacts on German

Agriculture using the farm group model FARMIS. In A. Filippo (Hrsg.), Modelling agricultural policies:

state of the art and new challenges: proceedings of the 89th European Seminar of the European

Association of Agricultural Economists (EAAE) (546-64). Parma: Monte Universita Parma Editore.

Pelikan J, Isermeyer F, Offermann F, Sanders J, Zimmer Y (2010) Auswirkungen einer Handelsliberalisierung

auf die deutsche und europäische Landwirtschaft. Braunschweig: vTI, IV, pp 91

World Trade Organization (WTO) (2008). Revised draft modalities for agriculture, December 2008 URL:

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/agric_e/agchairtxt _dec08_a_e.pdf

World Trade Organization (2009). Tariff negotiations in agriculture. Reduction methods. World Trade

Organization, background fact sheet (acc. 15 September, 2009 http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/

agric_e/agnegs_swissformula_e.htm

Page 81: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

79

Abstract

This study presents a quantitative policy impact analysis of alternative policy and macroeconomic assumptions in the agricultural farming sector. Three scenarios are considered: direct payment scenario, macroeconomic environment scenario and WTO scenario. We apply the CAPRI-Farm model, an extension of CAPRI which disaggregates the standard Nuts2 regional resolution of the supply models in CAPRI further to farm type models, capturing farm heterogeneity in terms of farm specialization and farm size across all EU regions and MS. The advantage of the CAPRI-Farm model compared to other similar models is that it represents comprehensively all major farm types in the EU and it links farm level behaviour with output and input market price responses.

The direct payment scenario assumes equalisation of decoupled payments – a regional flat-rate scheme – at the Nuts1, MS and EU levels. According to simulation results, the value of re-distributed payments vary strongly between the three flat-rate systems. The value of payments reallocated between farms in the EU increases from 9% (3.7 billion €) of the total CAP budget in the Nuts1 scenario to 19% (8.2 billion €) in the EU flat-rate scenario. Particularly negatively affected are large- and medium-sized farms and dairies, mixed crops and livestock, general field and mixed cropping, olives, cereals and oilseeds and permanent crops. Small farms tend to be less affected. However, sheep, goats and grazing, the residual farm category and mixed livestock farms realise higher premiums and incomes. The study shows relatively minor allocative market responses and thus small price effects for all three scenarios.

The WTO scenario aims to quantify the impact of trade liberalization on farming sector. More precisely, the scenario considers the impact of the proposal made by the chair of the WTO’s agriculture negotiations, Ambassador Crawford Falconer. The simulation results show that tariff reduction increases consumer welfare in the EU by 8.5 billion €, whereas agricultural income decreases by 6.8 billion € (-3%), mainly driven by losses realised in the animal sector. The analyses show sizable impacts on farm income for different farm types. Generally, farm types specialised in livestock production lose the most. The largest negative income effects were observed for cattle, dairying, rearing and fattening, dairy, mixed crops and livestock; and sheep and goat farms.

The macroeconomic environment scenario simulates the farm-level effects of a hypothetical economic recovery scenario that may lead to higher GDP growth and higher oil prices. Two shocks are assumed: an increase in the crude oil price by 50% and an annual world GDP growth rate increase by 1% relative to the baseline level. The results indicate that a higher GDP growth causes stronger price and market effects than does the increase in the oil price. With the oil price shock, farmers are affected by two opposing effects: an increase in production costs and an increase in revenues. In most cases, increasing costs dominate such that the overall farm income declines. The effect of higher GDP on income across farm types is generally positive due to the rising demand for agricultural products, which generates an increase in the prices of agricultural commodities. Farmers react to the new macro environment with adjustments of their production leading to an increase in arable land and intensification of crop and animal production activities. Further, a tendency to substitute grassland for arable land can be observed.

European Commission

EUR 24787 EN — Joint Research Centre — Institute for Prospective Technological Studies

Title: Farm level policy scenario analysis.

Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer

Editors: Sergio Gomez y Paloma and Pavel Ciaian

Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union2011

EUR — Scientific and Technical Research series — ISSN 1831-9424ISBN 978-92-79-19920-2 doi:10.2791/57250

Page 82: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

The mission of the Joint Research Centre is to provide customer-driven scientific and technical support for

the conception, development, implementation and monitoring of European Union policies. As a service

of the European Commission, the Joint Research Centre functions as a reference centre of science and

technology for the Union. Close to the policy-making process, it serves the common interest of the Member

States, while being independent of special interests, whether private or national.

How to obtain EU publications

Our priced publications are available from EU Bookshop (http://bookshop.europa.eu), where you can place

an order with the sales agent of your choice.

The Publications Office has a worldwide network of sales agents. You can obtain their contact details by

sending a fax to (352) 29 29-42758.

80

Page 83: Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer …publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/bitstream/JRC... · 2012-04-17 · The project team would like to acknowledge

Far

m le

vel p

olic

y sc

enar

io a

naly

sis

LF-N

A-24787-E

N-N

ISBN 978-92-79-19920-2

Farm level policy scenario analysis

EUR 24787 EN - 2011

9 789279 199202

Authors: Alexander Gocht, Wolfgang Britz and Marcel Adenäuer

Editors: Pavel Ciaian and Sergio Gomez y Paloma