Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

67
Submitted to Management Science manuscript Accepted at Management Science Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope He Huang School of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400030, China, [email protected] Zhipeng Li School of Economics and Management, Nanchang University, Nanchang 330031, China, [email protected] De Liu Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota Twin Cities, Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA, [email protected] Hongyan Xu School of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400030, China, [email protected] Motivated by challenges facing IT procurement, this paper studies a hybrid procurement model where a reverse auction of a fixed-price IT outsourcing contract may be followed by renegotiation to extend the contract’s scope. In this model, the buyer balances the need to incentivize non-contractible vendor investment and the need to curb the winning vendor’s information rent, by choosing the initial project scope and her investment in the quality of the project. We find that a buyer may benefit from inducing ex-post renegotiation to motivate vendor investment, especially when the winning vendor has high bargaining power and the quality uncertainty is low. Broadening the initial scope reduces information rent but leaves little room for ex-post renegotiation and hence discourages vendor investment, whereas increasing the buyer’s investment has opposite effects. Interestingly, the two measures can be strategic substitutes or complements depending on the likelihood of the renegotiation and the two parties’ bargaining powers. The buyer may strategically set low initial project scope and high investment to incentivize renegotiation and vendor investment, which may explain why many IT outsourcing projects start small and allow expansions. Our findings also generate several testable predictions for IT outsourcing. Key words : IT outsourcing; renegotiation; specific investments; reverse auctions; incomplete contracts 1. Introduction Organizations often use external providers for a wide range of IT services such as application and software development, technical support, infrastructure, system migration (e.g., to cloud comput- ing), and process automation. Surveys report that 31% of IT services were outsourced in 2016 1

Transcript of Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Page 1: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Submitted to Management Sciencemanuscript Accepted at Management Science

Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

He HuangSchool of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400030, China, [email protected]

Zhipeng LiSchool of Economics and Management, Nanchang University, Nanchang 330031, China, [email protected]

De LiuCarlson School of Management, University of Minnesota Twin Cities, Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA, [email protected]

Hongyan XuSchool of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, Chongqing 400030, China, [email protected]

Motivated by challenges facing IT procurement, this paper studies a hybrid procurement model where a

reverse auction of a fixed-price IT outsourcing contract may be followed by renegotiation to extend the

contract’s scope. In this model, the buyer balances the need to incentivize non-contractible vendor investment

and the need to curb the winning vendor’s information rent, by choosing the initial project scope and her

investment in the quality of the project. We find that a buyer may benefit from inducing ex-post renegotiation

to motivate vendor investment, especially when the winning vendor has high bargaining power and the

quality uncertainty is low. Broadening the initial scope reduces information rent but leaves little room for

ex-post renegotiation and hence discourages vendor investment, whereas increasing the buyer’s investment

has opposite effects. Interestingly, the two measures can be strategic substitutes or complements depending

on the likelihood of the renegotiation and the two parties’ bargaining powers. The buyer may strategically

set low initial project scope and high investment to incentivize renegotiation and vendor investment, which

may explain why many IT outsourcing projects start small and allow expansions. Our findings also generate

several testable predictions for IT outsourcing.

Key words : IT outsourcing; renegotiation; specific investments; reverse auctions; incomplete contracts

1. Introduction

Organizations often use external providers for a wide range of IT services such as application and

software development, technical support, infrastructure, system migration (e.g., to cloud comput-

ing), and process automation. Surveys report that 31% of IT services were outsourced in 2016

1

Page 2: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope2 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

(Deloitte 2016). The global IT outsourcing market is valued at USD 520.74 billion in 2019, with

an estimated compound annual growth rate of 7.7% from 2020 to 2027 (Grand View Research

2020). A cost-effective way of procuring IT services is through competitive tendering, also known

as reverse auctions, where the buyer invites multiple pre-qualified vendors (sellers) to bid for a

fixed-price service contract and awards the contract to the bidder with the lowest price.1 Compared

with negotiation-based outsourcing, reverse auctions can result in significant cost savings, improved

speed, access to a larger pool of vendors, and increased transparency (e.g., Reece 2004, Wilson

2016; Mishra and Bureau 2012). Reverse auctions are used in almost all Fortune 1000 companies

(Wyld 2011), and are especially popular in the public sector (e.g., Bajari et al. 2008, Wyld 2011)

and among young procurement professionals (Bowman 2019).

Despite the aforementioned strengths, reverse auctions may be inadequate for dealing with a

few challenges in IT outsourcing. The first challenge is quality uncertainties associated with IT

outsourcing, which may result from unexpected technical difficulties, changing demand and expec-

tations, and changing regulatory requirements such as new data privacy laws (Susarla 2012, Bhat-

tacharya et al. 2014). With such uncertainties, it is nearly impossible to specify all contingencies

for the IT outsourcing contract. Consequently, IT outsourcing contracts are often incomplete. Fur-

thermore, buyers may lack knowledge about vendor expertise at the beginning. This information

asymmetry problem could result in suboptimal contracts. With incomplete and suboptimal con-

tracts, organizations often find it necessary to renegotiate the terms of the contract (e.g., changing

requirements, adding/removing requirements, and even terminating the contract) ex post. For

instance, Korea Exchange and IBM extended the scope of a system maintenance service contract

after IBM’s excellent service delivery (IBM 2009). In a survey of 200 executives of midsize and

1 These are sometimes called “auction-determined” reverse auctions. Some reverse auctions are “buyer determined”,

in the sense that after collecting the bids, the buyer makes the award decision based on price and other factors (e.g.,

vendor reputation and prior collaboration) (Engelbrecht-Wiggans et al. 2007, Brosig-Koch and Heinrich 2014, Fugger

et al. 2015). We focus on the auction-determined format in this paper and refer readers to Wyld (2011) for more

discussion on the “buyer-determined” format.

Page 3: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 3

large companies, Gartner (2005) reports that over 55% of existing outsourcing contracts have been

renegotiated. Moreover, there are reports of IT outsourcing projects starting small and gradually

extending into full operational systems (Hertzum et al. 2012).

Another challenge lies in the “hold up” problems in IT outsourcing – that is, a vendor can make

a non-contractible investment that benefits the buyer, but once such an investment is made, the

buyer can hold up the value of the vendor investment. Specifically, IT outsourcing usually requires

the vendor to invest in quality improvements (e.g., technology R&D and security enhancements),

which are often non-contractible because they are nonverifiable by a third party (Snir and Hitt 2004,

Bhattacharya et al. 2014). For example, General Services Administration “encourages” vendors

to incorporate upgrades and innovations when procuring its next-generation telecommunication

services (Miller 2017). Reverse auctions with a fixed-price contract provide strong incentives for

vendor investments in cost reduction (e.g., Bajari and Tadelis 2001), but not for non-contractible

quality improvements. Consequently, reverse auctions may be inadequate for ensuring the quality

of IT outsourcing.

The aforementioned challenges suggest the importance of combining reverse auctions and rene-

gotiations. Renegotiation following a reverse auction (henceforth, ex-post renegotiation) can com-

plement the reverse auction in two ways: first, the ex-post renegotiation lets the two parties adjust

the contract to leverage new information about the vendor and the project. Second, renegotiations

may be useful for motivating the vendor’s non-contractible investment in project quality, because,

with renegotiations, vendors can capture a share of the surplus generated by their investment.

Reverse auctions with renegotiation make the most sense in a two-phased IT outsourcing project,

where the first phase is a reverse auction and the second phase is a renegotiation that expands the

scope of the project. Such two-phased implementations seem popular: a survey of large Australian

and UK organizations shows that 81 percent and 87 percent, respectively, of respondents award

pilot contracts for information system implementation before full-scale implementation (Hertzum

et al. 2012).

Page 4: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope4 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

While renegotiation frequently occurs after IT outsourcing auctions (e.g., Snir and Hitt 2004,

Deloitte 2013, Kujala et al. 2015), the literature is absent on the joint use of reverse auction and

ex-post negotiation. Many interesting issues arise in such a context, including:

� How would vendors behave in reverse auctions in anticipation of likely ex-post renegotiation?

� Can reverse auctions with renegotiation alleviate the information asymmetry and hold-up prob-

lems in IT outsourcing?

� When and how should buyers induce (or suppress) ex-post renegotiation after an IT outsourcing

auction?

This research addresses the aforementioned questions by examining a two-phased IT outsourcing

project: in the first phase, a buyer awards a fixed-price IT outsourcing contract to a winning bidder

via a reverse auction; the winner makes a non-contractible investment in quality enhancements

(henceforth vendor investment) and fulfills the contract; in the second phase, after observing the

first-phase quality outcomes, the two parties can renegotiate the contract to extend the project’s

scope.2 We capture three important features of IT outsourcing in our model: the two parties can

learn new information about the project implementation quality after the initial phase; the buyer

does not know vendors’ true expertise ex-ante (“information asymmetry”); the vendor investment

is non-contractible (the hold-up problem). We use this model to analyze vendors’ bidding and

investment decisions, and the buyer’s decisions.

We focus on two kinds of buyer decisions. First, the buyer can choose the scope of the initial con-

tract for auctioning (i.e., initial scope). Second, the buyer can choose her upfront investment (e.g.,

developing detailed project requirements and securing more financial and managerial resources for

the project) that affects vendors’ productivity and thus their bidding and investment behaviors in

IT outsourcing.

Overall, we find that a vendor may face three renegotiation cases: never-renegotiate, always-

renegotiate, or opportunistically-renegotiate (that is, renegotiate only when the implementation

2 Project scope refers to the work that needs to be accomplished to deliver a product, service, or result with the

specified features and functions (Rose 2013).

Page 5: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 5

quality in the first phase is favorable). The winning vendor has incentives to make an upfront quality

investment only when a renegotiation is possible, and the investment incentive and information rent

increase if renegotiation is more likely to happen. Broadening the initial scope undermines vendor

investment but also curtails vendor’s information rent, while increasing buyer investment has the

opposite effects. Interestingly, the two measures may be either strategic substitutes or complements

for the buyer, depending on the renegotiation scenarios and the vendor’s bargaining power in the

renegotiation. The buyer strategically chooses the initial project scope and her upfront investment

to balance the gains from the initial contract (for which the two measures are complements) and the

renegotiation one (for which the two measures are substitutes). The buyer optimally induces more

renegotiation as the quality uncertainty decreases and the vendor’s bargaining power increases.

In the extended analyses, we show that the main results hold qualitatively when we allow for an

optimal reserve price, costly learning of project quality, and buyer investments in cost reduction.

Our research contributes to the IT outsourcing and procurement auction literature in two ways.

First, we advance the understanding of the buyer and vendors’ strategic considerations in real-

world procurement auctions that are often renegotiated. Our hybrid procurement model, motivated

by observations from IT outsourcing, captures both information asymmetry and moral hazard

problems. In contrast, prior literature on reverse auctions with renegotiation has only dealt with

information asymmetry issues. In our hybrid procurement model, renegotiation is not a passive

coping mechanism but a strategic tool, used in conjunction with the reverse auction, for dealing

with moral hazard problems. Second, we provide new insights on how organizations should use the

initial project scope and buyer upfront investment as strategic levers in a hybrid IT outsourcing

environment. The extant literature has not provided insights on such issues. For example, it is not

yet clear why some organizations start with a small pilot project before scaling it up (e.g., Fenton

2016), while others start big (e.g., ESSU 2017). While prior research has examined the buyer’s

investment decision (e.g., Roels et al. 2010, Lee et al. 2013), it is unclear what roles it plays in the

hybrid procurement mechanism or how it should be coordinated with the initial scope.

Page 6: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope6 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Though the procurement literature has long recognized the prevalence of ex-post renegotiation in

contexts such as the construction industry, it has characterized renegotiation as a passive and costly

adaptation mechanism (Gil and Oudot 2009, Miller 2014, Bajari et al. 2014, Jung 2016) and focused

on strategies of avoiding such renegotiation (e.g., Herweg and Schmidt 2020). Only a handful of

papers have recognized the strategic value of ex-post renegotiation. Herweg and Schwarz (2018)

suggest that renegotiation and resulting cost overruns in the construction industry can be optimal

for the buyer. Agrawal and Oraiopoulos (2020) find that renegotiation can be a powerful way of

aligning the interests of the firms, and therefore, maximizing the value from a co-development

initiative. Still, there is very limited research on how to set up the reverse auction in anticipation of

ex-post renegotiation, especially in a complex IT outsourcing environment with both information

asymmetry and moral hazard problems.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: we next review the related literature, followed

by the research model. We then analyze the model and its extensions. The last section concludes

the paper.

2. Relation to Existing Literature

There is a large body of research on IT outsourcing (ITO). Several comprehensive reviews (e.g.,

Lacity et al. 2009, Liang et al. 2016) summarize this body of research. Most ITO studies are empir-

ical work with very different foci from this paper. They, however, have laid a foundation for this

research. For example, existing research has shown that contracting for IT services is inevitably

incomplete (e.g., Susarla et al. 2010), because it typically involves unforeseen contingencies (e.g.,

Aubert et al. 2004), non-contractible investments and behaviors (e.g., Susarla 2012), and immea-

surable performance (e.g., Fitoussi and Gurbaxani 2012). These studies inform our choice of model

elements. In the following, we focus on existing work on procurement design for ITO and other

related contexts, with an emphasis on analytical modeling papers.

This research is generally related to the literature on vendor selection problems in ITO. Nam

et al. (1995) and Chaudhury et al. (1995) study the winner-determination problem in ITO auctions

Page 7: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 7

when bidders have asymmetric cost structures. Tunca and Zenios (2006) study the choice between

auctions and relational contracts when the suppliers’ quality is nonverifiable. Cao and Wang (2007)

study a two-stage vendor selection model, where the buyer sponsors multiple vendors in the first

stage and picks the best for the second stage of the project. Their focus is on how to allocate the

buyer’s budget between the first and second stages. Unlike this research, the above papers do not

study how to motivate non-contractible vendor investments after vendor selection.

Our paper is also related to the economics literature on the hold-up problem – the risk of the

buyer holding up the vendor’s non-contractible investment can undermine the vendor’s incentives

to invest (see Che and Sakovics 2008 for a review). Tirole (1986) shows that a vendor generally

underinvests in a two-period procurement model where the vendor invests in the first period and

the vendor and the buyer acquire private information about their cost and valuation respectively,

before entering a renegotiation. This stream is devoted to alleviating the hold-up problem using

strategies such as vertical integration (Williamson 1979), shifting property rights (Grossman and

Hart 1986), and allocating control rights (Aghion and Bolton 1992). Our model is most similar

to the property-right approach in that the buyer can use her decisions to alter the renegotiation

surplus claimed by the winning vendor.

Bhattacharya et al. (2014) also study the hold-up problem in IT outsourcing. They show that

gain-share contracts are superior to commonly observed cost-plus contracts. Benaroch et al. (2010)

propose a real-option approach for determining when a buyer should include flexible contract terms

for ex-post renegotiation. Most recently, Agrawal and Oraiopoulos (2020) study a hold-up problem

in co-development initiatives where two parties can both make a non-contractible effort to affect

future outcomes and can renegotiate after observing the market potential. They adopt a decision-

right approach to alleviate the hold-up problem: one party may choose a menu of contracts ex-ante

whereas the other may choose a specific contract ex-post. Different from the above hold-up papers,

we study the hold-up problem jointly with a vendor selection problem. As a result, there is a

trade-off between alleviating the hold-up problem and extracting information rent. Our version of

Page 8: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope8 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

the hold-up problem is most similar to Agrawal and Oraiopoulos (2020)’s, though their setting (of

product co-development) and mitigation strategy are quite different from ours.

The issues of contract incompleteness and associated renegotiation are also investigated in other

industries, such as building construction (e.g., Bajari and Tadelis 2001, Bajari et al. 2008) and

weapon systems (e.g., Riordan and Sappington 1989, Tirole 1986). A few studies compare the

effectiveness of different contract/procurement formats when ex-post renegotiations are required.

Bajari and Tadelis (2001) model ex-post renegotiations in the construction industry as a result

of an inadequate initial design. They show that cost-plus contracts, which permit two parties to

reach efficient ex-post designs but provide little incentives for cost-reduction efforts, are preferred

to fixed-price contracts when a project is more complex. Herweg and Schmidt (2017) compare

price-only auctions and negotiations in a context where potential suppliers hold private information

about possible design improvements. They show that negotiations are superior to auctions if design

improvements are important, renegotiation is very costly, and the buyer’s bargaining position is

strong. A host of empirical studies examine the implications of auctioning incomplete contracts

and associated renegotiation: Bajari et al. (2008) find that reverse auctions perform poorly when

the project is complex and the initial contract is incomplete, but may still outperform negotia-

tions if there are many potential bidders. Miller (2014) finds that, relative to in-house projects,

renegotiation significantly increases costs, distorts bidding strategies, and causes welfare losses.

Bajari et al. (2014) show that bidders respond strategically to contractual incompleteness and

incorporate adaptation costs into their bids. Our research departs from the aforementioned studies

of renegotiation in that we study a more proactive approach of managing renegotiation: antici-

pating the likely renegotiation, the buyer can choose a smaller-scope contract for auctioning and

renegotiate additional scope as needed. Moreover, non-contractible vendor investments in quality

improvements play a key role in our setting but are absent from the aforementioned studies. Inter-

estingly, while a majority of empirical papers in the construction context paint a negative role of

ex-post renegotiation, Susarla (2012) demonstrates a positive role of renegotiation in ITO contexts:

Page 9: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 9

when the procurement contract includes delineations of decision rights for ex-post contingencies,

renegotiation can lead to Pareto improvements.

Our study belongs to a small literature that examines design issues in auction-renegotiation

hybrid models. Herweg and Schwarz (2018) study whether a buyer should announce a standard

or a fancier design in the initial auction for a construction project in anticipation of possible

renegotiation to the ex-post efficient design. They show that the buyer may prefer a simpler design

plus renegotiation for its ability to compress vendors’ information rent. Unlike their paper, we

consider both rent-extraction and hold-up problems in our setting. Herweg and Schmidt (2020)

focus on excessive renegotiation caused by vendors concealing their private information about

initial design flaws. They propose a direct mechanism based on third-party arbitration that induces

vendors to report design flaws ahead of the reverse auction. They focus on eliminating inefficient

renegotiations without considering hold-up problems. Moreover, they study an efficient design

whereas we study a design that maximizes the buyer’s expected surplus.

A few other studies also examine auction-renegotiation procurement models, but use auction

and/or renegotiation differently. Wang (2000) studies a procurement auction model with renegoti-

ation where the buyer can, immediately after the auction, incur an expense to renegotiate with the

winner to learn about his true cost. Huh and Park (2010) study a model where the buyer audits

the winner’s cost immediately after the auction and negotiates with the winner to determine a

final price. In both papers, negotiation occurs immediately after the auction as part of the cost

discovery, whereas renegotiation in our paper occurs after the fulfillment of the initial contract

and may lead to a scope expansion. Riordan and Sappington (1989) examine a two-stage defense

procurement model, where the buyer first uses an auction to choose a vendor to generate a design

and then uses a direct mechanism to select a vendor (which could be the designer) for production.

They focus on whether to invite additional vendors in the production stage.

Snir and Hitt (2004) propose a two-stage vendor selection mechanism for IT outsourcing that

tackles both vendor selection and hold-up problems. The buyer uses a screening contract to select

Page 10: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope10 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

a vendor in a pilot stage and award a full-implementation contract only if the pilot project exceeds

a minimum quality threshold. Their model differs from ours on the mechanisms used: we use

an auction instead of a screening contract in the first phase and renegotiation instead of a pre-

determined threshold in the second stage. Moreover, the two phases in their model are exogenous

whereas our first phase has an endogenous scope.

3. Model

A buyer would like to outsource an IT project to one of n (n≥2) pre-qualified vendors through

a reverse auction. Such an IT project can be application/software development, web develop-

ment/hosting, database development/management, and so on (Bradford 2019). As a convention,

we refer to the buyer as a “she” and a vendor as a “he.” The procurement proceeds in two phases.

Phase 1 is the auction phase where the buyer conducts a reverse auction to select a vendor for

carrying out the IT outsourcing project with a pre-announced initial scope s1. Then, the winner

of the auction implements the original scope s1. Phase 2 is the renegotiation phase, where the

two parties can renegotiate the initial contract to expand the project’s scope to s= s1 + s2. If the

renegotiation succeeds, the vendor will implement the additional scope s2.

The value of the project to the buyer is a function of both scope and quality of deliverables.

Specifically, denoting q1 and q2 as the quality of deliverables in phases 1 and 2 respectively, we

assume:

Project valuet = st× qt, t∈ {1,2} . (1)

The project’s scope st captures the number and substance of the required deliverables. For

example, an ERP implementation project with more modules and requirements per module has

a larger scope. The implementation quality qt captures the degree to which the deliverables meet

the buyer’s demand (Sundqvist et al. 2014). A higher-quality implementation generates more value

to the buyer for the same scope. For example, a higher-quality ERP implementation means that,

on average, the modules and functionalities are better built (e.g., more efficient, easier to use, and

producing higher-quality reports). We assume that the quality levels q1 and q2 are observable but

Page 11: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 11

non-verifiable. Similiar assumptions have been made in several prior studies (e.g., Tunca and Zenios

2006). The non-verifiability of project quality arises because quality standards are often subjective

and tacit.

We assume the quality of deliverables has both a stochastic component and a deterministic

component. Its deterministic component is a function of the two parties’ upfront investments in

quality. Specifically, we assume:

qt = q0 + γx+ θz+ εt, t∈ {1,2} (2)

where q0 (q0 > 0) is the baseline quality, x is the buyer’s upfront investment in quality with γ

being her investment coefficient, z is the vendor’s upfront investment in quality with θ being his

investment coefficient, and εt is the stochastic component. The additive format of joint investments

is commonly used in the literature (see, e.g., Xiao and Xu 2012, Li 2013, Agrawal and Oraiopoulos

2020).

In Equation (2), the baseline quality q0 reflects the default quality of this type of IT projects,

and is determined by the type of project and the current technology level. The buyer and the

vendor can make upfront investments (x and z, respectively) at the beginning of the project

to further improve its quality, and such investments can affect the entire project scope. Buyer

upfront investments x may include developing detailed project requirements, securing more finan-

cial and managerial resources for the project, and committing resources to manage changes. For

example, in its cloud-services procurement auction, the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA)

announced several investments it would make, such as the provision of telecommunications con-

nectivity, computing infrastructure, directory services, and migration support tools (FAA 2015).

Such investments can benefit the entire project by enabling high-quality deliverables. The ven-

dor’s upfront investments could include, for instance, acquiring and training talents with relevant

expertise, developing detailed implementation plans, and developing standards and interfaces for

Page 12: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope12 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

the buyer’s specific needs.3 Again, such vendor investments have a project-wide impact. For exam-

ple, application-development vendors can appoint the most skillful developers that will affect the

quality of all modules.

We assume the vendor investment z is observable but non-verifiable (thus non-contractible). It

is observable because the buyer can closely examine the vendor’s deliverables. It is non-verifiable

because there is no verifiable measure of quality. The buyer investment x is publically announced

and observable by vendors.

We interpret coefficients γ and θ as the buyer’s and the vendor’s expertise, respectively. Such

expertise can be developed from domain knowledge, technical know-how, and past experiences from

similar projects. Higher expertise allows a buyer/vendor to achieve a higher quality outcome with

the same amount of time/effort. We assume that the buyer’s expertise γ is public knowledge. In

contrast, a vendor’s expertise θ is his private information (or “type”). The vendors’ expertise {θi}ni=1

is independently and identically distributed on the support [θ, θ] (0 ≤ θ < θ), with a cumulative

distribution function F (·) and a probability density function f(·). The distribution is common

knowledge.

The stochastic component εt is a function of a project-specific latent state ε0 and some random

disturbances. The latent state ε0 reflects the unknown state of the world that affects the quality of

deliverables, such as the technological landscape, usage patterns, and end-user expectations. The

latent state ε0 is time-persistent but initially unknown to the buyer or the vendors.

The phase-1 and phase-2 quality states ε1 and ε2 take values from {εH , εL} (εH > εL) . Their values

are affected by environmental uncertainties such as uncertainties in the technological landscape,

3 In practice, the two parties can invest in implementation quality improvement as well as cost reduction. We focus

on quality-improvement investments for the following main reason. In the case of a fixed-price contract (which is the

setting we study), vendors have incentives to invest in cost reduction but not quality improvement. Our goal is to

investigate how the buyer can motivate the latter kind of investment using a combination of auction and renegotiation.

In some sense, we can assume that the vendor would make cost-reducing investments anyway thus we do not need to

explicitly model such investments.

Page 13: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 13

usage patterns, and end-user demands. To model the correlation between the two quality states,

we assume that both are manifestations of a latent quality state ε0, which also takes values from

{εH , εL}. With probability ρt ∈[

12,1]

(t ∈ {1,2}), the phase-t quality state εt is the same as the

latent quality state ε0, and with probability 1− ρt, it takes the opposite value. The latent quality

state ε0 is drawn randomly from {εH , εL} at the beginning of the project with probabilities λ and

1−λ, respectively, and a mean of zero. The buyer or vendors would not know the project’s latent

quality state ε0, but they can observe the phase-1 quality state to update their belief about the

latent quality state, which in turn affects their belief about phase-2 quality. We interpret ρt as

the informativeness of the phase-t quality about the latent quality state ε0: the higher ρt is, the

more informative is the phase-t project quality. We assume that ρt and the distribution of ε0 are

common knowledge.

For notational convenience, we denote

Pj ≡ Pr{ε1 = εj}, j ∈ {H,L}

Pj|i ≡ Pr{ε2 = εj|ε1 = εi}, i, j ∈ {H,L}

where Pj is the probability of ε1 taking the value εj, and Pj|i is the probability of ε2 taking the value

εj conditional on ε1 taking the value εi.4 It can be verified that ε1 and ε2 are positively correlated

in the sense that the phase-2 quality state is more likely to be high (low) if the phase-1 quality

state is high (low). We further denote

εt ≡ E [εt] , t∈ {1,2}

ε2|i ≡ E [ε2|ε1 = εi] , i∈ {1,H,L}

as the expected quality state of phase t and the conditional expected quality state of phase 2,

respectively.

4 By Bayesian rule, we have PH = λρ1 + (1 − λ)(1 − ρ1), PH|H = ρ1ρ2λ+(1−ρ1)(1−ρ2)(1−λ)ρ1λ+(1−ρ1)(1−λ)

, and PL|L =

ρ1ρ2(1−λ)+(1−ρ1)(1−ρ2)λρ1(1−λ)+(1−ρ1)λ

.

Page 14: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope14 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

The buyer chooses a vendor via a sealed-bid second-price reverse auction, where every participat-

ing vendor submits a price and the one with the lowest price wins and receives the next lowest price

as his payment (Milgrom and Weber 1982, Krishna 2009).5 The sealed-bid auction is commonly

used in IT project procurement, though, as we will show in the online appendix (see Lemma A1),

the revenue equivalence principle holds and our results are not sensitive to the specific auction

format used. We focus on a simple (i.e., no reserve price) reverse auction though we demonstrate

in the Extensions section that our main insights can still hold when there is an optimal reserve

price.

The timeline of the game is as follows (see Figure 1). In phase 1, the auction takes place. During

this phase, the buyer announces the initial scope s1 and makes her upfront investment x for a cost

of 12x2. Such a cost pattern is commonly used in literature (e.g., August et al. 2017, Bhattacharya

et al. 2014).6 After observing the initial scope s1 and the buyer’s upfront investment x, vendors

place their bids in the reverse auction. The auction results in a winning bidder and a winning price

p1.

After the auction, the winning bidder makes an upfront investment z (z ≥ 0) in quality improve-

ments for a cost of 12z2. Similar cost functions have been used in prior studies (e.g., August et al.

2017, Bhattacharya et al. 2014). The quadratic form captures the notion that improving project

quality is increasingly harder. We note that, although the cost of quality investments is the same for

5 We note that the price-only reverse auction can also be generalized to a “scoring auction” where price and non-price

elements (e.g. quality, time-to-delivery, provided that they are observable) can be factored into a score that is used

to determine the auction winner. Prior research shows that such scoring auctions can sometimes be mapped into a

price-only auction (Che 1993, Branco 1997). For simplicity, we only consider the price-only format in this paper.

6 Some of the buyer’s upfront investments, e.g., project planning and requirement specification, occur at the beginning

of the project. Others may occur during (e.g., process re-engineering) or after (e.g., training) the project, but these

investments need to be budgeted and pledged in advance. The exact timing of the buyer’s investment is not crucial

to our model results; what is important is that the buyer can make a credible commitment to her investment. For

simplicity, we simply say that the buyer makes her investment before the project begins.

Page 15: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 15

all vendors, the impact of such investments on quality is different for vendors of different expertise

(see Equation (2)).

The winning bidder then implements the initial scope s1 for a cost of cF (θ) + 12s2

1. The first

component cF (θ) is a one-time fixed cost and a decreasing function of the vendor’s expertise θ

(i.e., c′F (θ)< 0). The second component 12s2

1, the quadratic cost of the scope, captures the notion

that as the project gets larger, the marginal cost of scope is higher due to increased complexity

(Dogan et al. 2011). Overall, our assumption of the implementation cost suggests that vendors

incur the same variable cost for increasing a project’s scope, but different fixed costs for initiating

the project. For example, a higher-expertise vendor has a lower fixed cost because they have more

experience/expertise in designing a system architecture or a technical solution.

After the vendor implements initial scope s1, the buyer pays the vendor p1. By the end of this

phase, the buyer learns the winning vendor’s quality investment z, expertise θ, and the phase-1

quality q1.By our assumption, the quality investment z and the phase-1 quality q1 become observ-

able after the project phase 1 is delivered (though they remain non-verifiable). The buyer can infer

the vendor’s expertise θ from his bid since, as we will show in Lemma 3, the sealed-bid second-price

reverse auction is truth-telling.

At phase 2, the two parties may choose to renegotiate the project scope based on the expected

phase-2 quality. If the renegotiation succeeds, the two parties will determine an additional project

scope s2 and a payment p2 for implementing it. Because the total cost of scope is 12(s1 + s2)2,

the cost of implementing the additional scope is 12(s1 + s2)2− 1

2s2

1 (there is no fixed cost in phase

2). Under this cost function, the greater the initial scope s1, the higher the marginal cost of the

additional scope, reflecting the added complexity of coordinating with a larger phase-1 project.

We denote u1, u2, and u as the winning vendor’s phase-1, phase-2, and total expected surplus

respectively. Similarly, we denote v1, v2, and v as the buyer’s phase-1, phase-2, and total expected

surplus respectively. We adopt the generalized Nash bargaining solution (GNBS) for the renegoti-

Page 16: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope16 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

ation game.7 Specifically, a GNBS prescribes that the two parties choose (s2, p2) to maximize the

following Nash product (e.g., Binmore et al. 1986, Herweg and Schmidt 2020):

maxs2,p2

uα2 v1−α2 (3)

s.t. s2 ≥ 0, u2 ≥ 0, v2 ≥ 0.

The parameter α ∈ [0,1] captures the relative bargaining power of the winning vendor. One can

easily verify that in a GBNS, s2 is chosen to maximize the renegotiation surplus S (e.g., Agrawal

and Oraiopoulos 2020, Herweg and Schmidt 2020), defined as the sum of the two parties’ phase-2

surpluses, i.e.,

S = u2 + v2. (4)

Meanwhile, p2 is chosen to allocate the renegotiation surplus according to their bargaining powers

(i.e., u2 = αS and v2 = (1−α)S). Table 1 summarizes the notation used in our model.

Figure 1 Sequence of events.

Buyer announces

initial scope s1 and

makes investment x

Vendors bid

on prices

Buyer selects

winning vendor

(with price p1)

Buyer

pays p1

Buyer

pays p2

Renegotiation for

additional scope s2

and payment p2

Winner makes

investment z

Winner

implements s1

Winner implements s2

(with quality q2)

Quality q1

observed

Phase 1: Reverse auction Phase 2 (optional): Renegotiation

time

4. Analysis4.1. Renegotiation

Applying backward induction, we first analyze the renegotiation decision at phase 2 given the

realization of phase-1 quality q1. The winning vendor’s phase-2 expected surplus u2 is:

u2 = p2−1

2(s1 + s2)2 +

1

2s2

1 (5)

7 A renegotiation setting is commonly modeled as a Nash bargaining (e.g., Agrawal and Oraiopoulos 2020, Herweg and

Schwarz 2018, Herweg and Schmidt 2020). For example, Herweg and Schmidt (2015) employ the GNBS equilibrium

concept to characterize the renegotiation outcome, noting that “the GNBS is the only bargaining solution that is

Pareto efficient, invariant to equivalent utility representations and independent of irrelevant alternatives. Furthermore,

it reflects the relative bargaining power of the two parties.”

Page 17: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 17

Table 1 Summary of Notation

n number of vendors

st project scope in phase t∈ {1,2}qt realized quality in the phase t∈ {1,2}q0 baseline quality

εt stochastic component in the phase-t quality, t∈ {1,2}ε0 latent state, ε0 ∈ {εH , εH}λ probability of the high latent state ε0 = εH

σ standard deviation of ε0

ρt probability of εt = ε0 in phase t∈ {1,2}εt =E [εt], t∈ {1,2}, the expectation of εt

ε2|i =E [ε2|ε1 = εi], i∈ {1,H,L}, the expectation of ε2 conditional on ε1 = εi

Pj|i = Pr{ε2 = εj|ε1 = εi}, i, j ∈ {H,L}, the distribution of ε2 conditional on ε1 = εi

Pj = Pr{ε1 = εj}, j ∈ {H,L}, the distribution of ε1

x buyer’s upfront investment

γ buyer’s expertise (i.e., investment coefficient)

z winning vendor’s upfront investment

θ winning vendor’s expertise or “type” (i.e., investment coefficient), θi ∈ [θ, θ]

cF (θ) the winning vendor’s fixed cost

F (·), f(·) cumulative distribution function and probability density function of type θi

pt payment in phase t∈ {1,2}, where p1 is the winning price of the auction

v1,v2, and v the buyer’s phase-1, phase-2, and total expected surplus

u1,u2, and u the winning vendor’s phase-1, phase-2, and total expected surplus

S the joint surplus generated by renegotiation

α winning vendor’s bargaining power

The buyer’s phase-2 expected surplus v2 is

v2 = Eε2 [q2s2|ε1]− p2 =(q0 + γx+ θz+ ε2|1

)s2− p2 (6)

We define the ex-post optimal scope as the project scope that maximizes the expected renegoti-

ation surplus conditional on the phase-1 quality state ε1.

Lemma 1. At phase 2, the ex-post optimal scope is given by

s∗ = q0 + γx+ θz+ ε2|1 (7)

The two parties will renegotiate if and only if s∗ > s1. If the renegotiation occurs, we have:

s2 = s∗− s1 (8)

Page 18: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope18 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

p2 =1

2s2 [(1 +α)s2 + 2s1] (9)

S =1

2s2

2 (10)

Because the renegotiation decision may depend on the phase-1 quality state, we define three

possible renegotiation cases {N, O, A} that a winning vendor may face. Here, “N ” stands for the

never-renegotiate case where there will not be any renegotiation regardless of the phase-1 quality

state; “A” stands for the always-renegotiate case where there will always be renegotiation regardless

of the phase-1 quality state; finally, “O” stands for the opportunistically-renegotiate case where

there will be renegotiation only if the phase-1 quality state is high (i.e. ε1 = εH).

4.2. Vendor’s Problem

4.2.1. Winning Vendor’s Upfront Investment The winning vendor makes an upfront

investment after winning the auction but before the phase-1 quality is known. The vendor’s upfront

investment directly benefits the buyer, but not himself. With renegotiation, however, the vendor

can indirectly benefit from his upfront investment by capturing a share of the phase-2 renegotiation

surplus which increases with his upfront investment. Noting that the winning vendor’s phase-1

surplus is

u1 = p1− cF (θ)− 1

2s2

1−1

2z2, (11)

the winning vendor chooses upfront investment z to maximize his total expected surplus:

u(z;θ, p1)≡Eε1 [u1 +u2] = p1− cF (θ)− 1

2s2

1−1

2z2︸ ︷︷ ︸

(i)

+Eε1{α

2

[(q0 + γx− s1 + θz+ ε2|1)+

]2}︸ ︷︷ ︸(ii)

(12)

In Equation (12), the term (i) is the vendor’s phase-1 surplus, and the term (ii) is the expected

phase-2 surplus, which is computed as the vendor’s expected share of the renegotiation surplus

αS = αs222

(see Lemma 1).

Although the vendor incurs a convex investment cost of 12z2 in phase 1 (the term (i)), he also

enjoys a convex return from his investment z in phase 2 (the term (ii)), so his total expected

surplus may not be concave in z. The following assumption ensures that the winning vendor’s total

expected surplus is always concave in his investment z to rule out infinite vendor investment.

Page 19: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 19

Assumption 1. 1−αθ2> 0.

This assumption effectively sets an upper bound for the highest vendor expertise θ and this

upper bound is lower when the vendor has higher bargaining power α.

Lemma 2. The winning vendor’s optimal upfront investment is

z∗ (θ) =

0 (N)

αθPH(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H

)yO(θ) (O)

αθ (q0 + γx− s1 + ε2)yA(θ) (A)

(13)

where yO(θ) = (1−αθ2PH)−1

and yA(θ) = (1−αθ2)−1

(yO < yA) are interpreted as the vendor’s

investment effectiveness under cases O and A respectively, and conditions (N), (O), and (A) are

given by:

(N): q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈ (−∞,0)

(O): q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈[0,(ε2|H − ε2|L

)/yO(θ)

)(A): q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈

[(ε2|H − ε2|L

)/yO(θ),∞

).

Lemma 2 also implies that the winning vendor’s upfront investment depends on whether the

renegotiation is expected to happen. Recall that the vendor’s investment incentive comes solely

from his share of renegotiation surplus. Therefore, in the case of “never renegotiate” (condition

N ), the vendor will not invest in quality improvements (i.e., z∗ (θ) = 0). In contrast, in the case of

“opportunistically renegotiate” (condition O) or “always renegotiate” (condition A), the winning

vendor will make a positive investment.

Proposition 1. Under cases O and A, the winning vendor’s optimal upfront investment z∗(θ)

increases in the buyer’s upfront investment x and the vendor’s bargaining power α, and decreases

in the initial scope s1.

Proposition 1 shows how the buyer’s upfront investment x and initial scope s1 affect the vendor’s

investment z∗. Although both decisions work through the renegotiation surplus, their effects are

different. A higher buyer investment x is associated with a higher vendor investment because, as

Page 20: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope20 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

suggested by Lemma 1, a higher x increases the additional scope s2, which in turn increases the

renegotiation surplus and the vendor’s incentive to invest. In contrast, a higher initial scope s1

reduces the vendor’s investment because, for the same ex-post optimal scope, a higher initial scope

s1 means a smaller additional scope and renegotiation surplus, thus a smaller incentive for the

vendor to invest in quality improvements. When the vendor’s bargaining power α increases, he

receives a larger share of the renegotiation surplus, which motivates him to invest more. A higher

α also leads to increased efficiency because it makes the vendor more of a residual claimant.

Substituting z∗ into Equation (12), we obtain the winning vendor’s total expected surplus under

optimal investment, which is given by

u∗(θ, p1)≡ u(z∗;θ, p1)

= p1− cF (θ)− 1

2s2

1 +

0 (N )

12αPH

(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H

)2yO(θ) (O)

12α[(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2)

2yA(θ) +PHPL

(ε2|H − ε2|L

)2]

(A).

(14)

4.2.2. Vendors’ Bidding Equilibrium In the reverse auction, all pre-qualified vendors can

submit a bid anticipating their costs. A winning bidder will incur a fixed cost, and the cost of

implementing the initial scope, but will also gain a share of renegotiation surplus at phase 2, as

seen from Equation (14). We can rewrite (14) as u∗(θ, p1) = p1− c(θ), where

c(θ)≡ cF (θ) +1

2s2

1−

0 (N )

12αPH

(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H

)2yO(θ) (O)

12α[(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2)

2yA(θ) +PHPL

(ε2|H − ε2|L

)2]

(A)

(15)

Noting that c(θ) decreases in the vendor’s type θ and {c (θi)}ni=1 are also i.i.d, we may view the

reverse auction as a standard reverse auction among n risk-neutral bidders with {c (θi)}ni=1 as their

true costs. According to the auction theory (e.g., Krishna 2009), the revenue equivalence principle

holds in our model (see Lemma A1 in the online appendix EC.1). Thus, it is without loss of

Page 21: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 21

generality to restrict our attention to the second-price sealed-bid auction, in which vendor i bids

his true cost c(θi) in equilibrium.

Lemma 3. In the reverse auction, vendors bid their true costs {c (θi)}ni=1. The vendor with the

highest expertise θ(1) wins at price p1 = c(θ(2)), with a total surplus of

u∗(θ(1), c(θ(2))

)= c(θ(2))− c(θ(1)). (16)

We call the winning bidder’s surplus as his information rent. Equation (16) shows that the

winning bidder’s information rent is the difference between his true cost and the runner-up’s. In

general, different vendors may face different renegotiation scenarios upon winning; with a general

type distribution F (·), the buyer’s problem will become intractable. To make the problem tractable,

we additionally assume a discrete distribution of the vendor expertise over {θL, θH}: for all i ∈

{1, · · · , n}, θi = θL with probability β ∈ (0,1) and θi = θH with probability 1− β, where θL < θH .

Then, given the likely vendor-specific renegotiation scenarios N, O, and A as described in Lemma 2,

there could be four renegotiation scenarios N ,O,H, and A from the buyer’s perspective, where N

(O,A) denotes the never-renegotiate (opportunistically-renegotiate, always-renegotiate) scenario

where both H- and L-type winning vendors face the case N (O, A), and H denotes the hybrid

scenario where the H-type winning vendor always renegotiates (A) and the L-type renegotiates

opportunistically (O). The conditions for these renegotiation scenarios are summarized as follows:

(N ) : q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈ (−∞,0)

(O) : q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈ [0,QH) , where QH ≡(ε2|H − ε2|L

)/yO(θH)

(H) : q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈ [QH ,QL) , where QL ≡(ε2|H − ε2|L

)/yO(θL)

(A) : q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H ∈ [QL,∞) .

By Equations (15) and (16), the expected information rent of the winner (at the beginning of

phase 1) can be written as

Eθ(1),θ(2) [u∗] =JHL [cF (θL)− cF (θH)]

Page 22: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope22 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

+

0 (N )

12αPH

(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H

)2JHL [yO(θH)− yO(θL)] (O)

JHL

{12α[(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2)

2yA(θH) +PHPL

(ε2|H − ε2|L

)2]

− 12αPH

(q0 + γx− s1 + ε2|H

)2yO(θL)

}(H)

12α (q0 + γx− s1 + ε2)

2JHL [yA(θH)− yA(θL)] (A)

where JHL = Pr{θ(1) = θH , θ(2) = θL}.

Proposition 2. The expected information rent of the winner increases in the buyer’s upfront

investment x and the vendor’s bargaining power α, and decreases in the initial scope s1.

The results of Proposition 2 are intuitive: both increasing the buyer’s upfront investment x and

reducing initial scope s1 have the effect of increasing marginal return from the vendor investment

(as seen from Equation (12)). When the marginal return from vendor investment is higher, the high

types enjoy a greater advantage, giving them greater information rent. The vendor’s bargaining

power α is a multiplier of the winning vendor’s surplus (see Equation (14)). Thus, a higher α also

results in more information rent for the winning vendor. These effects, combined with the earlier

finding that vendor investment increases in x and α and decreases in s1(Proposition 1), highlight

the buyer’s trade-off: when the incentive for vendor investment is higher, the information rent

accrued to the winning vendor also increases.

Our finding that a larger initial scope helps reduce vendor information rent stands in contrast to

an earlier finding by Herweg and Schwarz (2018), which suggests a simpler design plus renegotiation

can compress vendors’ information rent. In Herweg and Schwarz (2018), the buyer is only concerned

with the rent extraction problem with heterogeneous costs of implementing the scope; a smaller

scope in their setting helps compress the winning vendor’s information rent. By contrast, in our

model, the buyer must balance rent extraction and incentivizing investment. In our setting, a larger

initial scope leaves less room for renegotiation and thus undermines vendor investment, which

limits the winning vendor’s advantage over competitors and hence reduces his information rent.

Page 23: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 23

4.3. Buyer’s Problem

At phase 1, the buyer’s problem is to choose initial scope s1 and upfront investment x to maximize

her total expected surplus:

v(s1, x)≡Eθ(1),θ(2),ε1 [v1 + v2] (17)

=Eθ(1),θ(2),ε1

[(q0 + γx+ θ(1)z

∗(θ(1)) + ε1)s1−

1

2x2− c(θ(2))

]︸ ︷︷ ︸

(i) Buyer’s expected phase-1 surplus

+Eθ(1),ε1

{1−α

2

[(q0 + γx− s1 + θ(1)z

∗(θ(1)) + ε2|1)+]2}

︸ ︷︷ ︸(ii) Buyer’s expected phase-2 surplus

.

In Equation (17), the term (i) is the buyer’s expected surplus from the phase-1 contract, and the

term (ii) is the buyer’s share of the expected renegotiation surplus. The buyer’s total expected

surplus v(s1, x) depends on the renegotiation scenario (i.e.,N ,O,H, orA) induced by her decisions.

Similar to Assumption 1, we need to make a few technical assumptions to ensure that the buyer’s

problem has an interior solution and her optimal investment is finite.

Assumption 2. We assume

a. 0≤ γ <mink∈{N ,O,H,A} γk,

b. QH1 ≤QO2, and

c. QA ≤QH2,

where the “Q”’s are thresholds for the baseline quality q0, and γk ∈ (0,1] is the upper bound for the

buyer’s expertise under renegotiation scenario k ∈ {N ,O,H,A} (the formulas of all the terms are

in Online Appendix EC.1, the proof of Lemma 4).

Assumption 2a sets an upper bound for the buyer’s expertise γ. This assumption ensures that the

buyer’s expected surplus v(s1, x) is jointly concave in (s1, x) under each renegotiation scenario (N ,

O, H, and A). By this assumption, we can obtain a local optimum for each scenario. Assumptions

2b and 2c further ensure that the buyer’s global optimal decision is always an interior solution of a

renegotiation scenario, rather than a boundary solution between two adjacent scenarios – the latter

is unlikely to occur but significantly complicates the analysis. Together, Assumption 2 implies that

Page 24: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope24 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

the buyer’s global optimal solution can be obtained by comparing the interior solutions for different

renegotiation scenarios. The following lemma outlines the condition for a renegotiation scenario to

be optimal.

Lemma 4. The buyer’s optimal initial scope s∗1, upfront investment x∗, and the corresponding

expected surplus v∗ ≡ v(s∗1, x∗) are as follows:

(s∗1, x∗, v∗) =

(s∗1N , x∗N , v

∗N ) if q0 ∈ (0,Q1]

(s∗1O, x∗O, v

∗O) if q0 ∈ (Q1,Q2]

(s∗1H, x∗H, v

∗H) if q0 ∈ (Q2,Q3]

(s∗1A, x∗A, v

∗A) if q0 ∈ (Q3,∞)

(18)

where the “Q”’s are thresholds for the baseline quality q0 (Q1 ≤Q2 ≤Q3), and s∗1k and x∗k denote

the interior optimal solution for the renegotiation scenario k ∈ {N ,O,H,A} with the corresponding

expected surplus v∗k (the formulas of all terms are in Online Appendix EC.1).

Noting that the scenariosN ,O,H, andA are in ascending order of the likelihood of renegotiation,

Lemma 4 shows that the buyer optimally induces a higher likelihood of renegotiation when the

baseline quality q0 is relatively high. This is because a higher baseline quality q0 reduces the impact

of uncertainty on the quality of deliverables in phase 1, so that the ex-post optimal scope is more

likely to be larger than the initial scope (Lemma 1). To measure quality uncertainty relative to

the baseline quality q0, we define σ/q0 as the relative quality uncertainty, where σ is the standard

deviation of the latent quality state ε0.8 We visualize the results of Lemma 4 by mapping out

the optimal renegotiation scenarios as a function of the relative quality uncertainty σ/q0 and the

vendor’s bargaining power α (Figure 2). As seen from this figure, the optimal scenario can be N ,

O, H, or A. As predicted by Lemma 4, as the relative quality uncertainty σ/q0 decreases and

the vendor’s bargaining power α increases, the optimal scenario moves from N , O, H, to A, with

8 Recalling that ε0 is a Bernoulli variable with Pr{ε0 = εH}= λ and mean zero, we can derive that σ= εH√

λ1−λ .

Page 25: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 25

an increasing likelihood of renegotiation. Intuitively, this is because when α is high and σ is low,

the vendor’s marginal return from his investment is high, making it less costly to motivate the

vendor investment. It may seem counter-intuitive for the buyer to induce renegotiation when the

vendor’s bargaining power is high, but when this is the case, the vendor is well-positioned to make

an efficient investment decision. Renegotiation capitalizes on this situation by making the high-

bargaining-power vendor a residual claimant (Che and Hausch 1999). This can indirectly benefit

the buyer because a vendor expecting a high renegotiation surplus bids lower in the reverse auction

phase.

Figure 2 The buyer’s optimal renegotiation scenario as a function of the relative quality uncertainty (σ/q0) and

the vendor’s bargaining power α.

A

ON

H

Vendor’s bargaining power α

Rel

ativ

e qual

ity u

nce

rtai

nty

σ/q

0

Note. Parameters: n= 2, θH = 0.9, θL = 0.45, β = 0.5, γ = 0.4, λ= 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85, and ρ2 = 0.7.

Having examined the buyer’s preferred renegotiation scenarios, we now explore the buyer’s deci-

sions, namely the initial scope s1 and the upfront investment x, focusing on their strategic rela-

tionship. Following Bulow et al. (1985) and Fudenberg and Tirole (2013), we say that they are

strategic substitutes (substitutes for short) if ∂2v∂s1∂x

< 0 and strategic complements (complements

for short) if ∂2v∂s1∂x

> 0. We pay particular attention to the strategic relationship because the buyer

should coordinate between the two decisions.

Proposition 3. (i) Under the never-renegotiate scenario N , the initial scope s1 and the upfront

investment x are always complements for the buyer.

Page 26: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope26 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

( ii) Under the renegotiation scenario k ∈ {O,H,A}, s1 and x are complements (substitutes) for

the buyer if Yk > Tk (Yk < Tk), where Yk (Tk) corresponds to the strength of the complementarity

(substitutability) between s1 and x in phase 1 (phase 2). The formulas of Yk and Tk are in Equations

(EC.3) and (EC.4) of the Online Appendix, respectively.

We illustrate the prediction of Proposition 3 in Figure 3, where we plot the strategic relationship

between s1 and x as a function of the vendor’s bargaining power α and the probability of the high-

quality state in phase 1, PH . We observe that, under the opportunistically-renegotiate scenario

O, s1 and x are complements in most cases except when the phase-1 is very likely to realize the

high-quality state (PH is high) and the vendor’s bargaining power is not high. Further, s1 and x

are more likely substitutes under the hybrid scenario H than under scenario O. Under the always-

renegotiate scenario A, s1 and x are complements if and only if the vendor’s bargaining power α

exceeds a threshold, regardless of the probability of the high quality state in phase 1.

Figure 3 Strategic relationship between s1 and x as a function of α and PH .

Vendor’s bargaining power α

Scenario

Pro

bab

ilit

y o

f ϵ

1 =

ϵH

, P

H

H

A

YA =

TA

YH = T

H

YO = TO

O

N

I

II

III

IVI, II, III, IV-

II, III, IV

III, IV

IVI, II, III

I, II

I

Zones where s1 and x are

complementssubstitutes

Note. Parameters: n= 2, θH = 0.9, θL = 0.1, and β = 0.5.

The intuition of Proposition 3 is as follows. Recall that the buyer’s expected surplus is composed

of two parts, phase-1 initial contract surplus and phase-2 renegotiation surplus (see Equation (17)).

For the former, the buyer’s initial scope s1 and upfront investment x are always complements:

a higher initial scope s1 justifies more buyer investment x because the investment would have a

Page 27: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 27

broader impact; conversely, a higher buyer investment translates into a higher project quality, thus

incentivizing the buyer to set a higher initial scope. For the phase-2 buyer surplus, s1 and x are

substitutes: a higher initial scope s1 implies less room for additional scope s2 in phase 2, thus the

optimal buyer investment that maximizes the phase-2 surplus is lower; conversely, a higher buyer

investment x implies a higher implementation quality, thus to maximize the phase-2 surplus, the

buyer should set a lower initial scope s1 to leave more space for additional scope in phase 2. The

overall relationship between s1 and x depends on the relative weight of the two phases. In the

never-renegotiate scenario (N ), the buyer’s expected surplus solely comes from phase 1, implying

s1 and x are complements. In the opportunistically-renegotiate scenario (O), because renegotiation

occurs only with probability PH , the proportion of buyer surplus from renegotiation is small.

Consequently, the buyer mainly cares about her phase-1 surplus, implying that s1 and x are mostly

complements except when her phase-2 surplus is sufficiently large. The latter occurs when PH is

very high and the vendor’s bargaining power is not too high. In the always-renegotiate scenario

(A), expected surplus from renegotiation is no longer a function of PH . The relative weights of

phase-2 surplus from renegotiation is a function of vendor bargaining power α. When α is small,

the phase-2 surplus dominates, causing s1 and x to be substitutes; conversely, s1 and x become

complements. In the hybrid-renegotiation scenario (H), the probability of renegotiation is higher

than that in scenario O but lower than that in scenario A, thus, s1 and x are more likely to be

substitutes in scenario H than in scenario O but less likely than in scenario A.

To see the implications of Proposition 3 for the buyer’s optimal decisions, we plot the buyer’s

optimal initial scope s1 and upfront investment x as a function of the relative quality uncertainty

σ/q0 in Figure 4. We observe that when the relative quality uncertainty decreases, the buyer would

increase her upfront investment to improve the implementation quality, but may either increase

or decrease the initial scope, depending on the likelihood of renegotiation. In scenario N , since

the buyer’s initial scope and upfront investment are always complements, the initial scope also

increases. A similar phenomenon is observed in scenario O due to the mostly complementary

Page 28: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope28 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

relationship between the two decisions. In scenario A, however, the vendor’s bargaining power

determines the relationship according to Proposition 3. When the vendor’s bargaining power α

is not high (Figure 4a-b), as the quality uncertainty decreases, the initial scope weakly decreases

while the upfront investment increases; when the vendor’s bargaining power is high (Figure 4c),

both the initial scope and the upfront investment increase.

Figure 4 Buyer’s optimal s1 and x as a function of the relative quality uncertainty.

Optimal upfront investment x* Optimal upfront investment x* Optimal upfront investment x*

σ/q0 decreases

from 2 to 0

in 30 steps

σ/q0 decreases

from 3 to 1

in 30 steps

σ/q0 decreases

from 3 to 1

in 30 steps

Opti

mal

init

ial

scope s 1*

Opti

mal

init

ial

scope s 1*

Opti

mal

init

ial

scope s 1*

OC

NC NC

NC

OC

HS

AS AS AC

HC

OC

(a) α = 0.3 (b) α = 0.6 (c) α = 0.9

Note. kC (kS) denotes the renegotiation scenario k ∈ {N ,O,H,A} with s1 and x being complements (substitutes).

Parameters: n= 2, θH = 0.9, θL = 0.45, β = 0.5, γ = 0.4, λ= 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85, ρ2 = 0.7, and q0 = 1.

We note that in some extreme cases, the initial scope s1 can be zero (e.g., when α= 0.3 and σ is

very low). We interpret such cases as the buyer is interested in the smallest possible initial project.

The intuition is as follows. When the initial scope is very small, vendors are willing to compete

aggressively in phase 1, anticipating that in phase 2, they will have a high chance of renegotiating

the project’s scope and earning a large surplus. Such small-scope initial contracts seem common in

practice: buyers often design the initial contract to be a pilot or discovery project with the intent

of expanding the project’s scope when the initial project turns out to be successful (Snir and Hitt

2004, Hertzum et al. 2012, Fenton 2016). Moreover, there is also anecdotal evidence that some

vendors anticipate a project to be renegotiated in their favor and therefore bid very aggressively

to win the initial contract (Herweg and Schwarz 2018, Bajari et al. 2014).

Page 29: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 29

4.4. Comparative Statics

Having solved the model, we now turn our attention to how the initial scope and buyer upfront

investment change with underlying model primitives. We focus on two key factors, namely, the

degree of vendor competition and the degree of information asymmetry. Because it is not possible

to compare equilibrium results analytically, we resort to numerical analyses.

4.4.1. Number of Competing Vendors To examine how competition affects the buyer’s

relative reliance on the phase-1 auction and the phase-2 renegotiation, we vary the number of

vendors n from 2 to 6 with a step size of 2, where a larger n represents more competition. As depicted

in Figure 5, the buyer’s optimal decisions inducing scenario N are unaffected by competition,

because no vendor would make any investment. In optimal scenarios O, H, and A, however, the

buyer responds to a larger n by reducing the initial scope s1 (Figure 5a) and increasing her upfront

investment x (Figure 5c). This result is interesting because although increased competition makes

the reverse auction more efficient, the buyer relies on the auction less, in contrast with earlier

research (e.g., Bajari et al. 2008). The intuition is as follows: with a larger n, the expected expertise

of the winner is higher, making it more attractive to increase x and reduce s1 to induce more vendor

investment (Figure 5d). We also observe that a larger n leads to a higher phase-2 scope (Figure

5b). Intuitively, as a larger n leads to higher investments from both sides, the optimal ex-post

scope tends to increase due to the improved implementation quality. In sum, with a larger pool of

qualified vendors, the buyer prefers a smaller initial scope for the auction phase and a larger scope

for the renegotiation phase.

4.4.2. Effect of Information Asymmetry It is interesting to examine whether the buyer

relies more or less on auctions when the degree of information asymmetry increases. We capture

the degree of information asymmetry by varying the dispersion of vendor expertise while fixing

its mean. In particular, we fix the mean expertise to 0.5 while varying the spread θH − θL from

0 to 1. With a greater expertise spread, we can expect greater information asymmetry. Figure

6 illustrates the results of numerical analysis with n = 2, α = 0.8, γ = 0.4, λ = 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85,

Page 30: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope30 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Figure 5 Effect of the number of competing vendors on the buyer’s decisions.(a) Phase-1 scope

n=2, 4, 6

(b) Exp. phase-2 scope (c) Buyer investment (d) Exp. vendor investment

Vendor’s bargaining power α

n=2, 4, 6n=2, 4, 6

n=2, 4, 6

ON

HA

ON

HA

ON

HA

ON

HA

Note. Parameters: θH = 0.9, θL = 0.45, β = 0.5, γ = 0.4, λ= 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85, ρ2 = 0.7, q0 = 0.741, and σ= 1.

ρ2 = 0.7, and β = 0.5. Figure 6a illustrates the optimal renegotiation scenario as a function of the

vendor expertise spread and the relative quality uncertainty. We observe that the buyer is more

likely to induce a higher likelihood of renegotiation as the expertise spread increases. Figures 6b-c

visualize how the project scopes in two phases and the investments from the buyer and the vendor

change with the expertise spread, given the relative quality uncertainty. We observe that, as the

expertise spread increases, the buyer should decrease the initial scope s1 (Figure 6b) and increase

her upfront investment x (Figure 6c), suggesting increased reliance on renegotiation. The reason is

as follows. As we increase the expertise spread, the winner tends to have higher expertise, which

motivates the buyer to induce more vendor investment (Figure 6c) by increasing her investment

x and reducing the initial scope (Proposition 1). When the vendors’ expertise is more dispersed,

the relative advantage of the winning vendor over competitors increases, which leads to higher

information rent to the winner. Figure 6 reveals that the buyer responds to the increased expertise

spread by incentivizing vendor investment rather than regulating information rent. Finally, the

expected phase-2 scope increases in the expertise spread. The intuition is similar to Figure 5b, thus

omitted.

Page 31: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 31

Figure 6 Effect of information asymmetry on the buyer’s decisions.(a) Renegotiation scenario division (b) Project scopes (c) Quality investments

Vendor expertise spread θH – θL Vendor expertise spread θH – θL Vendor expertise spread θH – θL

A

N

OH

AN O H AN O H

Phase-1 scope

Exp. phase-2 scope

Buyer investment

Exp. vendor investment

Rel

ativ

e q

ual

ity

un

cert

ain

ty σ

/q0

Note. Parameters: n= 2, α= 0.8, γ = 0.4, λ= 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85, ρ2 = 0.7, β = 0.5, βθL + (1−β)θH = 0.5 and θH − θL

varies from 0 to 1; for (a), the relative quality uncertainty σ/ q0 varies from 0 to ∞; for (b) and (c), σ/ q0 = 1.3 and

σ= 1.

5. Extensions5.1. Auction Design with a Reserve Price

In the main model, we have assumed a simple reverse auction with no reserve price, which may

not maximize the buyer’s surplus. Here, we introduce a reserve price and examine whether/how

it may affect our results. With a reserve price r, if all vendors bid higher than r, there will be no

trade. Otherwise, the winner will be paid the next lowest bid or the reserve price, whichever is

lower. It is a standard result that in a second-price auction, bidders bid truthfully regardless of the

reserve price (Krishna 2009). Therefore, a bidder with type θ will bid c (θ;s1, x) (Equation (15)).9

The buyer maximizes her expected total surplus, v(s1, x, r), by choosing s1, x, and r jointly.

Recall that the equilibrium bid c (θ;s1, x) decreases in vendor expertise θ, thus the highest

equilibrium bid is c (θL;s1, x). When r ≥ c (θL;s1, x), the reserve price does not bind, and the

buyer’s total expected surplus stays the same as before. When r < c (θH ;s1, x), all vendors are

excluded, and the auction ends with no trade. This is never optimal since the buyer can obtain a

positive surplus without using a reserve price. Without loss of generality, we can focus on cases

c (θH ;s1, x)≤ r≤ c (θL;s1, x).

9 To better present the results with a reserve price, we rewrite the vendors’ true costs (Equation (15)) as c (θ;s1, x),

a function of the initial scope s1 and buyer’s upfront investment x.

Page 32: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope32 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

We call the reserve price r = c (θL;s1, x) “degenerate” since it is equivalent to no reserve price

as in our main model. The reserve prices c (θH ;s1, x)≤ r < c (θL;s1, x) are “non-degenerate” in the

sense that they exclude L-type vendors but not H -type. Among the non-degenerate reserve prices,

the buyer prefers r = c (θH ;s1, x) because she can pay the least when there is a single H-type

vendor. In this case, the buyer’s optimal initial scope s∗1 and upfront investment x∗ are given by:

(s∗1, x∗) = argmax

s1,xv (s1, x, c (θH ;s1, x)) . (19)

Denoting the buyer surplus v∗ ≡ v (s∗1, x∗, c (θH ; s∗1, x

∗)), we have the following lemma on the optimal

reserve price.

Lemma 5. The optimal reserve price is nondegenerate (i.e. r∗ = c (θH ; s∗1, x∗)) if v∗ > v∗ and

degenerate (i.e., r∗ = c (θL;s∗1, x∗) which is equivalent to no reserve price), otherwise. When the

optimal reserve price is nondegenerate, the optimal initial scope s∗1, upfront investment x∗, and

buyer surplus v∗ are given by

(s∗1, x∗, v∗) =

(s∗

1N , x∗N , v

∗N

)if q0 ∈ (0, Q1]

(s∗

1O, x∗O, v

∗O

)if q0 ∈ (Q1, Q2]

(s∗

1A, x∗A, v

∗A

)if q0 ∈ (Q2,∞)

(20)

where the formulas of all terms are in the Online Appendix.

The three conditions in Equation (20) correspond to the never-renegotiate (N ),

opportunistically-renegotiate (O), and always-renegotiate (A) scenarios with a nondegenerate

reserve price, respectively.10 Figure 7 illustrates the results of Lemma 5. Figures 7a-b show that

introducing a reserve price reduces s1 and increases x. This is because the reserve price can help

regulate information rent, so that the buyer can further reduce the initial scope s1 and increase her

upfront investment x to incentivize vendor investment. Figure 7c shows that the optimal reserve

10 Because a nondegenerate reserve price excludes L-type vendors, the hybrid scenario H where L-type and H-type

vendors face different renegotiate scenarios no longer exists.

Page 33: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 33

price decreases in the vendor’s bargaining power α. This is because when vendors have higher

bargaining power, a more aggressive reserve price is needed to exclude low-expertise vendors. The

reserve price may also be negative when the initial scope s1 and one-time fixed cost cF (θ) are small

(Figure 7c). A negative reserve price r < 0 indicates that the vendors should pay to be selected for

the first phase of the project. Furthermore, with a nondegenerate reserve price r= c (θH ;s1, x), the

buyer can achieve a larger phase-2 scope (Figure 7d) and induce greater vendor investment (Figure

7e) than no reserve price. The numerical simulation also reveals that the buyer is better off with

an optimal reserve price (Figure 7f).

Figure 7 The buyer’s optimal decision results with a degenerate, nondegenerate, and optimal reserve price r.(a) Phase-1 scope

(f) Exp. buyer profit(e) Exp. vendor invest.

(c) Reserve price

(d) Exp. phase-2 scope

(b) Buyer investment

Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α

Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α

Degenerate r (no reserve price) Nondegenerate r Optimal r

Note. Parameters: n= 2, θH = 0.9, θL = 0.45, β = 0.5, γ = 0.4, λ= 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85, ρ2 = 0.7, σ = 1, σ/q0 = 1.35, and

cF (θ) = 0.03 /(1 + θ) .

Proposition 4. When a nondegenerate reserve price r is adopted, the buyer’s phase-1 scope

s1 and upfront investment x are complements under scenarios N , substitutes under scenario A,

and complements (substitutes) under scenarios O if PH < P (PH > P ), where the expression of

P ∈ (0,1) is provided in Equation (EC.24) in the online appendix.

Page 34: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope34 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

The intuition of Proposition 4 is as follows. The reserve price increases the buyer’s surplus from

both the phase-1 auction (where s1 and x are complements) and, if any, the phase-2 renegotiation

(where s1 and x are substitutes) by excluding low-expertise vendors. Moreover, the increase from

the phase-2 renegotiation is more significant, because with the reserve price regulating information

rent, the buyer can further lower the initial scope s1 and increase her investment x to motivate more

vendor investment and obtain more renegotiation surplus. This makes s1 and x always substitutes

in the always-renegotiate scenario (A). However, the effect of the reserve price on phase-2 surplus

is discounted in scenario O, since the renegotiation occurs only with probability PH . As a result,

if the probability PH is higher than a threshold P , the substitutability between s1 and x can be

preserved as in the scenario A; otherwise (PH < P ), the reserve price would increase the weight of

the phase-1 surplus more than the phase-2 surplus for the buyer, making s1 and x complements. In

scenario N , s1 and x are always complements since the renegotiation never occurs, which is similar

to the situation without a reserve price.

5.2. Costly Learning of Project Quality

In the main model, we assume that the learning of the project quality is costless, in the sense

that no matter how small the phase-1 scope is, one learns the same amount about the phase-2

quality. This may lead to the buyer adopting a zero scope for phase 1. A more natural assumption

is that learning improves with the phase-1 scope. Specifically, we let the informativeness of the

phase-t project be ρt = 12

(dst + 1), t ∈ {1,2}, where 0 < d < 1s

and s is the maximum scope. By

this formulation, if the buyer chooses a zero scope for phase 1 (s1 = 0), then ρ1 = 12, implying that

phase 1 is completely uninformative. As s1 increases, the informativeness level ρ1 increases but

never reaches 1, the perfect information case. We refer to d as the learning coefficient; a higher d

means that one learns more from the same phase-1 scope.

It can be verified that the expectation of phase-2 quality state ε2 conditional on phase-1 quality

state ε1 is now dependent on both s1 and s2:

ε2|1 =1

2(εH + εL) +

1

2(εH − εL)ai(s1)s2, i=H if ε1 = εH , i=L if ε1 = εL

Page 35: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 35

where the formulas of aH (s1) and aL (s1) are provided in Equations (EC.28) and (EC.29) of the

Online Appendix, respectively. The phase-2 scope s2 and the winning vendor’s optimal upfront

investment z∗(θ) are as follows:

s2 =(µ+ γx− s1 + θz)

+

1− (εH − εL)ai (s1),

z∗(θ) =αθφ (s1) (µ+ γx− s1)

+

1−αθ2φ (s1)

where µ= q0 + (εH + εL)/2, and φ (s1) =Eε1{

[1− (εH − εL)ai (s1)]−1}

.

We prove that the results of Proposition 1, Lemma 3, and Proposition 2 all hold qualitatively

(see the Online Appendix EC.3). However, the buyer’s problem becomes analytically intractable

due to the complications in solving s1. We resort to numerical analyses to obtain insights on

the effect of costly learning. In Figure 8, we plot the buyer’s optimal decisions as a function of

the vendor’s bargaining power α and the learning coefficient d. It shows that when the learning

coefficient d increases, the buyer tends to set a greater initial scope s∗1 (Figure 8a), because a

higher d increases the learning benefits of implementing the initial scope. Moreover, a higher d

amplifies the strength of complementarity between s1 and x in phase-1 but reduces the strength of

substitutability between s1 and x in phase-2. Therefore, as the learning coefficient d increases, the

initial scope s1 and buyer investment x are more likely to be complements (Figure 8c), and hence

the buyer’s optimal investment x∗ also increases (Figure 8b).

5.3. Buyer Investment in Cost Reduction

In the main model, we only consider the buyer’s investment in quality improvement. One may

wonder whether our findings extend to buyer investment in cost reduction, another popular form of

investment. We next study an alternative specification by redefining x as buyer investment in cost

reduction instead of quality improvement. Specifically, we assume that the phase-t quality qt = q0 +

θz+ εt, t∈ {1,2}. Further, we assume the winning vendor’s implementation cost is s2t2(1+γx)

, where

x is the buyer’s investment in cost reduction and γ ≥ 0 is the associated investment coefficient. As

before, we assume γ is common knowledge.

Page 36: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope36 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Figure 8 Buyer’s optimal decision with costly learning.

Vendor’s bargaining power α

d = 0.34, 0.36, 0.38, 0.4

Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α

(Substitutes)

(Complements)

(a) Initial project scope s1* (b) Buyer investment x* (c) Strategic relationship

Qual

ity-l

earn

ing c

oef

fici

ent d

d = 0.34, 0.36, 0.38, 0.4

Note. Parameters: n= 2, λ= 0.5, εH = 2, εL =−2, β = 0.5, θH = 0.5, θL = 0.1 γ = 0.3, and q0 = 1.

It can be verified that the phase-2 scope s2 and the winning vendor’s optimal investment z∗(θ)

are as follows, where the superscript “c” (cost reduction) is used to distinguish notation from those

of the main model:

s2 =[(1 + γx)

(q0 + θz+ ε2|1

)− s1

]+

z∗ (θ) =

0 (N c)

αθPH[(1 + γx)

(q0 + ε2|H

)− s1

]ycO(θ) (Oc)

αθ [(1 + γx) (q0 + ε2)− s1]ycA(θ) (Ac)

where ycO(θ) = [1−αθ2PH (1 + γx)]−1

, ycA(θ) = [1−αθ2 (1 + γx)]−1

, and the conditions for the

never-renegotiate (N c), opportunistically-renegotiate (Oc), and always-renegotiate (Ac) cases are

given by

(N c): q0 + ε2|H − s1/ (1 + γx)∈ (−∞,0)

(Oc): q0 + ε2|H − s1/ (1 + γx)∈[0,(ε2|H − ε2|L

)/ycO(θ)

)(Ac): q0 + ε2|H − s1/ (1 + γx)∈

[(ε2|H − ε2|L

)/ycO(θ),∞

)We prove that Proposition 1, Lemma 3, and Proposition 2 all hold qualitatively (see the online

appendix EC.4). However, the buyer’s problem becomes analytically intractable due to increased

complexity in solving x. We resort to numerical analyses for insights on the effect of buyer invest-

ments in cost reduction. The buyer’s optimal decisions as a function of the vendor’s bargaining

Page 37: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 37

power α and the buyer’s investment coefficient γ are illustrated in Figure 9. Figure 9b shows that

with a higher γ, the buyer makes a higher upfront investment x to capitalize on increased invest-

ment effectiveness. However, the initial scope s1 may increase or decrease (Figure 9a), depending

on the strategic relationship between s1 and x. As observed in Figure 9c, s1 and x are substi-

tutes only when α is neither too low nor too high; otherwise, they are complements. As we have

demonstrated before (Figure 2), when the vendor’s bargaining power α is low, the buyer prefers

scenarios with a low probability of renegotiation (i.e., the never- and opportunistically-renegotiate

scenarios). Under these scenarios, the buyer puts more weight on the phase-1 surplus than phase-2,

therefore, s1 and x are complements. When α is high, the buyer prefers the scenario with a high

probability of renegotiation (the always-renegotiate scenario). Since the buyer obtains a small share

(1−α) of renegotiation surplus, the phase-1 surplus still dominates, and hence s1 and x are also

complements. When α is moderate, the buyer emphasizes the phase-2 renegotiation surplus, and

s1 and x become substitutes. In line with the above arguments, we observe from Figure 9a that

when the buyer’s investment coefficient γ increases from 0 to 0.3, the initial scope s1 decreases for

low or high α but increases for moderate α.

In sum, when the buyer investment has the effect of reducing implementation cost instead of

improving quality, buyer decisions and the strategic relationship between the initial scope and the

buyer investment are qualitatively similar to our main findings in Proposition 3.

6. Conclusion

Motivated by several challenges facing IT outsourcing, we investigate a hybrid procurement model

where the initial phase of a project is determined by a reverse auction but the two parties can

renegotiate a second phase to add additional scope. In this model, the buyer needs to both incen-

tivize non-contractible vendor investments that solely benefit the buyer and curb the information

rent of the winning vendor, with two upfront decisions: initial project scope and buyer upfront

investment in implementation quality. Using this model, we generate several insights about the

role of renegotiation, the role of the initial project scope, and the coordination between the two

buyer decisions.

Page 38: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope38 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Figure 9 Buyer’s optimal decision with investment in cost reduction.

Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α Vendor’s bargaining power α

(Substitutes)

(Complements

)

(Complements

)

(a) Initial project scope (b) Buyer investment (c) Strategic relationship

Inv

estm

ent

effe

ctiv

enes

s b

b = 0.30

b = 0.15

b = 0

b = 0.30

b = 0.15

b = 0

Note. Parameters: n= 2, β = 0.5, θH = 0.5, θL = 0.1, λ= 0.8, ρ1 = 0.85, ρ2 = 0.7, σ= 1, and q0 = 3.

This research contributes several novel insights to the literature. First, we show that it may be

sometimes beneficial for a buyer organization to induce ex-post renegotiation as a way of allevi-

ating the hold-up problem. When a renegotiation occurs, the vendor can claim a share of surplus

generated by the renegotiation, which can motivate non-contractible vendor investment that is

absent in a pure fixed-price reverse auction. While ex-post renegotiation happens for many reasons

such as flaws in the initial contract (e.g., Herweg and Schmidt 2020), we highlight a new reason –

that renegotiation may alleviate the hold-up problem.

Our second major insight is about the pivotal role of the initial project scope in IT outsourcing.

We show that the initial scope affects both information rent and vendor investment: a high initial

scope leaves little room for ex-post renegotiation, thus undermines vendor investment. When rene-

gotiation seldom occurs, the expected information rent of the winning vendor is low because they

do not have strong incentives to invest and therefore cannot turn their advantage in investment effi-

ciency into information rent. Understanding this, a buyer may strategically set a low initial project

scope to incentivize renegotiation and non-contractible vendor investment. This finding offers a

rational explanation for the observation that many IT outsourcing projects start small and allow

scope expansion (e.g., Barry et al. 2002). While scope expansion happens for many other reasons

(e.g., a lack of clarity and foresight), this is the first study to show that buyers can strategically

use anticipated scope expansions to motivate non-contractible vendor investments.

Page 39: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 39

Another novel insight from this research is about how initial scope and buyer investment should

be jointly used. Like initial scope, buyer investment also affects both information rent and vendor

investment, only in the opposite direction: a smaller buyer investment decreases vendor investment

and curbs information rent. Because the buyer investment is more beneficial when the project

scope is larger, one may intuitively think that initial scope and buyer investment are strategic

complements – high initial scope should go hand in hand with higher buyer investment. We show,

however, that the opposite may also be optimal. While the buyer should use high initial scope

and high upfront investment (i.e., treat the two measures as complements) to maximize phase-1

buyer surplus, she should use low initial scope and high buyer investment (substitutes) to maximize

phase-2 surplus from renegotiation. Whether the two decisions are complements or substitutes

depends critically on the renegotiation scenario and the vendor’s bargaining power. When a buyer

prefers little or no renegotiation, the buyer should focus on phase-1 surplus and thus treat the

two decisions as strategic complements. When the buyer prefers renegotiation, but the vendor’s

bargaining power is low, she needs both low initial scope and high buyer investment to induce

renegotiation, thus the two decisions are substitutes. When the vendor’s bargaining power is high,

the vendor has strong incentives to invest and the buyer can once again treat two decisions as

complements – high initial scope and high buyer investment can maximize the combined surplus

from the two phases. In an extension, we additionally show that when the buyer can use a reserve

price to regulate vendor information rent, initial scope and buyer investment become substitutes

at all times.

Our model produces a few counter-intuitive results. For example, we show that the buyer prefers

renegotiation to occur when the vendor’s bargaining power is high. This is because a vendor with

higher bargaining power is well-positioned to make an efficient upfront investment that increases

the value of the project to the buyer. As a result, the buyer should induce renegotiation in such

a case. This may explain why Korea Exchange extended their IT service contract with IBM, an

industry-leading vendor with high bargaining power, and why Google, NASA, and USRA extended

their contracts with D-WAVE, the only supplier of quantum computers (IBM 2009, Alto 2017).

Page 40: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope40 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

We also show that, as the number of competing vendors increases, the investment efficiency of

the top bidder is higher, and the buyer prefers a smaller initial scope for the reverse auction so that

she can capitalize on the increased efficiency. This contrasts with the conventional wisdom that

one should rely more on auctions when they are many bidders (e.g., Bajari et al. 2008). Herweg

and Schmidt (2017) also show that intensified competition leads to increased renegotiation, but

their argument is a supplier-side one: suppliers leverage their private information more through

renegotiation when competition is intense. By contrast, we offer a buyer-side explanation: the buyer

proactively induces more renegotiation to capitalize on the winner’s increased investment efficiency.

We show that our main results are robust under several alternative specifications, including

permitting a reserve price in the reverse auction, making the informativeness of the phase-1 project

a function of its scope, and making the buyer investment cost-reducing instead of quality-enhancing.

Our findings generate several predictions for empirical research on IT outsourcing. First, our

results suggest that buyers who suffer from the hold-up problem are more likely to use a smaller

initial scope and renegotiate a larger scope after the initial contract. Second, auctions of contracts

that have a smaller scope but permit scope expansion are more profitable to buyers than auctions

of contracts that have a large but inflexible scope. Third, buyers who have relatively low bargaining

power are more likely to start with low initial project scope and to renegotiate with the vendor.

Some of our comparative static results are also readily testable. For example, our results show

that a higher-expertise vendor is more likely to renegotiate; when there is a large pool of qualified

vendors, we expect buyer investment to be higher and the initial project scope to be lower.

Our research can be extended in several ways. For example, our current model captures vendor

differences in investment efficiency and fixed costs; future research can extend our model to allow

other types of vendor differences such as heterogeneous implementation costs. Another way of

extending the model is to consider transaction costs associated with renegotiation, though we

expect our main insights to hold even with added transaction costs. Although our research focuses

on IT outsourcing, our findings may also hold implications for other outsourcing contexts where the

Page 41: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 41

hold-up and information asymmetry problems are prominent. It will also be interesting to compare

our hybrid procurement model with other procurement mechanisms in IT outsourcing and other

related contexts.

References

Aghion P, Bolton P (1992) An incomplete contracts approach to financial contracting. The Review of Eco-

nomic Studies 59(3):473–494.

Agrawal V, Oraiopoulos N (2020) The role of decision rights in codevelopment initiatives. Manufacturing &

Service Operations Management 22(4):832–849.

Alto P (2017) D-Wave 2000Q system to be installed at Quantum Artificial Intelligence Lab run by Google,

NASA, and Universities Space Research Association. Available at https://bit.ly/D-Wave2000Q.

Aubert BA, Rivard S, Patry M (2004) A transaction cost model of IT outsourcing. Information & Manage-

ment 41(7):921–932.

August T, Shin H, Tunca TI (2017) Generating value through open source: Software service market regulation

and licensing policy. Information Systems Research 29(1):186–205.

Bajari P, Houghton S, Tadelis S (2014) Bidding for incomplete contracts: An empirical analysis of adaptation

costs. The American Economic Review 104(4):1288–1319.

Bajari P, McMillan R, Tadelis S (2008) Auctions versus negotiations in procurement: an empirical analysis.

The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 25(2):372–399.

Bajari P, Tadelis S (2001) Incentives versus transaction costs: A theory of procurement contracts. Rand

Journal of Economics 32(3):387–407.

Barry EJ, Mukhopadhyay T, Slaughter SA (2002) Software project duration and effort: an empirical study.

Information Technology and Management 3(1-2):113–136.

Benaroch M, Dai Q, Kauffman RJ (2010) Should we go our own way? Backsourcing flexibility in IT services

contracts. Journal of Management Information Systems 26(4):317–358.

Bhattacharya S, Gupta A, Hasija S (2014) Joint product improvement by client and customer support center:

The role of gain-share contracts in coordination. Information Systems Research 25(1):137–151.

Page 42: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope42 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Binmore K, Rubinstein A, Wolinsky A (1986) The nash bargaining solution in economic modelling. Rand

Journal of Economics 17(2):176–188.

Bowman R (2019) Return of the reverse auction: Will suppliers play? Available at

https://www.supplychainbrain.com/blogs/1-think-tank/post/30131-return-of-the-reverse-auction-will-

suppliers-play.

Bradford L (2019) Different types of IT outsourcing. Available at https://www.thebalancecareers.com/what-

is-it-outsourcing-2072001.

Branco F (1997) The design of multidimensional auctions. The RAND Journal of Economics 63–81.

Brosig-Koch J, Heinrich T (2014) Reputation and mechanism choice in procurement auctions: An experiment.

Production and Operations Management 23(2):210–220.

Bulow JI, Geanakoplos JD, Klemperer PD (1985) Multimarket oligopoly: Strategic substitutes and comple-

ments. Journal of Political economy 93(3):488–511.

Cao Q, Wang Q (2007) Optimizing vendor selection in a two-stage outsourcing process. Computers & Oper-

ations Research 34(12):3757–3768.

Chaudhury A, Nam K, Rao HR (1995) Management of information systems outsourcing: A bidding perspec-

tive. Journal of Management Information Systems 12(2):131–159.

Che YK (1993) Design competition through multidimensional auctions. The RAND Journal of Economics

668–680.

Che YK, Hausch DB (1999) Cooperative investments and the value of contracting. American Economic

Review 89(1):125–147.

Che YK, Sakovics J (2008) Hold-up problem. Durlauf SN, Blume L, eds., The New Palgrave Dictionary of

Economics (Palgrave Macmillan Basingstoke), 2nd edition.

Deloitte (2013) The outsourcing handbook: A guide to outsourcing. Available at

http://www.deloitte.co.uk/makeconnections/assets/pdf/the-outsourcing-handbook-a-guide-to-

outsourcing.pdf.

Deloitte (2016) Global outsourcing survey 2016. Available at http://www.deloitte.com/us/ outsourcing.

Page 43: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 43

Dogan K, Ji Y, Mookerjee VS, Radhakrishnan S (2011) Managing the versions of a software product under

variable and endogenous demand. Information Systems Research 22(1):5–21.

Engelbrecht-Wiggans R, Haruvy E, Katok E (2007) A comparison of buyer-determined and price-based

multiattribute mechanisms. Marketing Science 26(5):629–641.

ESSU (2017) Somerset County Council to renegotiate PPP contract with IBM. Available

at https://www.european-services-strategy.org.uk/news/2011/somerset-county-council-to-renegotiate-

ppp-con.

FAA (2015) FAA Cloud Services (FCS) Acquisition SIR No. DTFACT-13-R-00013. Available at

https://faaco.faa.gov/index.cfm/announcement/view/22274.

Fenton S (2016) Preparing IT for the Internet of Things. Available at https://www.

cioapplications.com/cioviewpoint/preparing-it-for-the-internet-of-things-nid-420.html.

Fitoussi D, Gurbaxani V (2012) IT outsourcing contracts and performance measurement. Information Sys-

tems Research 23(1):129–143.

Fudenberg D, Tirole J (2013) Dynamic models of oligopoly (Routledge).

Fugger N, Katok E, Wambach A (2015) Collusion in dynamic buyer-determined reverse auctions. Manage-

ment Science 62(2):518–533.

Gartner (2005) Gartner says vendors must be prepared to renegotiate outsourcing contracts Available at

http://www.gartner.com/newsroom/id/492133.

Gil R, Oudot JM (2009) Competitive bidding, renegotiation and relational contracting: Evidence from French

defense procurement. University of California Santa Cruz, working paper.

Grand View Research (2020) IT services outsourcing market size, share & trends analysis report 2020 - 2027.

Available at https://www.grandviewresearch.com/industry-analysis/it-services-outsourcing-market.

Grossman SJ, Hart OD (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integra-

tion. Journal of Political Economy 94(4):691–719.

Hertzum M, Bansler JP, Havn EC, Simonsen J (2012) Pilot implementation: Learning from field tests in is

development. Communications of the Association for Information Systems 30:313–328.

Page 44: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope44 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Herweg F, Schmidt KM (2015) Loss aversion and inefficient renegotiation. The Review of Economic Studies

82(1):297–332.

Herweg F, Schmidt KM (2017) Auctions versus negotiations: the effects of inefficient renegotiation. The

RAND Journal of Economics 48(3):647–672.

Herweg F, Schmidt KM (2020) Procurement with unforeseen contingencies. Management Science 66(5):2194–

2212.

Herweg F, Schwarz MA (2018) Optimal cost overruns: Procurement auctions with renegotiation. Interna-

tional Economic Review 59(4):1995–2021.

Huh WT, Park KS (2010) A sequential auction-bargaining procurement model. Naval Research Logistics

57(1):13–32.

IBM (2009) IBM and Korea Exchange renew integrated maintenance service contract for third consecutive

year. Available at https://www-03.ibm.com/press/us/en/pressrelease/ 26568.wss.

Jung H (2016) Renegotiation on incomplete procurement contracts. Applied Economics 48(23):2125–2138.

Krishna V (2009) Auction Theory (Academic press).

Kujala J, Nysten-Haarala S, Nuottila J (2015) Flexible contracting in project business. International Journal

of Managing Projects in Business 8(1):92–106.

Lacity MC, Khan SA, Willcocks LP (2009) A review of the IT outsourcing literature: Insights for practice.

The Journal of Strategic Information Systems 18(3):130–146.

Lee CH, Geng X, Raghunathan S (2013) Contracting information security in the presence of double moral

hazard. Information Systems Research 24(2):295–311.

Li C (2013) Sourcing for supplier effort and competition: Design of the supply base and pricing mechanism.

Management Science 59(6):1389–1406.

Liang H, Wang JJ, Xue Y, Cui X (2016) IT outsourcing research from 1992 to 2013: A literature review

based on main path analysis. Information & Management 53(2):227–251.

Milgrom PR, Weber RJ (1982) A theory of auctions and competitive bidding. Econometrica 50(5):1089–1122.

Page 45: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable ScopeArticle submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science 45

Miller DP (2014) Subcontracting and competitive bidding on incomplete procurement contracts. The Rand

Journal of Economics 45(4):705–746.

Miller J (2017) GSA picks 10 vendors for $50b next-gen telecom contract. Available at

https://federalnewsnetwork.com/contractsawards/2017/08/gsa-picks-10-vendors-for-50b-next-gen-

telecom-contract/.

Mishra M, Bureau MT (2012) Clients ask IT firms like Infosys, TCS to bid for low-end projects

through reverse auctions. Available at http://articles.economictimes. indiatimes.com/2012-01-

10/news/30611682 1 auctions-outsourcing-sourcing-advisory-firm.

Nam K, Chaudhury A, Rao HR (1995) A mixed integer model of bidding strategies for outsourcing. European

Journal of Operational Research 87(2):257–273.

Reece D (2004) BBC shortlists three for £150m auction of technology arm. Available at

http://www.independent.co.uk/news/business/news/bbc-shortlists-three-for-pound150m-auction-of-

technology-arm-562524.html.

Riordan MH, Sappington DE (1989) Second sourcing. The RAND Journal of Economics 41–58.

Roels G, Karmarkar US, Carr S (2010) Contracting for collaborative services. Management Science

56(5):849–863.

Rose KH (2013) A guide to the Project Management Body of Knowledge (PMBOK® Guide)–Fifth edition.

Project Management Journal 44(3):e1–e1.

Snir EM, Hitt LM (2004) Vendor screening in information technology contracting with a pilot project.

Journal of Organizational Computing and Electronic Commerce 14(1):61–88.

Sundqvist E, Backlund F, Chroneer D (2014) What is project efficiency and effectiveness? Procedia-Social

and Behavioral Sciences 119:278–287.

Susarla A (2012) Contractual flexibility, rent seeking, and renegotiation design: An empirical analysis of

information technology outsourcing contracts. Management Science 58(7):1388–1407.

Susarla A, Subramanyam R, Karhade P (2010) Contractual provisions to mitigate holdup: Evidence from

information technology outsourcing. Information Systems Research 21(1):37–55.

Page 46: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope46 Article submitted to Management Science; manuscript no. Accepted at Management Science

Tirole J (1986) Procurement and renegotiation. Journal of Political Economy 94(2):235–259.

Tunca TI, Zenios SA (2006) Supply auctions and relational contracts for procurement. Manufacturing &

Service Operations Management 8(1):43–67.

Wang R (2000) Bidding and renegotiation in procurement auctions. European Economic Review 44(8):1577–

1597.

Williamson OE (1979) Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual relations. The Journal of

Law and Economics 22(2):233–261.

Wilson D (2016) GSA opens bids on massive $50b federal IT contracts. Available at http://

www.law360.com/articles/811795/gsa-opens-bids-on-massive-50b-federal-it-contracts.

Wyld DC (2011) Reverse auctioning: saving money and increasing transparency. Available at

http://www.businessofgovernment.org/sites/default/files/Reverse%20Auctioning.pdf.

Xiao W, Xu Y (2012) The impact of royalty contract revision in a multistage strategic R&D alliance.

Management Science 58(12):2251–2271.

Page 47: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Appendix. Online Companion to “Auctioning IT Contractswith Renegotiable Scope”

EC.1. Proofs of Lemmas and Propositions for the Main Model

Proof of Lemma 1. Define L(s2, p2) = ln(uα2v

1−α2 ), then the renegotiation problem in

Equation (3) can be rewritten as

maxs2,p2

L(s2, p2) = α ln (u2)+ (1−α) ln (v2)

subject to s2 ≥ 0, u2 ≥ 0 and v2 ≥ 0. The first-order conditions are

∂L

∂s2=− α

u2

(s1 + s2)+1−α

v2

(q0+ γx+ θz+ ϵ2|1

)= 0 (EC.1)

∂L

∂p2=

α

u2

− 1−α

v2= 0 (EC.2)

Solving the Equations (EC.1)-(EC.2) simultaneously subject to s2 ≥ 0 yields the results

of Lemma 1. It is easy to verify that the second-order conditions and the constraints

u2 ≥ 0 and v2 ≥ 0 are satisfied. Also note that by Equations (EC.1)-(EC.2), the optimal

phase 2 scope s2 can be equivalently determined by maximizing the entire social surplus

u2 + v2 + u1 + v1, or by maximizing the renegotiation surplus S = u2 + v2 since u1 and v1

are independent of s2. Q.E.D.

Proof of Lemma 2. Since the winning vendor’s objective function (12) is piecewise,

depending on the sign of q0+γx−s1+θz+ ϵ2|1, we analyze the optimal vendor investment

by three cases.

(i) If q0+γx−s1+θz+ ϵ2|H < 0, Equation (12) becomes u(z;θ, p1) = p1−cF (θ)− 12s21− 1

2z2,

which is maximized at z = 0. Substituting z = 0, the condition q0 + γx− s1 + θz+ ϵ2|H < 0

becomes condition (N): q0 + γx− s1 + ϵ2|H < 0.

ec1

Page 48: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec2 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

(ii) If q0 + γx − s1 + θz + ϵ2|H ≥ 0 and q0 + γx − s1 + θz + ϵ2|L < 0, Equation (12)

becomes u(z;θ, p1) = p1− cF (θ)− 12s21− 1

2z2+ αPH

2

(q0 + γx− s1 + θz+ ϵ2|H

)2, which is max-

imized at z = αθPH

(q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2|H

)yO(θ). Then the conditions q0 + γx − s1 + θz +

ϵ2|H ≥ 0 and q0 + γx− s1 + θz + ϵ2|L < 0 become condition (O): 0 ≤ q0 + γx− s1 + ϵ2|H <(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)/yO(θ).

(iii) If q0+ γx− s1+ θz+ ϵ2|L ≥ 0, Equation (12) becomes u(z;θ, p1) = p1− cF (θ)− 12s21−

12z2 + αPH

2

(q0 + γx− s1 + θz+ ϵ2|H

)2+ αPL

2

(q0 + γx− s1+ θz+ ϵ2|L

)2, which is maximized

at z = αθ (q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2)yA(θ). The condition q0+ γx− s1+ θz+ ϵ2|L ≥ 0 then becomes

condition (A): q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2|H ≥(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)/yO(θ).

Summarizing the results of (i)-(iii) yields Lemma 2. Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 1. For case O, we have ∂z∗

∂s1=−αθPHyO(θ)≤ 0, ∂z∗

∂x= αθPHγyO(θ)≥

0, and ∂z∗

∂α= θPH(q0 + γx− s1 + ϵ2|H)y

2O(θ) ≥ 0; for case A, we have ∂z∗

∂s1= −αθyA(θ) ≤ 0,

∂z∗

∂x= αθγyA(θ)≥ 0, and ∂z∗

∂α= θ(q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2)y

2A(θ)≥ 0. Q.E.D.

Lemma A1 (Revenue Equivalence). At phase 0, any symmetric and decreasing (with

respect to expertise) equilibrium of any standard reverse auction, such that the expected

payment to a vendor with expertise θ is zero, yields the same expected revenue to the buyer.

Proof of Lemma A1. This Lemma is an adaption of Proposition 3.1 of Krishna (2009),

and we prove it accordingly. Consider a standard reverse auction format F and a symmetric

and decreasing bidding equilibrium B of F . Let QF(θ) be the expected payment to a bidder

with expertise θ in equilibrium B, and suppose QF(θ) = 0. When all bidders other than i

adopt the equilibrium bidding strategy, the expected profit of bidder i (with expertise θi)

when he bids B(θ) is

uF(θi, θ) =QF(θ)− c(θi)G(θ)

Page 49: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec3

where G(θ) = F n−1(θ) is the distribution of Θ = maxj =i θj, and QF(θ) = B(θ)G(θ) by

definition. Since B is an equilibrium, uF(θi, θ) should be maximized at θ= θi, which implies

∂uF(θi, θ)

∂θ|θ=θi =Q′

F(θi)− c(θi)G′(θi) = 0

Integration yields

QF(θi) =QF(θ)+

∫ θi

θ

c(θ)G′(θ)dθ=

∫ θi

θ

c(θ)G′(θ)dθ=EΘ[c(Θ)|Θ< θi]G(θi)

where the second equation is due to the assumption QF(θ) = 0. The last equation implies

that the expected payment borne by the buyer does not depend on the particular auction

format F . Further, since F is standard and B is symmetric and decreasing, the auction

always selects the vendor with the highest expertise θ(1) as the winner. Therefore, the trans-

action processes after the auction, thus the buyer’s expected revenue, is also independent

of the particular auction format F . The above facts imply that the buyer’s expected profit

does not depend on the particular auction format F , which concludes the proof. Q.E.D.

Proof of Lemma 3. The auction is a standard reverse auction where all bidders are

risk neutral and have i.i.d. pseudo types (costs) {c(θi)}ni=1. Then by auction theory (e.g.,

Krishna 2009), the results of Lemma 3 can be immediately obtained. Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 2. Let E[u∗] be the shorthand for Eθ(1),θ(2) [u∗(θ(1), c(θ(2)))]. For sce-

nario O, ∂E[u∗]∂s1

=−αPH(q0 + γx− s1 + ϵ2|H)JHL [yO(θH)− yO(θL)]≤ 0, ∂E[u∗]∂x

= γαPH(q0 +

γx−s1+ ϵ2|H)JHL [yO(θH)− yO(θL)]≥ 0, and ∂E[u∗]∂α

= 12PH(q0+γx−s1+ ϵ2|H)

2JHL[y2O(θH)−

y2O(θL)] ≥ 0. For scenario A, similar results can be obtained by letting PH = 1. For sce-

nario H, ∂E[u∗]∂s1

= −αJHL

[(q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2)yA(θH)−PH(q0 + γx− s1 + ϵ2|H)yO(θL)

]≤ 0,

∂E[u∗]∂x

= αγJHL

[(q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2)yA(θH)−PH(q0 + γx− s1 + ϵ2|H)yO(θL)

]≥ 0, and ∂E[u∗]

∂α=

12JHL

[(q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2)

2y2A(θH)−PH(q0+ γx− s1+ ϵ2|H)2y2O(θL)

]≥ 0. Therefore, for all

scenarios, we have ∂E[u∗]∂s1

≤ 0, ∂E[u∗]∂x

≥ 0 and ∂E[u∗]∂α

≥ 0. Q.E.D.

Page 50: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec4 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Proof of Lemma 4. The buyer’s total expected surplus v(s1, x) (Equation (17)) depends

on the renegotiation scenario (i.e., N , O, H, or A) induced by her decisions. Therefore, we

analyze the buyer’s local optimal solution under each scenario (N , O, H, and A) and then

obtain the global optimal solution by comparing the local optimal solutions. Under each

scenario, we focus on the jointly concave v(s1, x) by applying the second-order conditions

(SOCs) determined by a negative definite Hessian Matrix, and then obtain the local optimal

solution by applying the Karush-Kuhn-Tucker (KKT) conditions.

Before analyses by scenarios, it is convenient to define some notations for future usage.

Under scenario k ∈ {N ,O,H,A}, let (s∗1k, x∗k) be the interior optimal solution of the buyer’s

initial scope and upfront investment, (sB1k, xBk ) (or (s

B11k , x

B1k ) and (sB2

1k , xB2k )) be the corre-

sponding boundary solution(s), and v∗k = v(s∗1k, x∗k) and vBk = v(sB1k, x

Bk ) be the corresponding

maximized expected buyer profit. For j ∈ {1,2,2|H}, denote qj = q0 + ϵj and wj(s1, x) =

q0+ γx− s1+ ϵj (or wj for short). For k=N , denote γk = 1; for k ∈ {O,H,A}, denote

Yk =Eθ(1)

[yk(θ(1))

], (EC.3)

Tk = (1−α)Eθ(1)

[y2k(θ(1))Pk(θ(1))

]+αEθ(2)

[yk(θ(2))Pk(θ(2))

], (EC.4)

γk =

√2Yk −Tk − 1

Y 2k −Tk

∈ (0,1), (EC.5)

where yA(θ) = yA(θ), PA(θ) = 1, yO(θ) = yO(θ), and PO(θ) = PH for θ ∈ {θH , θL}; yH(θ) =

yA(θ) and PH(θ) = 1 if θ= θH , and yH(θ) = yO(θ) and PH(θ) = PH if θ= θL.

Below we analyze the buyer’s local optimal solution under each scenario (N , O, H, A).

(i) When w2|H(s1, x)∈ (−∞,0) (scenario N ), the buyer’s expected profit (Equation (17))

becomes

vN (s1, x) = (γx+ q1)s1−1

2x2− 1

2s21−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

](EC.6)

s.t. w2|H(s1, x)< 0, s1 ≥ 0, x≥ 0.

Page 51: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec5

Examining the Hessian Matrix yields that vN (s1, x) is jointly concave in (s1, x) if 1−γ2 > 0

(ensured by Assumption 2a). Then solving the corresponding KKT conditions yields the

buyer’s optimal decision results as follows:

If q2|H < q1 :

s∗1N =q1

1− γ2

x∗N =

γq11− γ2

v∗N =q21

2 (1− γ2)−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]w2|H(s

∗1N , x∗

N ) =−(q1− q2|H)< 0

If q2|H ≥ q1 :

sB1N =q1

1− γ2+(q2|H − q1

)xBN =

γq11− γ2

vBN =q21

2 (1− γ2)−

(q2|H − q1)2

2−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]w2|H(s

B1N , xB

N ) = 0

(ii) When w2|H(s1, x)∈ [0,QH) (scenario O), the buyer’s expected profit (Equation (17))

becomes:

vO(s1, x) = (w2|HYO + q1 − q2|H)s1 +1

2TOw

22|H − x2

2+

s212−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

], (EC.7)

s.t. 0≤w2|H(s1, x)<QH , s1 ≥ 0, x≥ 0.

Examining the Hessian Matrix of vO(s1, x) yields the SOC γ < γO, which is ensured by

Assumption 2a. Then, the following optimal decision results can be obtained by solving

the KKT conditions:

if q0 <QO1 ≡(1− γ2YO)

(q1− q2|H

)YO − 1

− ϵ2|H :

Page 52: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec6 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

sB11O =

q11− γ2

+(q2|H − q1

)xB1O =

γq11− γ2

vB1O =

q212 (1− γ2)

−(q2|H − q1

)22

−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]w2|H(s

B11O, x

B1O ) = 0

if QO1 ≤ q0 ≤QO2 ≡QH [2YO −TO − 1− γ2 (Y 2

O −TO)]

YO − 1+QO1 :

s∗1O =q2|H (YO −TO)+ (1− γ2TO)

(q1− q2|H

)2YO −TO − 1− γ2 (Y 2

O −TO)

x∗O =

γ[(Y 2

O −TO) q2|H +(YO −TO)(q1− q2|H

)]2YO −TO − 1− γ2 (Y 2

O −TO)

v∗O =

[YOq2|H +

(q1 − q2|H

)]2 −TO

[q21 − (1− γ2)

(q1 − q2|H

)2]2 [2YO −TO − 1− γ2 (Y 2

O −TO)]−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]0≤w2|H(s

∗1O, x

∗O) =

(YO − 1) q2|H − (1− γ2YO)(q1− q2|H

)2YO −TO − 1− γ2 (Y 2

O −TO)≤QH

if q0 >QO2 :

sB21O =

q2|H − (1− γ2YO)QH + γ2(q1 − q2|H

)1− γ2

xB2O =

γ[q2|H − (1−YO)QH +

(q1− q2|H

)]1− γ2

vB2O =

[q1+(YO − 1)QH ]2 +(1− γ2)TOQ

2H − (1− γ2)

(YOQH + q1 − q2|H

)22 (1− γ2)

−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]w2|H(s

B21O, x

B2O ) =QH

(iii) When w2|H(s1, x) ∈ [QH ,QL) (scenario H), the buyer’s expected profit (Equation

(17)) becomes:

vH(s1, x) =(w2YHA+w2|HYHO + qH

)s1+

1

2THAw

22 +

1

2THOw

22|H − 1

2x2 +

1

2s21

−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]+

1

2PHPL [JHH +(1−α)JHL]

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2(EC.8)

s.t. QH ≤w2|H(s1, x)<QL, s1 ≥ 0, x≥ 0,

where qH = q1 − (JHH + JHL)q2 − JLLq2|H ,

Page 53: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec7

YHA = (JHH + JHL)yA(θH),

YHO = JLLyO(θL),

THA = αJHHyA(θH)+ (1−α) (JHH + JHL)y2A(θH),

THO = α (JHL + JLL)PHyO(θL)+ (1−α)JLLPHy2O(θL).

One can verify that YH = YHA+YHO and YH = THA+THO. Examining the Hessian Matrix

of vH(s1, x) yields the SOC γ < γH, which is ensured by Assumption 2a. Then, the following

optimal decision results can be obtained by solving the KKT conditions:

if q0 <QH1 ≡[2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)]QH

YH − 1− ϵ2|H

+[(1− γ2)THA− (1− γ2YH) (YHA+ JLL)]

(q2|H − q2

)− (1− γ2YH) (q2− q1)

YH − 1:

sB11H =

(1− γ2YHA) q2|H + γ2YHAq2− (1− γ2YH)QH + γ2qH1− γ2

xB1H =

γ[(1−YHA) q2|H +YHAq2 − (1−YH)QH + qH

]1− γ2

vB1H =

1

2

{(q2− q2|H +QH

)2THA +THOQ

2H −

[YHA

(q2− q2|H

)+YHQH + qH

]2}+

1

2(1− γ2)

[q2|H +YHA

(q2 − q2|H

)+(YH − 1)QH + qH

]2+

1

2PHPL [JHH +(1−α)JHL]

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2 −Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]w2|H

(sB11H, x

B1H)=QH

if QH1 ≤ q0 ≤QH2 =QH1+[2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)] (QL −QH)

YH − 1:

s∗1H =(YHA−THA) q2+(YHO −THO) q2|H + γ2 (YHATHO −YHOTHA)

(q2|H − q2

)+(1− γ2TH) qH

2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2H −TH)

x∗H =

γ [THA (YHO − 1)+YHA (YH −THO)] q22YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)

+γ [THO (YHA− 1)+YHO (YH −THA)] q2|H + γ (YH −TH) qH

2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2H −TH)

v∗H =

(YHAq2+YHOq2|H + qH

)2+2

(q2 − q2|H

) (YHOTHAq2−YHATHOq2|H

)2 [2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)]−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]

Page 54: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec8 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

+THq

2H − (1− γ2)THATHO

(q2− q2|H

)22 [2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)]−

THO

{γ2

[YHA

(q2− q2|H

)+ qH

]2+(q2|H + qH

)2}2 [2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)]

−THA

{γ2

[YHO

(q2|H − q2

)+ qH

]2+(q2 + qH)

2}

2 [2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2H −TH)]

+1

2PHPL [JHH +(1−α)JHL]

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2QH ≤w (s∗1H, x

∗H) =

(YH − 1) q2|H − (1− γ2)(q2|H − q2

)THA

2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2H −TH)

+(1− γ2YH)

[(q2|H − q2

)(YHA + JLL)+ (q2 − q1)

]2YH −TH − 1− γ2 (Y 2

H −TH)≤QL

if q0 >QH2 : the results are similar to the case of q0 <QH1, just by replacing QH with QL.

(iv) When w2|H(s1, x)∈ [QL,∞) (scenario A), the buyer’s expected profit (Equation (17))

becomes:

vA(s1, x) = (w2YA+ q1− q2)s1+1

2TAw

22 −

1

2x2+

1

2s21 −Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]+

1

2PHPL

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2,

(EC.9)

s.t. w2|H(s1, x)≥QL, s1 ≥ 0, x≥ 0.

Examining the Hessian Matrix of vA(s1, x) yields the SOC γ < γA, which is ensured by

Assumption 2a. Then, the following optimal decision results can be obtained by solving

the KKT conditions:

if q0 <QA =[2YA−TA− 1− γ2 (Y 2

A −TA)]QL

YA− 1− ϵ2|H

+[(1− γ2)TA− (1− γ2YA)YA]

(q2|H − q2

)− (1− γ2YA) (q2− q1)

YA− 1:

sB1A =(1− γ2YA)

(q2|H −QL

)+ γ2 [q1 +(YA− 1) q2]

1− γ2

xBA =

γ[(YA− 1)

(q2 − q2|H +QL

)+ q1

]1− γ2

vBA =1

2

{(q2 − q2|H +QL

)2TA−

[(q2 − q2|H +QL

)YA+ q1 − q2

]2}+

1

2(1− γ2)

[q1 +

(q2 − q2|H +QL

)(YA− 1)

]2 −Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]+

1

2PHPL

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2

Page 55: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec9

w(sB1A, x

BA)=QL

if q0 ≥QA :

s∗1A =(YA−TA) q2 +(1− γ2TA) (q1 − q2)

2YA−TA− 1− γ2 (Y 2A −TA)

x∗A =

γ [(Y 2A −TA) q2 +(YA−TA) (q1− q2)]

2YA−TA− 1− γ2 (Y 2A −TA)

v∗A =[q1 +(YA− 1) q2]

2+TA[(1− γ2) (q1 − q2)

2− q21]

2 [2YA−TA− 1− γ2 (Y 2A −TA)]

−Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

]+

1

2PHPL

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2w (s∗1A, x

∗A) =

(YA− 1) q2|H − (1− γ2)(q2|H − q2

)TA+(1− γ2YA)

[(q2|H − q2

)YA+ q2 − q1

]2YA−TA− 1− γ2 (Y 2

A −TA)≥QL

Below we explore the buyer’s global optimal decision result by comparing the local

optimal solutions analyzed above. It can be verified that the following relationships between

the boundary solutions of two adjacent scenarios hold:

vBN = vB1O , vB2

O = vB1H , vB2

H = vBA. (EC.10)

One can also verify that the following relationships between the interior solution and

boundary solution(s) of each scenario hold:

Scenario N : v∗N = vBN +(q2|H − q1)

2

2(EC.11)

Scenario O: v∗O = vB1O +

Λ2O(q0 −QO1)

2

2(1− γ2)(EC.12)

= vB2O +

Λ2O(q0−QO2)

2

2(1− γ2)(EC.13)

Scenario H: v∗H = vB1H +

Λ2H(q0−QH1)

2

2(1− γ2)(EC.14)

= vB2H +

Λ2H(q0−QH2)

2

2(1− γ2)(EC.15)

Scenario A: v∗A = vBA +Λ2

A(q0 −QA)2

2(1− γ2)(EC.16)

where Λk =Yk − 1√

2Yk −Tk − 1− γ2 (Y 2k −Tk)

, k ∈ {O,H,A} (EC.17)

Page 56: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec10 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

In general, it can be complicated and trivial to conduct a complete comparison across

all the scenarios under all possible situations, since the relationships among the critical

points of the scenarios (i.e., QO1, QO2, QH1, QH2 and QA) are largely undetermined (except

QO1 <QO2 and QH1 <QH2). We focus on situations where only interior solutions can be

globally optimal. To this end, we assume QH1 ≤ QO2 (Assumption 2b) and QA ≤ QH2

(Assumption 2c), which eliminates the global optimality of any boundary solutions. Let

Qk1k2 , k1, k2 ∈ {N ,O,H,A}, k1 = k2 be the threshold of q0 at which the buyer is indifferent

between the interior solutions of scenarios k1 and k2 (i.e., v∗k1 = v∗k2 holds for q0 =Qk1k2).

Then the buyer’s global optimal decision results can be expressed as follows:

(s∗1, x∗, v∗) =

(s∗1N , x∗N , v∗N ) if q0 ∈ (0,Q1]

(s∗1O, x∗O, v

∗O) if q0 ∈ (Q1,Q2]

(s∗1H, x∗H, v

∗H) if q0 ∈ (Q2,Q3]

(s∗1A, x∗A, v

∗A) if q0 ∈ (Q3,∞)

where the “Q”’s are thresholds for the baseline quality q0 (Q1 ≤ Q2 ≤ Q3), and their

formulas are determined as follows (see Figure EC.1):

• If (a) QNO <QOH <QHA, then Q1 =QNO, Q2 =QOH, and Q3 =QHA;

• If (b) QNO < QHA ≤ QOH or (e1) QHA ≤ QNO < QOA < QOH, then Q1 = QNO and

Q2 =Q3 =QOA ∈ (QHA,QOH);

• If (c) QOH ≤QNO <QHA or (d1) QOH <QNH <QHA ≤QNO, then Q1 =Q2 =QNH ∈

(QOH,QNO) and Q3 =QHA;

• If (d2) QOH <QHA ≤QNH ≤QNO or (e2) QHA ≤QOA ≤QNO <QOH or (f) QHA <

QOH <QNO, then Q1 =Q2 =Q3 =QNA .

Q.E.D.

Page 57: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec11

Figure EC.1 The buyer’s global optimal solution under different conditions

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOH QHA QH2QAQO2QH10

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOHQHA QH2QA QO2QH10 QOA

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOHQHA QH2QA QO2QH10 QNA

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOHQHA QH2QA QO2QH10 QNAQOA

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOHQHA QH2QH1 QO2QA0 QOA

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOH QNH QHA QH2QAQO2QH10

QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOH QNH QH2QA QO2QH10 QHA QO1

N

O

vHB1

vOB1 vO

B2

vAB vA

*

vA*

vO*

vN*

vHB2

H

AQNO

q0

q0

q0

q0

QOH QNH QH2QA QO2QH10 QHA QNA

(a) QNO < QOH < QHA (b) QNO < QHA ≤ QOH

(c) QOH ≤ QNO < QHA (f) QHA ≤ QOH ≤ QNO

(d1) QOH < QNH < QHA ≤ QNO (d2) QOH < QHA ≤ QNH ≤ QNO

(e1) QHA ≤ QNO < QOA < QOH (e2) QHA ≤ QOA ≤ QNO < QOH

Proof of Proposition 3. The strategic relationship between s1 and m is examined by

evaluating the sign of ∂2v∂s1∂x

and ∂2v∂x∂s1

. For scenario N , it follows from Equation (EC.6)

that ∂2vN∂s1∂x

= ∂2vN∂x∂s1

= γ > 0, which implies that s1 and x are complements. For scenario

k ∈ {O,H,A}, it can be derived from Equation (EC.7), (EC.8), or (EC.9) that

∂2vk∂s1∂x

= ∂2vk∂x∂s1

= γ(Yk −Tk), indicating that s1 and x are complements if Yk >Tk and substi-

tutes if Yk <Tk. Q.E.D.

Page 58: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec12 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

EC.2. Proofs of Results in Extension 5.1

Proof of Lemma 5. Given s1 and x, the buyer’s expected profit with a reserve price r is

given by

v(s1, x, r) =Eθ(1),θ(2),ϵ1

[q1(θ(1))s1 −

1

2x2 −min{r, c(θ(2);s1, x)}

+1

2(1−α)s22(θ(1))

∣∣∣∣ r≥ c(θ(1);s1, x)

]Pr

{r≥ c(θ(1);s1, x)

}(EC.18)

where q1(θ(1)) = q0+ γx+ θ(1)z∗(θ(1))+ ϵ1 and s2(θ(1)) =

(q0 + γx− s1 + θ(1)ν

∗(θ(1))+ ϵ2|1)+

.

Note that in a second-price auction, bidders always bid truthfully in equilibrium regardless

of the reserve price (Krishna 2009). Therefore, setting a reserve price r ≥ c(θL;s1, x) is

identical to not using a reserve price, and setting r < c(θH ;s1, x) yields no positive expected

profit to the buyer. Thus, we focus on the cases of c (θH ;s1, x) ≤ r ≤ c (θL;s1, x), where

r = c (θL;s1, x) is referred to as a degenerate reserve price (equivalent to the “no-reserve-

price” case) and r ∈ [c (θH ;s1, x) , c (θL;s1, x)) is referred to as a nondegenerate reserve

price.

When the buyer adopts a nondegenerate reserve price r ∈ [c (θH ;s1, x) , c (θL;s1, x)), Equa-

tion (EC.18) can be rewritten as

v(s1, x, r) = (JHH + JHL)

[q1(θH)s1 −

x2

2+

(1−α)s22(θH)

2

]− [JHLr+ JHHc (θH ;s1, x)]

(EC.19)

which is a decreasing function of r. Therefore, the optimal nondegenerate reserve price

should be r = c(θH ;s1, x). Substituting r = c(θH ;s1, x) into Equation (EC.19), we obtain

that the buyer’s expected profit under the optimal nondegenerate reserve price is given by

v(s1, x, c(θH ;s1, x)) = (1− JLL)

[q1(θH)s1−

x2

2+

(1−α)s22(θH)

2− c (θH ;s1, x)

](EC.20)

Page 59: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec13

Denote (s∗1, x∗) = argmaxs1,x v (s1, x, c (θH ;s1, x)) and v∗ ≡ v (s∗1, x

∗, c (θH ; s∗1, x

∗)). Then the

optimal reserve price is r∗ = c (θH ; s∗1, x

∗) (nondegenerate) if v∗ > v∗, and r∗ = c (θL;s∗1, x

∗)

(degenerate) otherwise.

Similar to the Proof of Lemma 4, below we derive the buyer’s optimal initial scope s∗1 and

optimal upfront investment x∗ under the nondegenerate reserve price by three renegotiation

scenarios (N , O, A). The hybrid scenario H where L-type andH-type vendors face different

renegotiate scenarios is combined into scenario A, since it leads to the same results as

the always-renegotiate scenario due to the fact that all L-type vendors are excluded by

the nondegenerate reserve price. Therefore, the combined always-renegotiate scenario A

represents situations where w2|H(s1, x)∈ [QH ,∞).

(i) When w2|H(s1, x) ∈ (−∞,0) (scenario N ), we have z∗(θH) = 0 and c(θH ;s1, x) =

cF (θH)+12s21, and thus Equation (EC.20) can be rewritten as

vN (s1, x, c(θH ;s1, x)) = (1− JLL)

[(γx+ q1)s1 −

1

2x2− 1

2s21− cF (θH)

](EC.21)

Comparing Equations (EC.21) and (EC.6), one obtains that scenario N has the same local

optimal solution with the scenario N of the main model.

(ii) When w2|H(s1, x) ∈ [0,QH) (scenario O), we have z∗(θH) = αθHPHyO(θH)w2|H and

c(θH ;s1, x) = cF (θH)+12s21 − 1

2αPHyO(θH)w

22|H , and thus Equation (EC.20) is rewritten as

vO(s1, x, c(θH ;s1, x)) =(1− JLL)

[(w2|HYO + q1− q2|H

)s1+

TOw22|H −x2+ s21

2− cF (θH)

](EC.22)

where YO = yO(θH) and TO = (1 − α)y2O(θH)PH + αyO(θH)PH . Note thatvO(s1,x,c(θH ;s1,x))

1−JLL

is identical to Equation (EC.7) if(YO, TO,Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

])in Equation (EC.7) is replaced

with (YO, TO, cF (θH)). Therefore, the buyer’s local optimal decision results under scenario

O can be obtained accordingly.

Page 60: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec14 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

(iii) When w2|H(s1, x) ∈ [QH ,∞) (scenario A), we have z∗(θH) = αθHyA(θH)w2 and

c(θH ;s1, x) = cF (θH) + 12s21 − 1

2α[yA(θH)w

22 +PHPL

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2], and thus Equation

(EC.20) is rewritten as

vA(s1, x, c(θH ;s1, x)) =(1− JLL) [(w2YA+ q1 − q2)s1 − cF (θH)]

+1

2(1− JLL)

[TAw

22 −x2 + s21 +PHPL

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2](EC.23)

where YA = yA(θH) and TA = (1−α)y2A(θH) +αyA(θH). Note thatvA(s1,x,c(θH ;s1,x))

1−JLLis iden-

tical to Equation (EC.9) if(YA, TA,Eθ(2)

[cF (θ(2))

])in Equation (EC.7) is replaced with

(YA, TA, cF (θH)). Therefore, the buyer’s local optimal decision results under scenario A can

be obtained accordingly.

Based on the above analyses and the results of the Proof of Lemma 4, the buyer’s optimal

decision results under a nondegenerate reserve price is shown as

(s∗1, x∗, v∗) =

(s∗1N , x∗

N , v∗N

)if q0 ∈ (0, Q1](

s∗1O, x

∗O, v

∗O

)if q0 ∈ (Q1, Q2](

s∗1A, x

∗A, v

∗A

)if q0 ∈ (Q2,∞)

where s∗1N =

q11− γ2

x∗N =

γq11− γ2

v∗N = (1− JLL)

[q21

2 (1− γ2)− cF (θH)

]s∗1O =

q2|H (YO −TO)+ (1− γ2TO)(q1− q2|H

)2YO −TO − 1− γ2

(Y 2O −TO

)x∗O =

γ[(

Y 2O −TO

)q2|H +(YO −TO)

(q1 − q2|H

)]2YO −TO − 1− γ2

(Y 2O −TO

)v∗O = (1− JLL)

[YOq2|H +

(q1− q2|H

)]2 −TO

[q21 − (1− γ2)

(q1− q2|H

)2]2[2YO −TO − 1− γ2

(Y 2O −TO

)] − cF (θH)

Page 61: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec15

s∗1A =

(YA−TA) q2 +(1− γ2TA) (q1 − q2)

2YA −TA− 1− γ2(Y 2A −TA

)x∗A =

γ[(

Y 2A −TA

)q2+(YA−TA) (q1− q2)

]2YA−TA− 1− γ2

(Y 2A −TA

)

v∗A = (1− JLL)

[q1+(YA− 1) q2]2 +TA

[(1− γ2) (q1− q2)

2 − q21]

2[2YA−TA− 1− γ2

(Y 2A −TA

)] − cF (θH)+1

2PHPL

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)2and Q1 and Q2 (Q1 ≤ Q2) are determined as follows:

• If QN O <QOA, then Q1 =QN O and Q2 =QOA;

• If QN O ≥QOA, then Q1 = Q2 =QN A ∈ (QOA,QN O), where

QN O =QO1+(q1 − q2|H)

+√

1− γ2

ΛO

QOA =QO2ΛO +QAΛA

ΛO +ΛA∈ (QA,QO2)

Λk =Yk − 1√

2Yk −Tk − 1− γ2 (Y 2k −Tk)

, k ∈ {O, A}

QO1 =(1− γ2YO)

(q1 − q2|H

)YO − 1

− ϵ2|H

QO2 =QO1+QH

[2YO −TO − 1− γ2

(Y 2O −TO

)]YO − 1

QA =

[2YA−TA− 1− γ2

(Y 2A −TA

)]QH

YA− 1− ϵ2|H

+[(1− γ2)TA− (1− γ2YA)YA]

(q2|H − q2

)− (1− γ2YA) (q2− q1)

YA− 1

Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 4. For scenario N , it follows from Equation (EC.21) that∂2vN∂s1∂x

=

∂2vN∂x∂s1

= (1−JLL)γ > 0, indicating that s1 and x are complements. For scenario O, it follows

from Equation (EC.22) that∂2vO∂s1∂x

=∂2vO∂x∂s1

= γ (1− JLL) (YO −TO). Therefore, s1 and x are

complements if YO >TO and substitutes if YO <TO. Note that YO >TO is equivalent to

PH < P ≡(1+αθ2H)−

√(1+αθ2H)

2 − 4α2θ2H

2α2θ2H∈ (0,1). (EC.24)

Page 62: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec16 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

For scenario A, it follows from Equation (EC.23) that∂2vA∂s1∂x

=∂2vA∂x∂s1

=

γ (1− JLL) (YA−TA) = γ (1− JLL) (1−α)yA(θH) [1− yA(θH)]< 0. Therefore, s1 and x are

substitutes. Q.E.D.

EC.3. Proofs of Results in Extension 5.2

Lemma 1 (revisit). At phase 2, the two parties renegotiate if and only if µ+γx+θz > s1.

If the renegotiation occurs, the additional scope, payment, and renegotiation surplus in

phase 2 are:

s2 =µ+ γx+ θz− s1

1− (ϵH − ϵL)ai (s1)(EC.25)

p2 =1

2s2 {2s1+ [1+α−α (ϵH − ϵL)ai(s1)]s2} (EC.26)

S =1

2[1− (ϵH − ϵL)ai(s1)]s

22 (EC.27)

where µ= q0 + (ϵH + ϵL)/2;

i=H if ϵ1 = ϵH , i=L if ϵ1 = ϵL; (EC.28)

aH (s1) =[ds1+(2λ− 1)]d

(2λ− 1)ds1 +1; (EC.29)

aL (s1) =[ds1− (2λ− 1)]d

(2λ− 1)ds1 − 1. (EC.30)

Proof of Lemma 1 (revisit). When ρt =12(dst +1), t ∈ {1,2}, one can verify that:

PH = 12[1+ (2λ− 1)ds1], PH|H = 1

2[1+ aH(s1)s2], and PL|L = 1

2[1− aL(s1)s2], where aH(s1)

and aL(s1) are as given by Equations (EC.29) and (EC.30), respectively. It follows that:

ϵ2|H = ϵL +(ϵH − ϵL)PH|H =1

2(ϵH + ϵL)+

1

2(ϵH − ϵL)aH(s1)s2

ϵ2|L = ϵL +(ϵH − ϵL)(1−PL|L

)=

1

2(ϵH + ϵL)+

1

2(ϵH − ϵL)aL(s1)s2

which can be expressed jointly as

ϵ2|1 =1

2(ϵH + ϵL)+

1

2(ϵH − ϵL)ai(s1)s2, i=H if ϵ1 = ϵH , i=L if ϵ1 = ϵL. (EC.31)

Page 63: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec17

Substituting Equation (EC.31) into Equation (6), one obtains

v2 (s2, p2) = (µ+ γx+ θz)s2 +1

2(ϵH − ϵL)ai(s1)s

22− p2, i=H if ϵ1 = ϵH , i=L if ϵ1 = ϵL

where µ = q0 + (ϵH + ϵL)/2. Then applying similar analysis to the Proof of Lemma 1 of

the main model, we obtain Equations (EC.25), (EC.26), and (EC.27). Q.E.D.

Before revisiting Lemma 2, we first define some notations and make some useful assump-

tions. Denote ϕ (s1) =Eϵ1

{[1− (ϵH − ϵL)ai (s1)]

−1}, which is equivalent to

ϕ (s1) =A+ B/(D− s21

)where A = 1 − g[g+(1−2λ)3]

(g+1−2λ)2, B = −16[(2λ−1)g−1]λ2(1−λ)2(ϵH−ϵL)

2

(2λ−1−g)4, D = [(2λ−1)g−1]2

(2λ−1−g)2d2> 0, and g =

(ϵH − ϵL)d. The following assumptions are made to the above notations.

Assumption EC.1. a. (2λ− 1)g− 1< 0;

b. 0≤ s1 <√D;

c. 1−αθ2ϕ (s1)> 0.

In the above, Assumption EC.1a sets an upper bound to the learning coefficient d when

λ> 12. It ensures B > 0, so that ϕ (s1) is increasing in s1. Thus, increasing the phase-1 scope

s1 indeed has the merit of uncovering more information about the quality state, as reflected

in the subsequent Equation (EC.33) where ϕ (s1) serves as a multiplier in the vendor’s

share of expected renegotiation surplus. Assumption EC.1b sets an upper bound to the

phase-1 scope s1 such that the model makes sense. Assumptions EC.1a and EC.1b together

also imply that ϕ (s1)≥ ϕ (0) =A+ B/D= 11−(2λ−1)g

> 0. Assumption EC.1c ensures that

the vendor’s objective function is concave in his upfront investment z. Under the above

assumptions, we revisit Lemma 2.

Lemma 2 (revisit). The winning vendor’s optimal upfront investment is

z∗(θ) =αθϕ (s1) (µ+ γx− s1)

+

1−αθ2ϕ (s1)(EC.32)

Page 64: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec18 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Proof of Lemma 2 (revisit). With Lemma 1 (revisit), the vendor’s total expected profit

can be expressed as the phase-1 expected profit u1 (Equation (11)) plus a share α of the

expected renegotiation surplus Eϵ1 [S] (determined by Equation (EC.27)):

u(z;θ, p1) = u1 +αEϵ1 [S]

= p1 − cF (θ)−1

2s21−

1

2z2+

1

2αϕ (s1)

[(µ+ γx+ θz− s1)

+]2

(EC.33)

Under Assumption EC.1c, we have ∂2u∂z2

=−1+αθ2ϕ (s1)1µ+γx+θz−s1>0 < 0, indicating that

u(z;θ, p1) is concave in z. Therefore, the optimal z can be determined by ∂u∂z

= −z +

αθϕ (s1) (µ+ γx+ θz− s1)+ = 0, which yields Equation (EC.32). Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 1. Since z∗(θ) = 0 when µ+ γx− s1 ≤ 0, we concentrate on the

case of µ+ γx− s1 > 0. When µ+ γx− s1 > 0, it is easy to obtain ∂z∗

∂x= αθγϕ(s1)

1−αθ2ϕ(s1)> 0 and

∂z∗

∂α= θϕ(s1)(µ+γx−s1)

[1−αθ2ϕ(s1)]2 > 0. Therefore, the winning vendor’s optimal upfront investment z∗(θ)

increases in the buyer’s upfront investment x and the vendor’s bargaining power α. As for

the impact of the initial scope s1, we have ∂z∗

∂s1= αθ∆1(s1)

[1−αθ2ϕ(s1)]2(D−s21)

2 , where

∆1(s1)≡∆2(s1)−(D− s21

)2ϕ (s1)

[1−αθ2ϕ (s1)

], (EC.34)

∆2(s1)≡ 2Bs1 (µ+ γx− s1) .

One can obtain that

∂∆1

∂s1= 2B (µ+ γx− s1)+ 4As1

(D− s21

) [1−αθ2ϕ (s1)

]Under Assumption EC.1 and A≥ 0, ∂∆1

∂s1> 0 holds for µ+ γx− s1 > 0. Therefore,

∆1(s1)<∆1(µ+ γx)<∆2(µ+ γx) = 0, (EC.35)

and thus ∂z∗

∂s1< 0 holds for µ+ γx− s1 > 0. Q.E.D.

Page 65: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec19

Proof of Lemma 3. Similar to the corresponding proof of the main model, just by

replacing c(θi) of the main model with c(θi) =12s21+ cF (θ)−

αϕ(s1)[(µ+γx−s1)+]2

2[1−αθ2ϕ(s1)]. Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 2. The information rent in this extension is written as

Rent=E[u∗(θ(1), c(θ(2)))] = JHL

{cF (θL)− cF (θH)+

1

2αϕ (s1)

(Υ+

)2[m(θH)−m(θL)]

}

where m(θ) = [1−αθ2ϕ (s1)]−1

and Υ= µ+γx−s1. Clearly, we have∂Rent∂x

≥ 0 and ∂Rent∂α

0. As for ∂Rent∂s1

, when we have

∂Rent

∂s1=

αΥ+JHL [m(θH)−m(θL)]m(θH)

(D− s21)2

{ΥBs1

[1+

m(θL)

m(θH)

]− (D− s21)

2ϕ (s1)

m(θH)

}

<αΥ+JHL [m(θH)−m(θL)]m(θH)

(D− s21)2

{2ΥBs1 −

(D− s21

)2ϕ (s1)

[1−αθ2Hϕ (s1)

]}=

αΥ+JHL [m(θH)−m(θL)]m(θH)

(D− s21)2 ∆1(s1)|θ=θH

where ∆1(s1) is given in Equation (EC.34). We have proved in Equation (EC.35) that

under Assumption EC.1 and A≥ 0, ∆1(s1)< 0 holds whenever µ+γx− s1 > 0. Therefore,

∂Rent∂s1

≤ 0, which concludes the proof. Q.E.D.

EC.4. Proofs of Results in Extension 5.3

Lemma 1 (revisit 2). At phase 2, the two parties renegotiate if and only if s1 <

(1+ bm)(e0 + θν+ ϵ2|1

). If the renegotiation occurs, the additional scope, payment, and

renegotiation surplus in phase 2 are:

s2 =[(1+ γx)

(q0+ θz+ ϵ2|1

)− s1

]+(EC.36)

p2 =s2 [2s1+(1+α)s2]

2(1+ γx)(EC.37)

S =s22

2(1+ γx)(EC.38)

Page 66: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

ec20 e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

Proof of Lemma 1 (revisit 2). Replacing v2 and u2 in the main model with v2 =(q0+ θz+ ϵ2|1

)s2−p2 and u2 = p2− 1

2(1+γx)[(s1 + s2)

2 − s21], the above lemma can be proved

by a similar process to the Proof of Lemma 1 in the main model. Q.E.D.

Lemma 2 (revisit 2). Assume 1−αθ2(1+γx)> 0. The winning vendor’s optimal upfront

investment is

z∗ (θ) =

0 (N c)

αθPH

[(1+ γx)

(q0 + ϵ2|H

)− s1

]ycO(θ) (Oc)

αθ [(1+ γx) (q0+ ϵ2)− s1]ycA(θ) (Ac)

(EC.39)

where ycO(θ) = [1−αθ2PH (1+ γx)]−1, ycA(θ) = [1−αθ2 (1+ γx)]

−1, and the conditions

(N c), (Oc), and (Ac) are given by

(N c): q0 + ϵ2|H − s1/ (1+ γx)∈ (−∞,0)

(Oc): q0 + ϵ2|H − s1/ (1+ γx)∈[0,

(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)/ycO(θ)

)(Ac): q0 + ϵ2|H − s1/ (1+ γx)∈

[(ϵ2|H − ϵ2|L

)/ycO(θ),∞

)Proof of Lemma 2 (revisit 2). With Lemma 1 (revisit 2), the vendor’s total expected

profit can be expressed as the phase-1 expected profit u1 = p1− cF (θ)− 12(1+γx)

s21− 12z2 plus

a share α of the expected renegotiation surplus Eϵ1 [S] (determined by Equation (EC.38)):

u(z;θ, p1) = u1 +αEϵ1 [S]

= p1 − cF (θ)−1

2(1+ γx)s21 −

1

2z2 +

α(1+ γx)

2Eϵ1

[(

q0+ θz+ ϵ2|1−s1

1+ γx

)+]2

Then the lemma can be proved by a similar process to the Proof of Lemma 2 in the main

model. Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 1. It is easy to verify that ∂z∗

∂x≥ 0, ∂z∗

∂α≥ 0, and ∂z∗

∂s1≤ 0. Q.E.D.

Page 67: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope

e-companion to Author: Auctioning IT Contracts with Renegotiable Scope ec21

Proof of Lemma 3. Similar to the corresponding Proof of Lemma 3 in the main model,

just by replacing c(θi) of the main model with

c(θi) = cF (θ)+s21

2(1+ γx)−

0 (N c)

αPH [(1+γx)q2|H−s1]2ycO(θ)

2(1+γx)(Oc){

α[(1+γx)q2−s1]2ycA(θ)

2(1+γx)+

αPHPL(1+γx)(ϵ2|H−ϵ2|L)2

2

}(Ac)

Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 2. Similar to the corresponding Proof of Proposition 2 in the main

model. Q.E.D.

References

Krishna V (2009) Auction Theory (Academic press).