AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal...

33
AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF FISCAL DEFICIT IN THE WEST AFRICAN MONETARY ZONE 1 Emmanuel Onwioduokit Abstract Preceding the actualization a monetary union, potential members are usually required to observe certain quantitative and qualitative criteria or benchmarks. These criteria are usually broadly classified into two: economic convergence criteria, and legal criteria. Specifically, the West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ), member countries among other criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). The paper sought to ascertain the nature of relationship between fiscal deficits and economic growth, as well as to establish the fiscal deficit threshold that is consistent with economic growth in the West African Monetary Zone. Empirical evidence indicates a positive relationship with economic growth. Also the threshold level of deficit that is consistent with economic growth in the WAMZ was identified at 5.0 percent. The policy implications and recommendations based on the major findings of this paper is that fiscal deficit criterion in the WAMZ should be maintained at 4.0 per cent since this level falls within the acceptable range of optimal deficit identified in the study. JEL Classification: C2, E1, E2, O4, O5 Keywords: Fiscal Deficit, Economic Growth, Threshold, West African Monetary Zone INTRODUCTION Traditionally, the protocol governing the formation of an economic and monetary union requires member countries to adhere to prudent and consistent macroeconomic policies and structural reforms which should be sustained over time. Prior to actualizing a monetary union, potential members are usually required to observe certain quantitative and qualitative criteria or benchmarks. These criteria are usually broadly classified into two: economic convergence criteria, and legal criteria. The former is centred on three areas, namely monetary, fiscal and structural convergence, while the latter is concerned with the legal framework for monetary integration. In principle, these convergence criteria serve as a tool for providing information; an anchor for expectations and policies; and a mechanism for discipline. The criteria are expected to lend credibility to the monetary integration agenda. 1 Emmanuel Ating Onwioduokit is Deputy Director, West African Monetary Institute, Accra, Ghana. The views expressed in this paper are personal to the author and does not represent the official position of his employer.

Transcript of AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal...

Page 1: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF FISCAL DEFICIT IN THE WEST AFRICAN MONETARY ZONE1

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

Abstract

Preceding the actualization a monetary union, potential members are usually required to observe certain quantitative and qualitative criteria or benchmarks. These criteria are usually broadly classified into two: economic convergence criteria, and legal criteria. Specifically, the West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ), member countries among other criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). The paper sought to ascertain the nature of relationship between fiscal deficits and economic growth, as well as to establish the fiscal deficit threshold that is consistent with economic growth in the West African Monetary Zone. Empirical evidence indicates a positive relationship with economic growth. Also the threshold level of deficit that is consistent with economic growth in the WAMZ was identified at 5.0 percent. The policy implications and recommendations based on the major findings of this paper is that fiscal deficit criterion in the WAMZ should be maintained at 4.0 per cent since this level falls within the acceptable range of optimal deficit identified in the study.

JEL Classification: C2, E1, E2, O4, O5 Keywords: Fiscal Deficit, Economic Growth, Threshold, West African Monetary Zone

INTRODUCTION

Traditionally, the protocol governing the formation of an economic and monetary union requires member countries to adhere to prudent and consistent macroeconomic policies and structural reforms which should be sustained over time. Prior to actualizing a monetary union, potential members are usually required to observe certain quantitative and qualitative criteria or benchmarks. These criteria are usually broadly classified into two: economic convergence criteria, and legal criteria. The former is centred on three areas, namely monetary, fiscal and structural convergence, while the latter is concerned with the legal framework for monetary integration. In principle, these convergence criteria serve as a tool for providing information; an anchor for expectations and policies; and a mechanism for discipline. The criteria are expected to lend credibility to the monetary integration agenda.

1 Emmanuel Ating Onwioduokit is Deputy Director, West African Monetary Institute, Accra,

Ghana. The views expressed in this paper are personal to the author and does not represent the

official position of his employer.

Page 2: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

2

Specifically, the West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ), member countries among other criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for setting a target on fiscal deficits, is the concern that excessive deficit financing would crowd out the private sector and net exports, and that, it would increase government debt to a level where inflationary financing, arrears and eventually default, would become a serious concern. At the practical level, there is the likelihood for potentially unsustainable fiscal deficit behaviour by governments if there are no explicit limits on the level of deficit financing. Furthermore, fiscal deficits limits are explicitly articulated within the context of a monetary union because; individual countries cannot finance their deficits through the issuing of new money. Countries do not hold any other major macroeconomic instrument than the fiscal policy. As a result, they may be tempted to exploit it in a non-sustainable manner, to promote short-run economic growth. If individual countries get to a situation where they can no longer finance the fiscal deficits, then they will have to be bailed-out or abandon the monetary union. In the first scenario, if any country is bailed-out by the central authority, a moral hazard problem emerges, as other countries will lack the incentives to keep their deficits under control. In the second case, if a country exits the monetary union, the common bond market is seriously affected. In this circumstance investors tend to run from public bonds, which lead to budgeting problems in the other countries. The commencement date for the launch of the common monetary union and the issuance of a single currency has been postponed three times (2003, 2005, 2009), with the expected date for the start of the union now fixed for January 1, 2015. The deferments of the commencement date of the Union have always been linked to non compliance of member countries with the stipulated convergence criteria especially the criteria on fiscal deficit-GDP ratio and inflation. A critical perusal of countries’ performance on the convergence scale over the period has shown that the fiscal deficits criterion has been the least fulfilled criterion by member countries (WAMI, 2009). Although the WAMZ convergence process largely mimics that of the European Monetary Union, there is very limited empirical evidence as to where the various bench marks for convergence criteria were derived. The general belief is that the WAMZ Authorities adapted the European Union convergence criteria and made some modifications to fit what was perceived as the peculiar conditions of the Zone (Nana, 2007). Consequently, the various WAMZ ratios and benchmarks have been in contention since the commencement of the process. (See WAMI, 2005). Although the importance of fiscal convergence, before and after the realization of the union is not in dispute, some critiques, including (Nana, 2007 and Balogun, 2007) have argued that the fiscal deficit/GDP ratio, excluding grants of 4.0 percent, the key fiscal convergence

Page 3: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

3

requirement for the WAMZ, is not optimal for growth without any further attempt to state empirically what the threshold should be. This paper seeks to empirically establish the optimal level of fiscal deficit that is consistent with growth in the zone. The remaining part of the paper is organized as follows: Part II contains a brief overview of the WAMZ economies including recent policy thrust. Part III dwells on theoretical and empirical issues. Part IV outlines the analytical framework and empirical methodology. The empirical findings are presented in Part V. Part VI contains summary and policy recommendations.

OVERVIEW OF WAMZ ECONOMIES

The WAMZ covers a total land area of 1.49 million sq kilometres. However, with the exception of Guinea, Liberia and Sierra Leone that have shared national borders, the other countries are not geographically contiguous. The Zone is heterogeneous in terms of GDP and population. Although, the economies are relatively open, the export sector is largely dominated by limited commodities. The Zone has a total combined population of about 200 million as at 2010, representing 67.8 percent and 20.2 percent of the population of ECOWAS and Africa, respectively. The Zone’s economy, measured by its combined GDP, totalled $387,846 billion (PPP); 59.4 percent and 22.1 percent of ECOWAS and Sub-Saharan Africa, respectively. The Zone accounted for about 0.5 percent of world GDP in 2010. The average GDP per capita (PPP) was estimated at $1,513.4 in 2010. Nigeria is the dominant economy in the Zone, with about 77.1 percent of the population and 88.0 percent of the zone’s GDP. The composition of the country’s GDP in 2010 indicated: agriculture (33.4 percent), industry (34.1 percent) and services (32.5 percent). Nigeria’s economy is oil-based, with the oil sector contributing about 28.0 percent of GDP, over 80 percent of total revenue, and over 90 percent of foreign exchange earnings. The second largest economy in the zone is Ghana, with 8.0 percent of the zone’s GDP. Guinea and Sierra Leone accounted for 2.0 and 1.0 percent of the Zone GDP, respectively, while The Gambia accounted for 0.98 percent of the Zone’s GDP.

Page 4: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

4

Figure 1: WAMZ GDP by Country Contribution

1%

8%2%

88%

1%

WAMZ GDP (US$)

The Gambia Ghana Guinea Nigeria Sierra Leone

As indicated in figure 1, in 2010, Ghana’s GDP was equivalent to 7.6 percent of Nigeria’s GDP and four times that of Guinea. The Gambia had the lowest GDP (US$779 million). In terms of per capita income, Nigeria is number one in the zone ($2,274) followed by The Gambia ($1,911); Ghana ($1,558); Guinea ($1,042); and Sierra Leone ($782). Thus Nigeria’s per capita GDP was about three times that of Sierra Leone in 2010.

Recent Policy Thrust and Outcome

The main objective of fiscal policy in the WAMZ member countries during the convergence period (2001-2010) was the attainment of fiscal sustainability through broadening of the tax base to enhance tax administration and expenditure control. In The Gambia, the key objective of government was to improve fiscal management, accountability and the rate of budget execution to support macro economic growth. Ghana’s general policy thrust was to correct the fiscal slippage and re-establish the role of fiscal policy in achieving accelerated growth with stability. In Guinea, the objective centered on rationalizing and prioritizing discretionary government expenditures in favour of essential public services while continuing to maintain good relationships with international creditors. Nigeria’s key objective was to prop up macroeconomic stability with fastidious emphasize on provision of critical infrastructure and human capital development, implementing socio-economic reforms while consolidating democracy. Fiscal policy in Sierra Leone was directed at attaining and sustaining macroeconomic stability. In this direction, a battery of measures to improve tax administration and broaden the tax base was pursued.

Page 5: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

5

The overall fiscal deficit to GDP ratio (excluding grants) for the Zone moderated from 4.2 percent in 2001 to 1.3 percent in 2007, but deteriorated to 1.4, 3.8 and 6.2 percent in 2008, 2009 and 2010, respectively. All countries registered deficits, though at varying levels during the period. Tax mobilization efforts, represented by tax revenue/GDP ratio, declined from 14.6 percent in 2001 to 12.0 percent in 2003. The ratio improved steadily to 19.6 percent in 2005, and thereafter dropped to 11.2 percent in 2007. In 2008, 2009 and 2010, respective ratios of 17.0, 12.1 and 12.3 percent were recorded. Overall, the ratio for the Zone fluctuated between 10.7 percent (lowest) in 2002 and 19.6 percent (highest) in 2005. The observed development in the ratio reflected weak revenue performances in most of the member countries. With regards to total expenditure and net lending as a ratio of GDP, the zonal performance showed a mixed trend. From 34.1 percent in 2001, the ratio plummeted to 25.7 percent in the succeeding year and thereafter increased consistently, peaking at 42.6 percent in 2005. The ratio declined gradually to 25.3 percent in 2007. In 2008, 2009 and 2010, respective ratios of 31.8, 22.7 and 28.7 percent were recorded. Overall, the ratio ranged between 22.7 percent (2009) and 42.6 percent (2005).

THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL REVIEW Government borrowing is an important part of fiscal policy and management of aggregate demand. When the government runs a fiscal deficit, it means that in a given year, total government expenditure exceeds total income. The government can borrow to cover the deficit through the issue of government debt such as Treasury Bills and long-term government bonds. The issue of debt involves selling debt in the bond and bill markets. Most of the government debt is bought by financial institutions and individuals. There is a near consensus that a persistently large fiscal deficit can turn out to be a major problem for the government and the economy. Fiscal deficits are generally expected to be growth-retarding, all things being equal. This can arise because total savings are reduced (if the private sector does not fully adjust its savings or government borrowing finances consumption goods provision), consequently reducing factor accumulation. On the other hand, if deficits are perceived as unsustainable, then changes in tax/expenditure policy and/or monetary policy will be anticipated. Either is likely to retard growth via effects on investment from increases in expected inflation or uncertainties associated with possible fiscal policy changes. Even if monetary policy is designed to counteract the inflationary effects of a budget deficit, growth is still likely to be retarded by the associated increases in interest rates (Tanzi and Zee, 1997). At the theoretical level, there are three schools of thought regarding the economic impacts of fiscal deficits: Neoclassical, Keynesian, and Ricardian. The Neoclassical paradigm anticipates perceptive individuals planning consumption over their own life

Page 6: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

6

cycles. Fiscal deficits hoist total lifetime consumption by shifting taxes to succeeding generations. If economic resources are fully employed, increased consumption inevitably implies diminished saving. Interest rates must then increase to equilibrate the capital markets. Accordingly, fiscal deficits "crowd out" private capital accumulation. Within the Keynesian analysis, a considerable proportion of the population is thought of as either narrow-minded or liquidity constrained. The propensities to consume out of current disposable income of these individuals are assumed to be very high. A momentary tax cutback therefore has an instantaneous and quantitatively momentous impact on aggregate demand. If the economy's resources are at the outset underemployed, national income increases, in so doing generating second round effects and the renowned Keynesian multiplier. Given that deficits motivate both consumption and national income, saving and capital accumulation need not be negatively affected. Thus, aptly timed deficits have advantageous consequences on economic growth. In the Ricardian argument, succeeding generations are associated through intentional, selflessly goaded resource transfers. Within definite circumstances, this implies that consumption is determined as a function of dynastic resources, to be precise, the total resources of a taxpayer and all of his descendants. In view of the fact that deficits simply shift the payment of taxes to upcoming generations, the current discounted values of taxes and expenditures must equal, in so doing it leave dynastic resources unaltered. Thus, deficit policy is a matter of indifference. In the last decade, the issue of how best to design monetary unions has attracted huge academic concern. A fundamental question is whether restrictions in the member states’ fiscal policies should be obligated in a monetary union. The key debate regarding need for fiscal restraint in a monetary union centred around whether lack of fiscal discipline is an obstacle to achieving the objective of monetary union (in particular price stability). Also what form of fiscal constraints is appropriate for effective macroeconomic management, which will not interfere with the use of such policies for other legitimate purposes, including, cushioning the impact of shocks. Researchers, who have studied this area, hold remarkably different opinions regarding the influence of monetary union for fiscal discipline. Central to the discussion on the subject is the time inconsistency of optimal monetary and fiscal policy. Time consistency of optimal monetary and fiscal policy has been extensively discussed in the literature on the macroeconomics of public finance. For instance, the seminal work by Calvo (1978) pointed to the ex post incentives of a government to use a surprise inflation to reduce the real value of any outstanding fiat money, when other sources of finance distort economic activity. Lucas and Stokey (1983) extended Calvo’s analysis by showing how similar time-consistency problems arise in a real economy due to the government’s ability to manipulate the market value of indexed debt. In addition, they showed that these problems can be avoided if every government undertakes a unique restructuring scheme

Page 7: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

7

of the maturity (and contingency) of the indexed debt left to its successor, under the assumption that outstanding government debt cannot be subjected to outright default. Lucas and Stokey (1983) also argued that the time-consistency problem is inevitable in a monetary economy, where governments constantly have an ex post incentive to reduce (increase) the real value of net nominal government liabilities (assets) by a surprise inflation, so as to lower distortionary taxes. Tabellini (1986), analyzed the coordination between a single monetary authority and several independent fiscal authorities in a game- type model, showed that policy coordination between the fiscal authorities and the common monetary authority increases the speed of convergence toward the common steady state as compared to the outcome of the non-cooperative game. However, Persson, Persson, and Svensson (1987) suggested that a unique restructuring of both nominal and indexed debt could resolve both types of time-consistency problems. More precisely, they suggested that the first-order conditions for optimal fiscal and monetary policy in a sequence of discretionary equilibria could be made identical to the corresponding first order conditions for the Ramsey policy–the optimal policy under commitment. One of their conditions for the nominal debt structure is that each government leaves its successor with a total value of nominal claims on the private sector equal to the money stock, such that net nominal liabilities are zero, which appeared to remove the incentive for surprise inflation. By applying an informal but innovative variation argument, however, Calvo and Obstfeld (1990) showed that the solution proposed by Persson, Persson, and Svensson (1987) is indeed not an optimum. Turnovsky, Basar and d’Orey (1988), in a dynamic model, compared Nash, Stackelberg and Pareto solutions and found that the advantages from full-fledged cooperation are likely to be relevant. Sala-i-Martin and Sachs (1991) reported that full cooperation represented by fully centralized budget helps countries, which are hit by asymmetric shocks to attenuate the negative effect of the shock (decrease in output or increase in unemployment). The tool of full cooperation represented by centralized budget will soften the impact of the shock substantially from its original impact. The real impact of the asymmetric shock in a given country depends on two main factors: the size of the country and level of public debt. Nordhaus (1994) considered the strategic relationship between one fiscal and one monetary authority. When a Nash game is played (with the central bank), the lack of cooperation (among fiscal authorities) is responsible for an inefficient policy mix, resulting in an excessively restrictive monetary and an excessively expansionary fiscal policy. The solution of Stackelberg game (with the fiscal authority playing as leader, taking the central bank’s monetary reaction into account) dominates the Nash outcome. This result is explained by the difference in the objectives of the two authorities. The fiscal authority tries to fight unemployment by means of an expansionary policy, but the

Page 8: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

8

central bank reacts with a restrictive monetary policy to keep inflation under control. The outcome is a too expansionary fiscal policy in the Nash equilibrium and secondary effect is a crowding-out effect of private investments in favor of public expenditures. When the fiscal authority takes such behavior into account, and it plays the role of a Stackelberg leader, it will act in a less expansionary way, so as to allow the central bank to follow a less contractionary policy. Bayoumi et al. (1995) presented a further argument for effective fiscal discipline: using US and Canadian data on the borrowing costs of states and provinces concluded that in these currency unions, financial markets effectively ‘price’ in differences in fiscal positions, providing proper incentives to take action before government debt becomes unsustainable. Masson (1996) supported the explicit inclusion of fiscal criterion on the ground that it would be especially difficult to rule out by statute, since there could be other plausible arguments for loosing monetary policy (or not tightening it in the face of inflationary pressures). Furthermore, he argued that a country in a monetary union with an overhang of debt would be vulnerable to adverse shocks, even if its fiscal deficits were currently under control. An unsustainable level of debt would raise the dilemma for the central bank of choosing between allowing a government to default and bailing it out. In addition, fiscal criteria signal the country’s willingness to adhere to the constraints of monetary union. Inability to satisfy the criteria would indicate that the country was unlikely to maintain policies necessary to remain in the monetary union in the face of unfavourable shocks. Eichengreen and von Hagen, (1996) noted that in the case of a cooperative game only among the fiscal policies of the EMU member countries, in which the ECB stays outside, the fear of inflationary pressure due to an excessive expansionary fiscal policy will determine very small welfare gains. Their policy implication is straightforward: the SGP might have a very strong limiting impact on the efforts for a positive or active cooperation in EMU which would lead to more output and employment but will deal with interest rates and exchange rate disturbances, which can alter the equilibrium in investment and savings in EMU. In favour of fiscal restraints prior to the commencement of a monetary union, Woodford (1996) argued that, “variations in the governments’ budget can be an important source of macroeconomic instability and that the instability is not eliminated when the central banker follows a monetary policy rule that is completely unresponsive to the size of public debt.” If nominal rigidities are present, then this variation in governments’ budget and fluctuations in the level of aggregate demand resulting from fiscal shocks can cause variations in the level of real economic activity, real interest rates and rates of inflation, even though rational expectations are assumed. A Rational

Page 9: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

9

Expectations Equilibrium, not involving stable prices and output, may result when shocks that change the expected present value of current and future government budgets occur. This occurs as the fiscal policy regime is ‘non-Ricardian’ and therefore changes the households’ intertemporal budget constraints. In the context of a common monetary policy, this is important for member countries, since a path of unsustainable debt, followed by any government, will impose price level instability in the union overall, even if the other governments adhere to a sustainable debt path. The only way that other governments could ensure price level stability would be to vary their own budget surplus in the opposite way, so that the public debt of the monetary union remains on a steady path. Since this would amount to financing the fiscally irresponsible government’s budget deficit, no government would want to extend such a favour. He concluded that a ceiling on debt would then ensure that the path of debt of all governments in the union is on a sustainable path. Following Woodford (1996), Buiter (1997) argued that achieving fiscal sustainability prior to joining a monetary union is highly desirable, perhaps even essential, from the perspective of the national interest of each candidate country. He contended, however, that it is not certain whether it is necessary to impose it ‘externally’ as a pre-condition of membership, rather than allowing a country to join a monetary union even though its fiscal house is not in order, and letting that country live with the consequences of its fiscal non-sustainability. He further contends that fiscal sustainability is not synonymous with the achievement of the two Maastricht fiscal criteria, neither are they necessary nor sufficient for fiscal sustainability (or for macroeconomic stability) for the EU. Consequently, Buiter (1997) asserted that achieving durable fiscal sustainability is the only truly necessary financial-economic condition for joining a monetary union. It should also be a sufficient condition for membership. When a country joins a monetary union, a decision which should be irrevocable, it gives up its discretionary access to seigniorage and its ability to impose both the anticipated inflation tax and the unanticipated inflation tax. Such a reduction in the national crisis management arsenal should only be contemplated if there is confidence that politically mandated expenditure levels will be financeable with the available taxes and other regular sources of revenue, now and in the future. Beetsma and Bovenberg (1998) focused on the interaction between monetary-fiscal policies in a monetary union. They found that a monetary union with decentralized fiscal policies and centralized monetary policy produces an inflationary bias and excessive spending on public goods. The main policy-making suggestion deduced from their study is that fiscal coordination or fiscal centralization may discipline the macroeconomic policy in the EMU member countries. The practical response to these studies calling for tighter coordination between monetary and fiscal policies at the European level was the creation of the SGP (Stability and Growth Pact) that limited the maneuver area for fiscal

Page 10: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

10

authorities in their expansionary fiscal policy driven by the government deficit. Consequently, the authors expressed concerns of moral hazard. They argued that in a monetary union, if a country running excessive fiscal deficits can be bailed out by the central bank, the costs are borne by other members of the union. This reduces the incentive that members have to be fiscally disciplined. In pursuance of the need for fiscal restraint in a monetary union, Eichengreen and Wyplosz (1998) contended that the main justification for explicit fiscal restraints is that prohibition against bailouts in some form is never iron clad especially for countries with weak monetary and fiscal institutions that also lack strong public support for low inflation. Consequently, formal rules are in danger of being set aside. Large fiscal deficits make it more likely that the point would be reached that the central bank, despite its formal statutes, might yield to pressures for bailout. This could come either in form of monetary financing, or through lowering interest rates, thus lowering government’s interest cost and ultimately inflating away the real value of the debt. In support of the argument for fiscal restraint, Breuss and Weber (1999) demonstrated using a large-scale econometric model involving 10 EMU countries and the European Central Bank (ECB) confirmed that in the case of a full cooperation, where the 10 EMU countries simultaneously coordinate their fiscal policies with the monetary policy of the ECB, the welfare gains are very large for the whole EMU area. However the strong fiscal and monetary policy impulses would lead to a violation of the fiscal targets envisaged in the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). They reported a trade-off between full cooperation and SGP, which limit the room for maneuver of fiscal policy for the EMU member states, also hinder the Pareto efficiency. Full-cooperation is the case of USA, where the evidence of higher fiscal deficits are obvious, but do not have negative impacts on the economic growth and macroeconomic stability. The studies compared European model of SGP and American model of full cooperation. Beetsma and Uhlig (1999) further argued that the main justification for fiscal restraints is that prohibition against bail-outs in some form is never ironclad, particularly in countries with weak monetary and fiscal institutions and lack of strong public support for low inflation. Large fiscal deficits make it more likely that the union central bank might yield to pressures for bail-out despite its formal statutes. Van Aarle, Engwerda and Plasmans (2001) applied a two-country model in a contest of existing monetary union with decentralized fiscal authorities and a centralized monetary authority. The cases they consider include: non-cooperation; full cooperation; coalition between the two fiscal authorities; coalition between one fiscal authority and the monetary authority. Their main finding is that cooperation is often efficient for the fiscal players. Although in many simulations full cooperation does not induce a Pareto

Page 11: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

11

improvement for the ECB, while the governments’ coalitions imply a considerable loss for the ECB compared to the non-cooperative and full cooperative cases. Lambertini and Rovelli (2002) claimed that with a common currency, the weaker EMU member states are exposed to greater competitive pressures, suffering higher levels of unemployment as a result of their lower productivity and competitiveness. Therefore, substantial transfer payments could be necessary. Alternatively, fiscal policy in each member countries can deviate from those in others and be used to counteract regional shocks. Thus, an active fiscal authority is necessary. What might be also necessary is an insurance mechanism against regional shocks. This may imply the need for a stronger political union too. Alvarez, Kehoe, and Neumeyer (2004) re-examined the time consistency of the optimal fiscal and monetary policy in a setting very similar to that of (Lucas and Stokey, 1983; Persson, Persson, and Svensson, 1987; and Calvo and Obstfeld, 1990), except that they assumed that private-sector preferences satisfy conditions that imply that the Friedman rule, a zero nominal interest rate, is optimal. Under the Friedman rule, Alvarez, Kehoe, and Neumeyer (2004) then demonstrated that the Ramsey policy can be made time consistent: this is achieved by the Lucas and Stokey (1983) conditions on the indexed debt structure plus the Persson, Persson, and Svensson (1987) condition of zero government net nominal liabilities. As Alvarez, Kehoe, and Neumeyer (2004) however noted, under the Friedman rule their monetary economy becomes isomorphic to a non-monetary economy. The Alvarez, Kehoe, and Neumeyer (2004) results were essentially a restatement of the Lucas and Stokey (1983) result. Chari and Kehoe (2004) asserted that the desirability of fiscal constraints depends critically on whether the union’s monetary authority can commit to its future policies. If the authority can commit, then fiscal constraints on member states will not increase welfare, but if it cannot commit, then such constraints will increase welfare. He asserts that a time inconsistency problem in monetary policy leads to a free-rider problem in fiscal policy. The authors illustrated in the simplest possible framework, a reduced-form two period benchmark model. In the first period of this model, fiscal authorities of states in a monetary union issue nominal debt to risk-neutral lenders who live outside the union; in the second period, the union’s monetary authority decides the common inflation rate. They assume that second-period output is a decreasing function of the inflation rate, so that the monetary authority balances the benefits of devaluing nominal debt against the costs of reducing output. The larger the debt the monetary authority inherits, the higher it wants to set the inflation rate and, without some mechanism to prevent that, the higher it sets the inflation rate. Thus, without monetary policy commitment, when one of the fiscal authorities issues more debt, the others are made worse off. This free-rider problem implies that the level

Page 12: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

12

of debt in a non cooperative equilibrium is different from that in a cooperative equilibrium. If the monetary authority instead commits to its policies, then the union has no free-rider problem. They sum up as follows: the desirability of debt constraints in a monetary union depends critically on whether the monetary authority can commit to its policies. If it can commit, then debt constraints are not desirable; they can only impose costs. But if the monetary authority cannot commit, then the time inconsistency problem in monetary policy produces a free-rider problem in fiscal policy, and debt constraints are desirable. De Bonis and Della Posta (2004) provided an analytical framework for the analysis of the monetary and fiscal interactions in an environment, which may represent the current European situation, characterized by a single monetary authority (ECB) and several fiscal authorities. Considering macroeconomic policy as implemented through two instruments, monetary and fiscal policy, and defined by two objectives, price and output stabilization, they justify the introduction of fiscal rule like those contained in the SGP. On the other hand, several arguments against fiscal constraint in a monetary union have been put forward by some other economists. Bovenberg et al., (1991) in their contribution underscored the danger that countries will be pushed into a region where fiscal policy becomes uncontrollable. Assuming that there is an upper limit to the debt ratio that investors are willing to finance, governments could be pushed close to this threshold as a result of the loss of seigniorage revenues occasioned by a move to monetary union. Given the impracticality of reducing the deficit to zero, governments would be vulnerable to adverse shocks that might lead inevitably to bail-out or default and the union central bank might be induced to provide the former. De Grauwe (1996) argued that the influence of any single government over the monetary authority is weakened, since it is but one of several governments in the monetary union. Similarly, Beetsma and Bovenberg (1998) posit that because of political myopia among other reasons, the fiscal authorities may attempt to force the central bank to moderate the effect of distortionary taxes by increasing inflation. Within a monetary union, their power to do so is diminished. However, if there is fiscal policy coordination by members in the monetary union, this may strengthen the hand of governments over the union central bank. Dornbusch (1997) opined that the inclusion of fiscal convergence criteria as pre-conditions for monetary union is unnecessary for two reasons. First, the provisions for the European Union for instance go all the way in assuring that the institution is independent, cannot solicit or accept guidance, and cannot finance governments. In addition, the provision of no bailouts of public debts eliminates an immediate spillover effect of poor public finance to the central bank or country’s budgets. Thus, there is no

Page 13: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

13

basis for insistence on debt provisions; consequently the concern for fiscal probity is not justifiable by the need for sound monetary policy. Cooper and Kempf (2000) analyzed monetary and fiscal policy interactions in a two-country model, with and without a monetary union, where the monetary and fiscal authorities agree on the macroeconomic goals. When the monetary authority has leadership, a monetary union is Pareto-efficient. However, if the fiscal authorities have leadership, a monetary union is Pareto-efficient only if the aggregate shocks are highly correlated. Tornell and Velasco (2000) opined that pegged exchange rates may provide a less visible discipline for policy makers than flexible exchange rates, contrary to conventional wisdom. Tornell and Velasco claimed that in situations where there is no fiscal discipline to begin with and authorities have no recourse to debt financing, fixed rates per se do not generate discipline; conversely, flexible rates may tilt the balance in favour of greater discipline because of the immediacy of punishment associated with imprudent fiscal policies. In a monetary union, with pooled foreign exchange reserves, the expanding country can avoid market discipline even longer. Overall, given the results in the literature, it would thus appear that the time-consistency problem of optimal policy is unavoidable in genuinely monetary economies where monetary instruments and nominal assets and liabilities play an essential role in shaping equilibrium allocations and raising some revenue for the government, in particular, in economies where the Friedman rule is not optimal. A plethora of studies have emerged in recent times regarding the impact of fiscal deficit on economic growth. As the debate on fiscal deficits and growth progressed, more elegant models and empirical strategies have been explored in the analysis of the subject. Prominent among these include, Christopher Adams and David Bevan (2002), Robert Korsu (2009) and Yaya Keho (2010). Their findings are divergent. However, the only study that sought to explicitly determine the optimal threshold of fiscal deficit that is consistent with growth is the work by Adams and Bevan (2002) that assessed the relation between fiscal deficits and growth in a panel of forty five (45) developing countries. An overlapping generation’s model in the tradition of Diamond (1965) that incorporated high-powered money in addition to debt and taxes was specified. The estimation strategy involved a standard fixed effect panel data estimation and bi-variate linear regression of growth on the fiscal deficits using pooled data. An important contribution of the empirical analysis is the existence of a statistically significant non-linearity in the impact of budget deficit on growth. However, this non-linearity the authors argued reflected the underlying composition of deficit financing. In effect, Adams and Bevan posited that for a given level of government spending, a shift from a balanced budget to a (small) deficit may temporarily reduce distortions especially

Page 14: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

14

if the distortions impact growth rather than output. Based on a consistent treatment of the government budget, the authors found evidence of a threshold effect at a level of the deficit around 1.5 percent of GDP. While there appeared to be a growth payoff to reducing deficits to level, this effect disappeared or reversed itself for further fiscal contraction. The magnitude of this payoff, but not its general character, necessarily depended on how changes in the deficit were financed (through changes in borrowing or seigniorage) and on how the change in the deficit was accommodated elsewhere in the budget. The authors also found evidence of the interaction effects between deficits and debt stock, with high debt stocks exacerbating the adverse consequences of high deficits. Moreover, Gale and Orszag (2002) summarized the conclusions of almost 60 studies: of these fifty percent found a “predominantly insignificant” effect of fiscal deficits on interest rates and the other fifty percent a ‘mixed ‘or ‘predominantly insignificant’ effects. They argued that even when interest rates do not increase as a result of fiscal expansion (e.g., because of foreign capital savings replacing domestic savings) economic performance may still be negatively affected by persistent imbalances as capital stock accumulation declines, either because of a fall in domestic or foreign net investment. The authors indicated that a projected rise in the fiscal deficits-GDP ratio of 1 percentage result in an increase in the long term interest rates by 0.4 to 0.6 percentage points. In the same manner, Dai and Singleton (2003) findings indicated that a 1 percentage point increase in the deficits increases 10 year (interest) rate by 41 basis points. Furthermore, Laubach (2003) reported that fiscal deficit has a significant effect on interest rate. A one percentage increase in the projected deficit-to-GDP ratio is estimated to raise long term interest rates by approximately 25 basis points. Similarly, interest rate rises by about 4 basis points in response to a percentage point in the projected debt-GDP ratio. At is clear from the literature is the opposition to convergence criteria is not so much based on the irrelevance of the criteria but the inability to ascertain the level that will be consistent with the various countries growth trajectory.

ANALYTICAL AND FRAMEWORK AND EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY

The analytical framework adopted for this study follows essentially the Keynesian framework. Recalled that in a simple Keynesian framework, desired aggregate demand relationship is specified in the goods market as:

( )Y C I G X M (1)

Page 15: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

15

With the following behavioural equations:

, 0

, 0

, 0

, >0

d

d

d

C a bY b

Y Y T

I i

G G

X s e

M m Y

Where Y is output; C, consumption; I, investment; G, government spending which is assumed to be exogenous; X, exports; M, imports; Yd, disposable income; T, tax revenue; i, interest rate; e, exchange rate. In equilibrium (after substituting behavioural equations into the desired aggregate demand equation (1)), output will be given by

1

( )A

Y i e G b T

(2)

Where1 , b A a s m

From equation (2), increasing taxes will reduce output, while increasing government spending will increase output. But fiscal deficit (FD) is given by

( )FD G T G b T (3)

Fiscal deficit is the excess of government expenditure over its revenue. Assuming that the government derives its total revenue from tax sources (which is quite realistic), G-T gives the deficit position of the government. Since individuals do not spend all their income, the total revenue that could be generated from consumption expenditure is

( )b T. Thus, subtracting this from government expenditure will give approximate

position of the fiscal balance. Putting (3) into (2) gives

1A

Y i e FD

(4)

Given that the countries in the WAMZ are essentially small-open economies (without ability to influence international price developments) and for holistic treatment of the economy, the model is extended to incorporate the money sector as well as the external

Page 16: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

16

sector. The money market in an open economy can be represented by the following equations:

Money Demand Function:

, 0, 0DM

kY i kP

(5)

Money Supply Function: 1 2 1 2 , , 0

SM Bm m i m m

P P

(6)

Equilibrium Condition: D SM M (7)

where P is the general price level, B international reserves held by the central

bank and 1 2,m m are coefficients.

From the above money market model, the LM schedule2 can be specified as

LM Schedule:

, 0, 0B

i YP

(8)

Given the importance of the external sector in the countries of study, the influence of the sector is incorporated through the balance of payments schedule. The balance of payments schedule is given as

BP Schedule: 2 0 1 2 0 1 2 , , , 0 B A Y e i (9)

where 2Ais the aggregate of exogenous components in the net export function and

0 1 2, , are coefficients.

Putting equation (8) into (3) gives

1 1 2

BY A Y e FD

P

(10)

where 1

and 2

2 The LM curve is used to determined equilibrium in the money market. The L stands for

liquidity and M for Money.

Page 17: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

17

Putting equation (9) into (10) produces

11 2 0 1 2 2 Y A A Y e i Y e FD

P

(11) Isolating like terms and re-arranging equation (11) gives

1 2 3 4

1Y C e i e FD

P

(12) where

1 1 2 1 1 1 11 0 2 1 2 3 4

11 , , , , ,

A AC

Recasting the second term on the right-hand side of equation (12) in logarithmic generic term gives

2 4Y C e i FD (12B)

where the rate of inflation and 1 3 .

In equation (12B), equilibrium output is positively related to fiscal deficit. In a time series context, output is influenced by its own past level (output dynamics) which is consistent with accelerator principle. Equation (12B) can be restated as

1 2 4t t t t tY c Y i e FD (13)

Recasting (13) gives

1 2 3 4t t t ty c i e FD (14)

where 1t t ty Y Y which captures the change in GDP (growth rate of GDP) and

1 4, 0 . Equation (14) is essentially an output (GDP) growth model which gives the

long-run relationship between output growth (change in output) and fiscal deficit. This relationship is positive; implying the widening of fiscal deficit will improve growth. However, some empirical studies document the negative relationship between growth and fiscal deficit, while some others establish a positive relationship as given by the simple Keynesian framework. This ambiguity of the relationship between growth and

Page 18: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

18

fiscal deficit suggests a threshold effect of fiscal deficit on growth. This will inform the empirical modelling of growth-deficit relationship in this study. From the supply-side of the economy, output is a function of capital stock and labour. A simple Cob-Douglas production function generates a growth model of the form

0 1 2ln lny K L (15)

Where K refers to capital stock, L refers to labour force growth, is a change notation

and 0 1 2, , are coefficients.

Specification of the Empirical Model

In specifying the empirical model, the study relies on the above theoretical framework. From both the demand and supply sides of the economy, variables such as interest rate, exchange rate, inflation, fiscal deficit, investment (change in capital stock) and labour are identified as the key variables explaining growth. However, it is appropriate to include in the empirical model those reform variables that also influence economic growth. In the WAMZ countries, financial sector reforms have been undertaken, while trade liberalization policies have also been implemented. Hence, it is appropriate to include financial reforms variable and trade openness variable in the empirical model. The key variables in the empirical model are defined as follows: Dependent variable Yit = GDPGt = Growth rate of real GDP Independent variables

= Gross fixed capital formation as a ratio of GDP as a proxy for growth

in capital stock. Lab = Secondary school enrolment as a proxy for labour force.

= FD/GDP = Fiscal Deficit/GDP, excluding grants

= Inflation rate

M2GDPt = M2/GDP ratio – measuring financial depth

= Exchange Rate expressed as a given amount of local currency per US dollar

(Depreciation/ appreciation)

= Degree of openness of the economy, measured as

Besides investment, labour force and fiscal deficit; other control variables included in the

model are, namely, interest rate ( , exchange rate depreciation/ appreciation ( ,

inflation ( financial deepening M2/GDP and openness index (OPN). Interest rate

Page 19: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

19

has an important role in economic growth. Higher interest rates reduce the growth of consumer spending and economic growth. This is because more incentive to save in a bank rather than spend, more expensive to borrow, therefore less spending on credit and less investment; increase cost of mortgage repayments, therefore, reduce disposable income and therefore consumer spending. Consequently, an inverse relationship is expected between interest rate and economic growth. Exchange rate development impacts on the economic growth process. On balance we expect a positive relationship between depreciation and economic growth. Inflation is another significant variable influencing output growth rate. This variable is especially significant for in the WAMZ, where food price and other exogenous factors including high imports of food and intermediate products play very important role. In general, very high levels of inflation may undermine economic growth. However if the inflation rate is low, stable and sustainable, it may be interpreted as an indicator of macroeconomic stability that would enhance growth. And if the economy is at equilibrium higher inflation should impact adversely on growth. Hence, we expect to get inverse relationship with output growth. Financial deepening measured by the ratio of M2 to GDP essentially seek to capture the role of the financial sector development in economic growth. The conventional theory predicts a positive correlation between the level of financial deepening and economic growth. In modern economic theory the role of the financial sector is seen to be catalytic to the growth of the economy. Also, the index of openness proxy by the ratio of the sum of imports plus export over GDP is expected to positively influence growth, all things being equal, the more open the economy the more access to foreign capital that is expected to increase investment and economic growth. Thus, the level of openness of the economy is expected to positively impact on economic growth. Budget deficit is another significant variable influencing output growth rate. This variable is especially significant for most developing countries including the WAMZ countries, where fiscal discipline plays very important role. In general very high levels of fiscal deficit may undermine economic growth. However if the budget deficit is low, stable and sustainable, it may be interpreted as an increased demand for goods and services. And if the economy is below its equilibrium on Keynesian cross, higher fiscal deficit, that is increased government expenditures, should stimulate growth. Consequently we expect to get positive relationship with output growth. Based on the general framework provided and the foregoing variables identified, the linear growth equation is explicitly specified as follows: The panel estimation model is specified as follows:

Page 20: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

20

16 Where i=1,2,…5 for countries. t = 1, 2,… for time period.

Specification of Threshold Autoregressive (TAR) Model The TAR model specifies that individual observations can fall into discrete classes based on the value of an observed threshold variable (Lee and Wong, 2005). Following the framework of Li (2005), we specify the threshold model for the WAMZ countries as follows: The panel estimation model is specified as follows:

...17

Where = Dummy variable with values 1 if > K* or 0 otherwise.

= Annual fiscal deficit - GDP ratio.

K* = The threshold level of fiscal deficit/GDP which is to be calculated.

= The effect of fiscal deficit below the threshold level.

= The effect of fiscal deficit above the threshold level.

Other variables are as previously defined. Where ‘i’ and ‘t’ are as defined in equation (16). All the variables are as defined above. From the above equation, a priori expectations of a

threshold effect of deficit on growth are that

If threshold effect holds then the turning point can be calculated using the

relation3: Taking the antilog of this will give optimal level of fiscal

deficit that will maximize real GDP growth.

3 ;

Page 21: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

21

Data Sources and Estimation Techniques GDP growth data, gross capital formation as well as secondary school enrolment data were obtained from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators; Fiscal Deficit data were obtained from the Ministries of Finance of Nigeria. Imports, Exports, Interest rates, exchange rate, and broad money growth data were sourced from the central banks of Nigeria, while inflation rates were obtained from the National Bureau of Statics of Nigeria. All variables are measured either in growth rate terms or as ratios. Different models specified are estimated using different appropriate econometric techniques. For the linear growth model, the study employs the Classical Ordinary Least Squares Technique (OLS) as suggested by Min Li (2005). For the non-linear model, the study uses the non-Linear Least Square (NLLS) method as suggested by Khan et al. (2001). As explained by Khan et al. (2001), the method involves the following procedures: for any K*, the model is estimated by OLS, yielding the Residual Sum of Squares (RSS) as a function of K*. The least square estimate is found by selecting the value of K* that minimizes the sum of squared residuals. An extensive and systematic analysis of the data was carried out to ensure conformity with basic properties of the OLS estimate. In particular, the stationarity test using Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) and the co-integration test, using Engle-Granger Two-Step procedure (EGTS) were applied. The use of EGTS is informed by the large number of the explanatory variables and the fact that not all the series integrated at order one to warrant the use of the Johansson Technique. The study period is 1980 to 2009. Due to data problem Liberia was excluded from the study.

Diagnostic Tests for Optimal Level of Deficit Having identified the threshold level for deficit, it is important to determine whether the threshold effect is statistically significant. In this regard, this study conducted Normality Test (J-Qtest); Serial Correlation (LM test); Heteroscedasticity (ARCH) and Stability (Cusum square).

ANALYSIS OF RESULTS

Panel Unit Root Results

Panel unit root test of the variables was carried out using three standard methods including Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003), Fisher-Type test using ADF and PP-test (Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001)) and Hadri (1999). Table 51 present the results of the panel unit root tests based on the three methods test for all variables in the model. The Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003) method test indicate that LENDRit, M2GDPit and OPENit have a unit root but DEFit, DEPit, INFit, INVit, and RGDPRit have not unit root. Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001) method based on ADF-Fisher Chi-square test

Page 22: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

22

indicate similar results. Also Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001) method based on PP-Fisher Chi-square test indicate that LENDRit, M2GDPit and OPENit have unit root. Table 1: WAMZ Panel Unit Root Test Results

VARIABLE STATISTIC AT LEVEL STATISTIC AT 1ST DIFFERENCE

IPS ADF-FISHER PP-FISHER IPS ADF-FISHER PP-FISHER

DEF

-2.31495**

21.7100**

36.7119***

- - -

DEP -4.92693*** 41.5370*** 82.4097**** - - -

INF -2.30362*** 20.5702** 38.1812*** - - -

INV -1.76002** 20.9720** 20.2697** - - -

LENDR 0.47784 6.28887 5.67729 -4.57386*** 38.9173*** 231.766***

M2GDP 2.78909 4.93406 14.4480 -5.22094*** 43.6906*** 72.8210***

OPEN -0.97054 13.9592 20.2419 -4.97863*** 41.6701*** 117.590***

RGDPG -4.69147*** 41.0380*** 31.5827*** - - -

Computed by the Researcher: **Significant at 5%; ***Significant at 1%

IPS Im, Pesaran and Shin W-stat; ADF-FISHER -ADF - Fisher Chi-square; PP-FISHER- PP - Fisher Chi-square From the results of the panel unit root test, it can be concluded that three variables used in this model have unit root. However, these variables were stationary after first difference. Thus, as indicated in Table 1, LENDR, M2GDP and OPEN were significant at 1.0 percent after first difference.

Panel Cointegration Test Results Table 2 present the results of the panel cointegration test for the 1(1) variables based on Pedroni Residual Cointegration Tests.

Page 23: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

23

Table 2: WAMZ Pedroni Residual Cointegration Test Results

NULL HYPOTHESIS: NO COINTEGRATION

Alternative hypothesis: common AR coefs. (within-dimension)

Weighted

Statistic Prob. Statistic Prob.

Panel v-Statistic -0.043168 0.5172 -0.774698 0.7807

Panel rho-Statistic -1.344205 0.0894 -2.057476 0.0198

Panel PP-Statistic -3.123388 0.0009 -3.922965 0.0000

Panel ADF-Statistic -1.372572 0.0849 -1.520618 0.0642

Alternative hypothesis: individual AR coefs. (between-dimension)

Statistic Prob.

Group rho-Statistic -1.168842 0.1212

Group PP-Statistic -3.686068 0.0001

Group ADF-Statistic -0.857671 0.1955

From Table 1, it is clear that overall all variables were has cointegration with each other given the probability of the various statistics. Thus the null of no cointegration is rejected.

Page 24: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

24

RESULTS OF PANEL GROWTH MODEL Table 3 present the results of the parsimonious model of fiscal deficit and economic growth in the WAMZ. Table 3: WAMZ Fiscal Deficit -Growth Model Results (Parsimonious)

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C 1.872481 1.140791 1.641388 0.1033

RGDPG(-1) 0.527446 0.069368 7.603612 0.0000

DEP -0.042486 0.021414 -1.983994 0.0495

INV 0.146829 0.084398 1.739718 0.0844

INV(-1) -0.167287 0.085067 -1.966530 0.0515

DEF(-4) 0.040728 0.066546 0.612034 0.5416

M2GDP(-2) 0.072207 0.037691 1.915753 0.0577

R-squared 0.402584 Mean dependent var 3.626615

Adjusted R-squared 0.373441 S.D. dependent var 4.902551

S.E. of regression 3.880637 Akaike info criterion 5.602218

Sum squared resid 1852.299 Schwarz criterion 5.756624

Log likelihood -357.1442 Hannan-Quinn criter. 5.664958

F-statistic 13.81442 Durbin-Watson stat 1.714836

Prob. (F-statistic) 0.000000

All variables appear with both the correct sign and incorrect sign. While lag real GDP, investment, deficit and M2GDP were correctly signed, depreciation and lag investment were wrongly signed. With respect to significance, only fiscal deficit was not significant at 10.0 percent. From the results, our variable of interest, DEF indicate a positive relationship with economic growth rate with a four year lagged period. Thus a 10.0 percent increase in deficit positively impact economic growth in the Zone by 0.4 percent. As indicated earlier this variable is not significant at the conventional level. A 10.0 percent depreciation impact growth negatively contemporaneously in the Zone. Current investment as well as broad money growth as a ratio of GDP positively impact economic growth in the Zone. A 10.0 percent increase in investment contemporaneously increase real GDP growth by 1.5 percent, while a 10.0 percent increase in M2GDP positively impact growth by 0.7 percent with two year lag.

Page 25: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

25

ANALYSIS OF THE RESULTS OF THE THRESHOLD MODEL

The estimation results, based on repeated estimation of the threshold model for the different values of expected threshold (K), are reported in Appendix 1. The first column labelled K, gives the range over which the search for the threshold is conducted. The dummy variable D1t represents the effect of inflation below the chosen threshold (K) value while G2t represents the effect for deficit above the threshold. Only the explanatory variables that are statistically significant are reported along with the deficit dummies to conserve space As shown in Table 4, the minimization of RSS occurs at the threshold point of 5.0 percent, where the RSS records the lowest value of 1932.17. To further confirm the threshold effect, the adjusted R2 from the estimation at 5.0 percent yields the highest value of 40.0 percent. A perfunctory perusal of the Appendix 1 reveals that the coefficient of deficit dummy at the threshold (G2t ), carries positive sign indicating that lower than 5.0 percent, the effect of deficit on growth may be positive. Conversely, the coefficient of deficit dummy D1t, representing effect of deficit below the threshold level possess negative sign, suggesting that, deficit level beyond 5.0 percent is detrimental to growth. Thus the threshold level of deficit for the WAMZ is identified at 5.0 percent. It should be noted that the two parameters are statistically significant at conventional levels. Table 4: WAMZ Fiscal Deficit -Growth Threshold Model Results

K Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. RSS R-Sqr

D1*DEF(-2) -0.120028 0.056904 -2.109308 0.0369 1952.36 0.39

G1*DEF(-2) 0.013392 0.139573 -0.095951 0.9237

C 0.911527 1.280062 0.712096 0.4777

RGDPG(-1) 0.588825 0.154535 3.810305 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.182036 0.142830 -1.274496 0.2048

DEP -0.043409 0.019989 -2.171715 0.0317

1% INV 0.192796 0.082837 2.327418 0.0215

INV(-1) -0.232281 0.075242 -3.087121 0.0025

M2GDP(-2) 0.090934 0.042554 2.136911 0.0345

D2*DEF(-2) -0.118265 0.054331 -2.176738 0.0313 1951.68 0.44

G2*DEF(-2) 0.035355 0.137080 -0.257913 0.7969

C 0.927252 1.311924 0.706788 0.4810

RGDPG(-1) 0.590676 0.153905 3.837920 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.183670 0.142857 -1.285692 0.2009

2% DEP -0.043326 0.019765 -2.192131 0.0302

INV 0.189920 0.084237 2.254582 0.0259

INV(-1) -0.230974 0.075395 -3.063543 0.0027

Page 26: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

26

M2GDP(-2) 0.093013 0.043357 2.145280 0.0338

D3*DEF(-2) -0.110220 0.054041 -2.039575 0.0435 1953.68 0.39

G3*DEF(-2) 0.141000 0.092430 -1.525487 0.1296

C 1.020873 1.332848 0.765934 0.4451

RGDPG(-1) 0.590390 0.154061 3.832168 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.184127 0.142777 -1.289614 0.1995

DEP -0.041819 0.019661 -2.126977 0.0354

3% INV 0.188894 0.084880 2.225436 0.0278

INV(-1) -0.230755 0.076190 -3.028673 0.0030

M2GDP(-2) 0.088492 0.042014 2.106273 0.0371

D4*DEF(-2) -0.109439 0.052463 -2.086013 0.0390 1951.50 0.39

G4*DEF(-2) 0.168293 0.096339 -1.746883 0.0831

4% C 1.051903 1.340726 0.784577 0.4342

RGDPG(-1) 0.589073 0.154605 3.810188 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.184288 0.142428 -1.293905 0.1980

DEP -0.042214 0.019838 -2.127907 0.0353

INV 0.187851 0.085033 2.209153 0.0290

INV(-1) -0.230427 0.076642 -3.006531 0.0032

M2GDP(-2) 0.087044 0.042223 2.061523 0.0413

D5*DEF(-2) -0.096004 0.053931 -1.780115 0.0774 1932.17 0.40

G5*DEF(-2) 0.227048 0.084413 -2.689728 0.0081

C 1.089178 1.342894 0.811068 0.4188

RGDPG(-1) 0.591938 0.152251 3.887904 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.181290 0.142937 -1.268323 0.2070

DEP -0.041135 0.019604 -2.098310 0.0379

INV 0.188626 0.085612 2.203265 0.0294

5% INV(-1) -0.234674 0.078182 -3.001639 0.0032

M2GDP(-2) 0.084617 0.039365 2.149550 0.0335

6% D6*DEF(-2) -0.104070 0.053087 -1.960371 0.0521 1942.56 0.39

G6*DEF(-2) -0.190459 0.073696 -2.584382 0.0109

C 1.034513 1.328239 0.778861 0.4375

RGDPG(-1) 0.591913 0.153020 3.868200 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.182986 0.142713 -1.282198 0.2021

DEP -0.041660 0.019895 -2.093944 0.0383

INV 0.194838 0.086018 2.265068 0.0252

INV(-1) -0.240887 0.076653 -3.142562 0.0021

M2GDP(-2) 0.086444 0.040266 2.146829 0.0337

D7*DEF(-2) -0.122669 0.057966 -2.116239 0.0363 1949.30 0.39

7% G7*DEF(-2) -0.069752 0.080223 -0.869472 0.3862

Page 27: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

27

C 0.971959 1.352455 0.718663 0.4737

RGDPG(-1) 0.584330 0.149845 3.899561 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.184481 0.145571 -1.267291 0.2074

DEP -0.040950 0.019764 -2.071934 0.0403

INV 0.185939 0.085530 2.173953 0.0316

INV(-1) -0.224898 0.076030 -2.958030 0.0037

M2GDP(-2) 0.092307 0.043176 2.137936 0.0344

D8*DEF(-2) -0.128042 0.069987 -1.829498 0.0697 1951.69 0.39

8% G8*DEF(-2) -0.080514 0.058456 -1.377342 0.1708

RGDPG(-1) 0.582051 0.150309 3.872358 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.183712 0.142858 -1.285980 0.2008

DEP -0.041252 0.019865 -2.076552 0.0399

INV 0.185647 0.084413 2.199282 0.0297

INV(-1) -0.221732 0.076400 -2.902262 0.0044

M2GDP(-2) 0.089898 0.041815 2.149901 0.0335

9% D9*DEF(-2) -0.099958 0.087086 -1.147813 0.2532 1953.20 0.39

G9*DEF(-2) -0.124780 0.054886 -2.273435 0.0247

C 1.050175 1.289833 0.814194 0.4171

RGDPG(-1) 0.596357 0.152848 3.901625 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.186710 0.139759 -1.335948 0.1840

DEP -0.042133 0.019782 -2.129863 0.0351

INV 0.189553 0.085822 2.208664 0.0290

INV(-1) -0.234256 0.079448 -2.948522 0.0038

M2GDP(-2) 0.088352 0.041329 2.137774 0.0345

10% D10*DEF(-2) -0.094980 0.105098 -0.903731 0.3678 1944.51 0.39

G10*DEF(-2) -0.129302 0.054667 -2.365283 0.0195

C 1.087307 1.257706 0.864516 0.3889

RGDPG(-1) 0.591011 0.154129 3.834509 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.194746 0.139247 -1.398567 0.1644

DEP -0.042710 0.019776 -2.159690 0.0327

INV 0.187726 0.085166 2.204225 0.0293

INV(-1) -0.235802 0.083207 -2.833907 0.0054

M2GDP(-2) 0.089956 0.040510 2.220584 0.0282

D11*DEF(-2) -0.078663 0.120360 -0.653564 0.5146 1950.38 0.39

11% G11*DEF(-2) -0.130885 0.054426 -2.404810 0.0176

C 1.157121 1.259070 0.919028 0.3598

RGDPG(-1) 0.599516 0.152756 3.924665 0.0001

RGDPG(-2) -0.192325 0.137755 -1.396143 0.1651

DEP -0.042468 0.019894 -2.134757 0.0347

Page 28: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

28

INV 0.188991 0.085698 2.205319 0.0292

INV(-1) -0.239449 0.084568 -2.831431 0.0054

M2GDP(-2) 0.088100 0.040468 2.177011 0.0313

12% D12*DEF(-2) -0.073212 0.158274 -0.462564 0.6445 1951.02 0.39

G12*DEF(-2) -0.127269 0.058656 -2.169739 0.0319

C 1.207950 1.239346 0.974667 0.3316

RGDPG(-1) 0.592876 0.153425 3.864272 0.0002

RGDPG(-2) -0.188773 0.137383 -1.374067 0.1718

DEP -0.042566 0.019785 -2.151396 0.0333

INV 0.185966 0.081381 2.285138 0.0240

INV(-1) -0.238187 0.087478 -2.722814 0.0074

M2GDP(-2) 0.088242 0.040799 2.162823 0.0324

Table 5 presents another enthralling finding of this study. The effects of deficit, précised by the signs of the coefficients of the deficit dummies are generally positive. The coefficients of the deficit dummy G21t, maintain positive values between 1 and 5.0 percent, indicating that deficit impacts positively on growth within the deficit range of 1-5.0 percent at the WAMZ wide level. The policy implication is that if the Zone were to be operational today, permitting deficit beyond 5.0 percent will be detrimental to growth at the zonal level. Thus the range 1 – 5 percent provides the amphi-theatre for a menu of policy choices on deficit levels that would be consistent with economic growth in the WAMZ. Table 5: WAMZ Range of Fiscal Deficit Conducive for Growth

D1t = Effect of deficit below K G2t = Effect of deficit above K

K Coefficient Effect Coefficient Effect

1% -0.120028 Negative 0.013392 Positive

2% -0.118265 Negative 0.035355 Positive

3% -0.110220 Negative 0.141000 Positive

4% -0.109439 Negative 0.168293 Positive

5% -0.096004 Negative 0.227048 Positive

6% -0.104070 Negative -0.190459 Negative

7% -0.122669 Negative -0.069752 Negative

8% -0.128042 Negative -0.080514 Negative

9% -0.099958 Negative -0.124780 Negative

10% -0.094980 Negative -0.129302 Negative

11% -0.078663 Negative -0.130885 Negative

12% -0.073212 Negative -0.127269 Negative

SUMMARY AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

Page 29: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

29

This paper sought to ascertain the nature of relationship between fiscal deficits and economic growth, as well as to establish the fiscal deficit threshold that is consistent with economic growth in the West African Monetary Zone. Empirical evidence indicates that all variables appear with both correct and incorrect signs. While lag real GDP, investment, deficit and M2GDP were correctly signed, depreciation and lag investment were wrongly signed. With respect to significance, only fiscal deficit was not significant at 10.0 percent. From the results, our variable of interest, fiscal deficit indicates a positive relationship with economic growth rate with a four year lagged period. Thus a 10.0 percent increase in deficit positively impact economic growth in the Zone by 0.4 percent. As indicated earlier this variable is not significant at the conventional level. A 10.0 percent depreciation impact growth negatively contemporaneously in the Zone. Current investment as well as broad money growth as a ratio of GDP positively impact economic growth in the Zone. A 10.0 percent increase in investment contemporaneously increase real GDP growth by 1.5 percent, while a 10.0 percent increase in M2GDP positively impact growth by 0.7 percent with a two year lag. In the WAMZ there is a positive relation was established between fiscal deficit and economic growth, however the variable was not significant at conventional level. The threshold level of deficit that is consistent with economic growth at the WAMZ level was identified at 5.0 percent. This study has found that there is inverse positive relationship between fiscal deficit and economic growth in the WAMZ. It should however be noted that the impact of deficit on growth is not contemporaneous as the variable impact on growth positively with a lag. This is not surprising as it takes time for the investment in infrastructure financed by deficits to mature and impact growth. This again is instructive on another front; given that the measurement of this convergence criterion in the WAMZ convergence process is based on current deficit, the import of such measure could be lost in the process as it does not approximate reality. The results of the threshold model validate our hypothesis that the threshold model for all the countries in the WAMZ is not identical and that it is not 4.0 percent. However, since the identified threshold ranges from 1-5 per cent and the WAMZ convergence criterion on fiscal deficit is 4.0 percent (within the range), it could be safely concluded that the threshold is valid. The policy implications and recommendations based on the major findings of this paper is that fiscal deficit criterion in the WAMZ should be maintained at 4.0 per cent since this level falls within the acceptable range of optimal deficit identified in the study.

Page 30: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

30

REFERENCES Adam, C. and D. L. Bevan (2002), “Fiscal Deficits and Growth in Developing

Countries”, Department of Economics, University of Oxford. Alvarez, F., P. J. Kehoe, and P. A. Neumeyer (2004), “The Time Consistency of Optimal

Monetary and Fiscal Policies,” Econometrica 72, 541—567. Balogun, E.D. (2007), “Monetary Policy and Economic Performance of West African

Monetary Zone?”, West African Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration”. Vol. 7 (1); pp.33- 59

Bayoumi, T., M. Goldstein, and G. Woglom, (1995), “Do Credit Markets Discipline

Sovereign Borrowers? Evidence from US States”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, No 4, Part 1 (Nov.), pp. 1046-1059

Beetsma, R. and A. Bovenberg (1998), “Monetary Union without Fiscal Coordination

May Discipline Policymakers”, Journal of International Economics, 45, 239-58. Beetsma, R. and H. Uhlig (1999), “An Analysis of the Stability and Growth Pact”,

Economic Journal, 109, 546-71. Bovenberg, A., J. Kremers, and P. Masson (1991), “Fiscal Discipline and Flexibility in

EMU: The Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact.”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 14(3), 81-97

Breuss, F. and A. Weber, A. (1999), “Economic Policy Coordination in the EMU: How

much scope will there be within the framework of the SGP”?, WIFO Working Paper No. 113,

Buiter, W. H. (1997), “The Economic Case for Monetary Union in the European

Union”, in Christophe Deissenberg, Robert F. Owen and David Ulph eds. European Economic

Calvo, G.A., and M. Obstfeld (1990), “Time Consistency of Fiscal and Monetary Policy: A Comment,” Econometrica 58, 1245—1247.

Calvo, G. A. (1978), “On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in a Monetary

Economy,” Econometrica 46, 1411—1428. Chari, V. and P. Kehoe (2004), “On the Desirability of Fiscal Constraints in a Monetary

Union”, NBER Working Paper No. 10232.

Page 31: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

31

Cooper, R. and H. Kempf (2000) “Designing Stabilization Policy in a Monetary Union,” NBER Working Paper #7607, March

Dai, Q. and K. J. Singleton (2003), ‘Term structure dynamics in theory and reality’, Review

of Financial Studies 16(3), 632–678. De Bonis, V. and P. Della Posta (2004), “Strategic Interaction between Monetary and

Fiscal Authorities in a Monetary Union”, Research Paper, Università di Pisa : Pisa,

De Grauwe, P. (1996), “Discussion”. In H. Siebert (Eds.), Monetary Policy in an Integrated

World Diamond, P. (1965), “National debt in a neoclassical growth model”, American Economic

Review, 55, 1126-1150. Dornbusch, R. (1997). “Fiscal aspects of monetary integration”, American Economic Review,

Vol. 87, no. 2, pp. 221-223.Dynamics and Control, No.10, Eichengreen, B. and J. von Hagen (1996). “Fiscal Policy and Monetary Union: Is there a

tradeoff between Federalism and budgetary restrictions?”, Working Paper No. 5517, NBER : Cambridge,

Eichengreen, W. and N. Wyplosz (1998), “Stability Pact: More than a Minor Nuisance?”

Economic Policy 26, 67-113. Gale, W. G. and P. R. Orszag (2002), “The Economic Effects of Long Term Fiscal

Discipline,” Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Discussion Paper, December. Hansen, B. E. (1999), ‘Threshold Effects in Non-Dynamic Panels: Estimation, Testing

and Inference’, Journal of Econometrics, 93(2): 345-368. Im, K S, H. Pesaran, and Y. Shin (2003), “Testing for Unit Roots in Heterogeneous

Panels,” Journal of Econometrics, 115, pp. 53–74 Islam, M. F. (1998), “Brazil’s Twin Deficits: An Empirical Examination”, Atlantic

Economic Journal, Vol. 26, No. 2, pp. 121-128. Karras, G. (1994), ‘Macroeconomic Effects of Budget Deficits: Further International

Evidence’, Journal of International Money and Finance, 13(2), 190-210.

Page 32: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Vol. 12, No.1 Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration

32

Keho, Y. (2010), “Fiscal deficits and Economic Growth: Causality Evidence and Policy Implications for WAEMU Countries”, European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences, Issue 18, pp 99-105.

Khan, M. S. and A. S. Senhadji (2001), ‘Threshold Effect in the Relationship Between

Inflation and Growth’, IMF Staff Papers, 48: 1-21. Korsu, R. D. (2009), “Fiscal Deficit and the Eternal Sector Performance of Sierra Leone:

A Simulation”, West African Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration, Vol. 9 (1), pp. 51-73

Lambertini, L. and R. Rovelli (2002),’ Independent or Coordinated Monetary and Fiscal

Policy’ in Landau, D. (1983): “Government Expenditure and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Study”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 49, pp. 783-97.

Lee, C. C. and S. Y. Wong (2005), ‘Inflationary Threshold Effect in the Relationship

between Financial Development and Economic Growth: Evidence from Taiwan and Japan’, Journal of Economic Development, 30(1): 45-69.

Levin, A, C. F. Lin, and C. S. J. Chu (2002), “Unit Root Test in Panel Data: Asymptotic and

Finite Sample Properties”, Journal of Econometrics 108, pp. 1-24. Levine, R and D. Renelt (1992), ‘A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross Country growth

regressions’, American Economic Review, 76, 808-819. Levine, R. and S. Zervos (1993), “Looking at Facts: What we know about Policy and

Growth from Cross-Country Analysis”, World Bank Policy Research Papers, WPS 1115.

Li, E. (2005), ‘Inflation and Economic Growth: Threshold Effect and Transmission

Mechanism’, Department of Economics, University of Alberta, Canada. (Mimeograph) pp. 1-69.

Liargovas, P. and C. Papazoglou (1997), “The Relationship Between Government

Budget Deficits and Interest Rates in Greece”, International Review of Economics and Business, Vol. 44, No. 4: 807-817.

Lucas, R. E., and N.L. Stokey (1983), “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in and

Economy without Capital,” Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 55—93. Masson, P. (1996), “Fiscal Dimensions of EMU”, Economic Journal, 106, 996-1004.

Page 33: AN EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF THE OPTIMAL …...criteria are required to fulfill fiscal target (fiscal deficit-GDP ratio of less than or equal to 4.0 per cent). Among other reasons for

Emmanuel Onwioduokit

33

Nana, O.J. (2007), “Eco Currency: Is a Third Postponement Avoidable?”, West African Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration”. Vol. 7 (1); pp.1-14

Nordhaus, W. D. (1994), “Policy Games: Coordination and Independence in Monetary

and Fiscal Policies”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity No. 2, Persson, M., Persson, T. and Svensson, L. E.O. (1987), “Time Consistency of Fiscal and

Monetary Policy,” Econometrica 55, 1419—1431. Sala-i-Martin, X., and J. Sachs (1991), ‘Fiscal Federalism and Optimum Currency Areas:

evidence for Europe from United States’, Working Paper No. 3855, NBER : Cambridge,

Tabellini, G. (1986), ‘Money, Debt and Deficits in a Dynamic Game”, Journal of

Economic Dynamics and Control,’ Vol.10 (4) pp.427-442 Tanzi, V. and H.H. Zee (1997), Fiscal Policy and Long Run Growth, IMF Staff Papers, Vol.

44, pp.2179-2209. Tornell, A. and A. Velasco (2000), “Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates: Which

Provides More Fiscal Discipline?” Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, 399-436. Turnovsky, S.T., T. Basar and V. d’Orey (1988), ‘Dynamic Strategic Monetary Policies

and Coordination in Interdependent Economies’ American Economic Review, 78, 341-361

Van Aarle, B., J. Engwerda, and J. Plasmans (2001),” Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Interaction in the EMU: A Dynamic Game Approach", CESifo Working Paper No. 437

Woodford, M. (1996),”Control of Public Debt: A requirement for price stability,” NBER

Working Paper 5684, West African Monetary Institute (2005), “A Study on the State of Preparedness of the

West African Monetary Zone Countries for Monetary Union”, West African Monetary Institute (2006), “Macroeconomic Convergence Report” Accra. West African Monetary Institute (2009), “Macroeconomic Convergence Report” Accra.