AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and...

27
State Capacity and Deregulation: The Philippines and Indonesia Compared Asuncion M. Sebastian Comparative Politics DVS540P Dr. Antoinette Raquiza April 13, 2012

description

Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia compared both at the country and at the (selected) industry levels.

Transcript of AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and...

Page 1: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

 

State  Capacity  and  Deregulation:                                                The  Philippines  and  Indonesia  Compared                

Asuncion  M.  Sebastian                                                                                                                                                                                                                Comparative  Politics  DVS540P                                                                                                                                                                                                              Dr.  Antoinette  Raquiza                                                                                                                                                                                                                    April  13,  2012  

Page 2: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

 

 

State  Capacity  and  Deregulation:  The  Philippines  and  Indonesia  Compared    Introduction    

Building   on   the   works   of   Fukuyama   (2004)   and   Williamson   (2003),   this   paper  

discusses   state   capacity   and   deregulation—one   of   the   three   major   thrusts   of  

structural  adjustment  program  (SAP),  the  two  others  being  trade  liberalization  and  

privatization.  The  SAP  was  embodied  in  the  Washington  Consensus  implemented  in  

Latin  America;  however,  essentially  the  same  program  was  adapted  by  the  member-­‐

countries  of  the  Association  of  the  South  East  Asian  Nations  (ASEAN)  in  the  nineties,  

which   became   a   period   of   opening   of   their   economies   to   global   trade   and  

competition.    

 

Using   the   deregulation   experiences   of   the   Philippines   and   Indonesia,   this   paper  

argues   that   1)   state   capacity,   specifically   its   aspect   of   organizational   design   and  

management,   is   necessary   for   deregulation   programs   to   achieve   the   desired  

development   goals   and   2)   technological   innovations   resulting   from   deregulation  

break  down  monopolies  and  promote  market  efficiency,  thereby  contributing  to  the  

attainment  of  those  goals.  These  arguments  are  represented  in  the  diagram  below.  

 

 

Page 3: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 2 of 26

Scope  

Trade   liberalization,   deregulation,   and   privatization   are   different   yet   interrelated  

concepts   and   are   often   implemented   together   under   the   SAP.   This   paper   focuses  

only  on  deregulation,  herein  defined  as  the  “easing  of  barriers  to  entry  and  exit  [into  

the  market,  without]  abolishing  regulations  designed  for  safety  and  environmental  

reasons”   (Williamson,   The   Washington   Consensus   and   Beyond,   2003)   and   “are  

intended   to   influence   how   firms   operate,   (having)   no   controls   over   capital  

movements”  (Williamson,  Beijing  Consensus  Versus  Washington  Consensus,  2010).  

Since   deregulation   does   not   involve   transfer   and/of   exchange   of   assets,   its  

implementation  is   less  complicated  and  controversial,  and  its  supporting  evidence,  

more  transparent  than  that  of  trade  liberalization  and  privatization.    

 

The  discussion  will  not  cover  the  financial  sector,  as  Indonesia  was  way  ahead  of  the  

Philippines  in  opening  its  capital  markets,  making  their  cases  incomparable.  It  will  

instead   focus  on   select   industries   that   require  heavy   investment  on   infrastructure  

thus   justifying   their   original   state   as   monopolistic   markets   (or   the   “natural  

monopoly”   industries).   These   industries   include   air   transportation,   automobile,  

telecommunications,  and  electric  power  generation.  Oil   industry   is  not   included   in  

the   analysis   because   Indonesia   is   a   net   oil   exporter   while   the   Philippines,   in  

contrast,  is  a  net  oil  importer.  

 

Rationale  for  the  Cases  

This  paper  presents  Philippines  and  Indonesia  as  cases  of  similar  characteristics  and  

contexts   with   differing   results   of   implementation   of   deregulation,   with   the   latter  

having  economic  and  social  performance  than  the  former.    

 

Geographically,  both  Philippines  and  Indonesia  are  archipelagic—the  Philippines  is  

composed  of  7,107   islands  and   Indonesia,  13,670.   (Buendia,  2002)  Both   countries  

are  also  susceptible   to  natural  calamities—typhoons  and  volcanic  eruptions   in   the  

Philippines,   earthquakes   and   tsunamis   in   Indonesia.     These   features  pose   a  major  

Page 4: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 3 of 26

challenge   to   industries   that   require  heavy   investment   in  physical   infrastructure   in  

order  to  move  goods  and  service,  including  those  cited  earlier  as  part  of  this  study—

air  transportation,  automobile,  telecommunications,  and  electric  power  generation.    

 

Demographically,  both  countries  have  diverse  cultures,  languages,  and  religions.  The  

Philippine  population  is  estimated  at  77  million  (17th  largest  in  the  world  as  of  2002,  

which   has   grown   to   94   million   by   2010)   with   110   ethno-­‐linguistic   and   cultural  

groups  spread  over  77  provinces  (as  of  2002,  which  has  numbered  80  in  2011).  On  

the  other  hand,  Indonesia  has  a  population  of  213  million  (4th  largest  in  the  world  as  

of   2002,  which  has   grown   to   over   248  million   by   2012),   speaking   250   languages,  

spread   over   32   provinces.   (Buendia,   2002)   This,   combined   with   the   countries’  

geographic  features,  makes  disparity  in  development  an  inevitable  problem.  

 

Politically   integrating   a   diverse   people   is   also   concern   for   the   government.  

Historically,  neither  country  has  been  a  nation  prior  to  colonial  rule  of  the  European  

countries,  which   gave   both   countries   common   experience   (or   common   enemy   for  

that   matter)   that   compelled   the   people   to   unite.   The   Philippines   was   under   the  

Spanish  rule  for  more  than  370  years  (400  years  of  colonialism  to  include  American  

occupation)  while   Indonesia  was  under   the  Dutch  power   for  350  years.   (Buendia,  

2002)     The   post-­‐colonial   state   capacity   building   for   the   two   countries   should  

therefore  not  differ  much.    

 

Consequently,   both   countries   are   characterized   by   clientelism,   patronage,   and  

corruption   so   much   so   that   the   interests   of   the   government   and   those   of   large  

businesses  cannot  readily  be  separated,  and  that  public  economic  policies  reflect  the  

interest  of   the   few  elites.   (Ghosh,  1996)   In   the  Philippines,   the  “incredibly  corrupt  

Marcos   dictatorship”   was   overthrown   by   the   Aquino   administration   that   did   not  

have   the   ability   to   eradicate   the   rent-­‐seeking   behavior   of   the   president’s   kin.  

(Brilliantes,   1993)   In   Indonesia,   the   first   family   has   “a   stake   in   almost   every  

important   commodity   or   service   in   the   country”.   Thus   some   people   viewed  

deregulation  as  a  test  to  the  president’s  willingness  to  sacrifice  his  and  his  family’s  

Page 5: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 4 of 26

interest—the  results  were  mixed.  (Liddle,  1988)  While  in  many  cases  the  monopoly  

markets   are   “natural   monopolies”,   Indonesia’s   was   known   to   be   “plastic  

monopolies”  because   these  were  monopolies  only  by   the  virtue  of  being   linked   to  

the  first  family.  (Soesastro,  1989)    

 

In  the  eighties  and  nineties,   Indonesia  was  widely  known  to  be  more  corrupt  than  

the  Philippines  with  its  Vice  President  admitting  that  corruption  reached  “epidemic  

proportions   in   the   bureaucracy   and   the   business.”   (Bello,   2009)   Thus,   corruption  

could  not  be  blamed  for  the  Philippines’  ineffective  deregulation  and  poor  economic  

performance  in  general.  “Kung  walang  corrupt,  walang  mahirap”  may  not  hold  water  

if  various  economies  like  Indonesia  would  be  examined.  

 

However,   Philippines   and   Indonesia   also   differ   in   some   ways.   Under   the   post-­‐

colonial   regime,   the   Philippines   adopted   the   unitary   structure   of   governance   and  

institutions   of   democracy   from   the   Americans.   However,   this   kind   of   democracy,  

opined  Lee  Kuan  Yew  of  Singapore  in  his  analysis  of  why  the  country  has  difficulty  

in   economic   take-­‐off,   does   not  work   in   the   Philippines.   (Brilliantes,   1993)   On   the  

other  hand,  Indonesia,  under  the  powerful  leadership  of  its  first  president  Sukarno,  

used  the  indigenous  village  system  of  governance,  which  espoused  functional  rather  

than  party  representation,  and  consensus  deliberation  rather  than  partisan  election.  

(Buendia,  2002)  This  kind  of  orientation  could  explain  why  the  policies,  especially  

those  under  the  second  president  Suharto  were  pro-­‐indigenous  and  protectionist  in  

nature.    

 

As   a   reflection   of   the   countries’   political   system   and   culture,   the   Indonesian  

government   as   a   whole   determined   who   the   “beneficiaries”   of   structural  

adjustments  would  be  (which  were  the  conglomerates)  while  in  the  Philippines,   in  

the  absence  of  a  cohesive  political  system,  patterns  of  recipients  was  “less  planned,  

less   clear,   and   less   predictable…with   different   groups   (winning   some   and   losing  

some)”.   (Milne,   1992)  This,   however,   does  not  mean   that   Indonesia’s   institutional  

design   (as   discussed   by   Fukuyama)   is   any   stronger   than   the   Philippines’s.   The  

Page 6: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 5 of 26

former’s   dependence   on   the   power   of   its   leader,   Suharto,   rendered   the   state  

unresponsive  unless  Suharto  personally  gave  approval;  thus  the  nation  was  shaken  

when  Suharto  fell  critically  ill  in  1997.  (Bird,  1997)  

 

In   terms   of   the   market,   Indonesia   is   different   from   the   Philippines   in   that   the  

number   of   local/indigenous   firms   is   smaller   and   the   local   Chinese   are   less   well  

assimilated.   In   Indonesia,   too,   it   is   a   basic   objective   to   promote   local  

entrepreneurship   to   accelerate   transfer   of   the   management   of   foreign-­‐owned  

enterprises  into  local,  private  enterprises.  (Milne,  1992)  

 

Theoretical  Background  

Fukuyama   (2004)   argued   that   there   was   nothing   wrong   in   the   Washington  

Consensus  per  se,  only  that  as  the  states  needed  to  be  cut  back  in  certain  areas—for  

example,   through   reduction   of   subsidies   and   tariff   protection,   privatization,   and  

deregulation—they   also   needed   to   be   strengthened   in   others.   He   defined   state  

strength   or   capacity   as   its   “power   or   ability   to   plan   and   execute   policies   and   to  

enforce  laws  cleanly  and  transparently”.  The  four  main  components  of  state  capacity  

are  the  following:  1)  organizational  design  and  management;  2)  institutional  design  

or  political  system;  3)  basis  of  legitimization;  and  4)  social  and  cultural  factors.    Of  

these   components,   what   is   deemed   most   appropriate   in   the   discussion   of  

deregulation   is   organizational   design   and   management,   which   combines   the  

discipline   of   management,   public   administration,   and   economics.     Moreover,  

Fukuyama   recommended   that   developing   states   focus   on   this   aspect   on   state  

building  because   it   can  be   “manipulated  and  built”.  Hence,   the  analysis  of   the   two  

country   cases—Philippines   and   Indonesia—shall   center   on   this   particular  

component  of  state  capacity.    

 

Milne   (1992),   supportive   of   Fukuyama’s   point,   asserted   that   the   nature   of  

government   largely   dictates   whether   (structural   adjustment   program)   can   or  

cannot   be   implemented   consistently   and   successfully.   Bello   (2009)   also   cited   the  

Page 7: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 6 of 26

case  of  the  Philippines’  neighboring  ASEAN  countries:  these  states  may  have  played  

a   less   aggressive   role   but   an   active   state   posture  manifested   in   industrial   policy,  

protectionism,   mercantilism,   and   intrusive   regulation   was   central   in   their  

industrialization.  

 

In   support  of   these  authors’   argument,   this  paper  proposes   that   state   capacity   is  

necessary   for   the   scope-­reduction   programs   such   as   deregulation   to   be  

effective   in   achieving   national   development   goals.   Goals   may   vary   across  

nations:  market  efficiency  as  in  the  case  of  the  Philippines;  or  development  of  non-­‐

oil  export  capacity  for  macroeconomic  stability  or  strengthening  of  local  enterprises  

in  the  case  of  Indonesia;  or  provision  of  quality  and  reliable  supply  of  basic  needs  to  

the  public  for  some,  for  exmaple.    

 

Looking   back   at   the  Washington  Consensus,   following   are   the   lessons   that   can   be  

culled  from  the  experience:  1)  income  distribution  must  be  considered  (Williamson,  

The   Washington   Consensus   and   Beyond,   2003);   2)   the   program   should   be   done  

during   the   period   of   rapid   growth,   not   crisis   (Williamson,   The   Washington  

Consensus  and  Beyond,  2003);  3)  the  idea  of  deregulation  should  not  be  taken  too  

broadly  (Williamson,  Beijing  Consensus  Versus  Washington  Consensus,  2010);  and  

4)  having  a  government   that  delivers   is   important   (Williamson,  Beijing  Consensus  

Versus   Washington   Consensus,   2010).   These   caveats,   which   could   very   well   fall  

under   the   banner   of   “organizational   design   and  management”,  will   be   included   in  

the  country  analyses.  

 

Bowen   and   Leinbach   (1995)   concluded   thus:   where   public   enterprise   is   natural  

monopoly,   deregulation   may   not   produce   the   desired   increase   in   competition.   A  

natural  monopoly   is   characterized   by   scale   economies   required   for   efficiency   and  

profitability  to  recoup  huge  investments  in  capital,  thus  providing  “natural”  barriers  

to   entry   of   other,   most   often   smaller,   players.   Examples   are   petroleum   refining,  

tobacco   products,   glass   products,   and   non-­‐ferrous   metals.   Other   industries   may  

appear   to   be   natural   monopolies   when   in   fact   the   market   simply   happens   to   be  

Page 8: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 7 of 26

relatively   small   for   a   large   firm—among   these   industries   are   professional  

equipment,  footwear,  ceramics,  and  metal  furniture.  (Hill,  2003)    

 

Although   the   above   observation   on   natural   monopolies   may   not   be   completely  

inaccurate,  this  paper  further  argues  that  technological  innovation  that  results  

from   deregulated,   competitive   environment   breaks   down   monopolies,  

although   a   deregulated,   competitive   environment   does   not   always   produce  

technological  innovation.  Innovation  allows  the  players  to  compete  in  aspects  other  

than  price;   if   products   and   services   are  undifferentiated   and  players   can   compete  

only  through  cutthroat  pricing—which  shrewd  businesspeople  will  least  likely  do—

then   the   industry   may   only   consolidate   into   a   duopoly,   or   at   best   oligopoly   and  

cartels,   despite   deregulation.   Perhaps,   the   role   of   technological   innovation   in  

determining  the  success  of  structural  policies  is  this  paper’s  main  contribution.  

 

Deregulation  in  Indonesia  

The   country’s   dependence   on   oil   revenues   and   the   decline   in   world   oil   prices   in  

1986,  coupled  with  the  rise  in  interest  rates  and  the  appreciation  of  yen,  caused  the  

rupiah  to  plummet  and  Indonesia’s  foreign  debt  to  bloat.  At  this  time,  several  major  

reforms   were   introduced,   including   modern   tax   system,   promotion   of   non-­‐oil  

exports,   reduction   of   trade   barriers   or   select   products,   and   deregulation   of   select  

industries   (e.g.   service   industries   remained   closed   to   foreign   investors   and  

agricultural   and   handicraft   sectors   to   medium-­‐   and   large-­‐scale   enterprises,   both  

domestic  and  foreign).  (Fane,  1996)  Thus,  “Indonesian  deregulation  can  be  seen  as  a  

pragmatic   response   to   an   economic   situation…(and)   Indonesia’s   policymaking  

processes   should   not   be   viewed   as   mechanical   or   unilateral”.   (Soesastro,   1989;  

Bowen  &  Leinbach,  1995)    

 

Further,   since   Indonesia   had   other   sources   of   credit,   it   was   not   beholden   to   the  

development  agencies  for  funds;  and  because  the  adjustment  occurred  without  the  

tutelage  of  the  International  Monetary  Fund  and  the  World  Bank,  it  could  afford  to  

Page 9: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 8 of 26

ignore   (and   it   did)   certain   features   of   the   package   and   deregulation   remained  

minimal  (if  not  selective).  (Ghosh,  1996)  

 

The   eighties   were   known   to   be   Indonesia’s   “decade   of   deregulation”.   (Soesastro,  

1989)   The   country   implemented   deregulation   more   widely   than   privatization   in  

promoting  market   efficiency,   for   the   latter  may   actually  mean   “   strengthening   the  

market  at  the  expense  of  the  state.”  (Milne,  1992;  Fane,  1996)  In  Fukuyama’s  term,  

privatization  may  mean  limiting  state  scope  while  also  diminishing  state  capacity.    

 

What  was   also   surprising  was   that  while   other   countries   reacted   to   the   shock   by  

imposing   exchange   controls   and   import   licensing,   Indonesia   emphasized  

deregulation.   As   to   why   the   country   did   not   implement   such   open   policy   in   the  

earlier  decades,  often  the  answer  given   is  “bad  times  mean  good  policies”.   (Liddle,  

1988;  Fane,  1996;  Bird,  1997)    

 

Although   the   state   implemented   market-­‐oriented   policies   in   the   eighties   and  

nineties,   up   to   Suharto’s   term   in   May   1998,   the   state   had   remained   the   most  

important   economic   actor.   These   market-­‐oriented   policies   were   aimed   at  

“deepening   the   country’s   industrial   structure,   creating   a   heavy-­‐industry   nucleus  

around  which  to  center  the  economy”.  This  strategy  included  the  development  of  an  

automobile   industry,   an   integrated   steel   complex,   a   shipbuilding   complex,   and   an  

aircraft   industry.   (Bello,   2009)   Alongside   with   this   program   were   the  

implementation  of   local  content  schemes  and  selective  tax  exemptions  intended  to  

protect   individual   firms.   (Fane,   1996)   Indonesia’s   strategic   and   selective   policies  

only   show   that   the   country   did   not   adopt   structural   adjustment   lock   stock   and  

barrel—again  an  indication  of  state  capacity.  

 

Indeed,   the   country’s   deregulation   policies  were  well   thought   out.   In   general,   the  

state   mandates   that   the   benefits   of   deregulation   and   economic   growth   must   be  

widely   and   evenly   spread,   and   that   the   development   of   the   rural   areas   should   be  

considered  continuously.  (Soesastro,  1989)  In  fact,  the  economic  nationalists  (to  be  

Page 10: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 9 of 26

described  in  the  next  paragraph)  feared  that  foreign  interest  may  dominate  the  key  

sectors   and   that   wealth   discrepancies   between   the   conglomerates   and   the  

disadvantaged   group   may   become   worse   under   deregulation.   (Hein,   1990)  

Specifically,   certain   caveats  were   highlighted:   1)   if   singularly   pursued   to   promote  

non-­‐oil   export,   deregulation  may   lead   to  new  distortions;   2)   if   focused  heavily   on  

manufacturing,  it  could  lead  to  bias  against  the  agricultural  sector;  3)  deregulation’s  

initial   impact  was  on   the  psyche   level,   that   is,   business   climate  had  become  more  

favorable  with   its   implementation;   and  4)   there   is   a  need   to  assess  deregulation’s  

impact   at   the   industry   or   sectoral   level,   especially   in   the   non-­‐tradable   markets.  

(Soesastro,  1989)  

 

Indonesia’s   organizational   design   and   management   capacity   is   evident   in   the  

country’s  political  structure.  The  head  of  the  state  deals  with  two  competing  groups  

of   advisers:   1)   the   technocrats,   many   of   whom   are   professional   economists   that  

favor   market   forces   or   neoliberalism;   and   2)   the   economic   nationalists,   many   of  

whom   are   engineers   who   promote   large-­‐scale,   capital-­‐intensive   projects   using  

advance   technology.   The   latter   group  believed   that   such   projects   should   be   state-­‐

owned   and   may   need   direct   government   subsidies   and   protection.   (Fane,   1996)  

They  argued  that  it  is  worth  paying  the  short-­‐term  costs  of  protectionist  policies  to  

promote  the  development  of  state  enterprises  and  indigenous  (non-­‐Chinese  locals)  

entrepreneurs   who   cannot   as   yet   compete   in   either   domestic   or   world   markets.  

(Soesastro,   1989)   It   appears   then   that   Indonesia’s   economic   development  

framework  is  largely  influenced  by  the  economic  nationalists.    

 

As  of  2000,  the  following  industries  in  the  country  had  been  deregulated:  petroleum  

and   natural   gas   refineries,   electric   power   generation,   telecommunications,  

automobile,   and   certain   agricultural   commodities.   (Asia   Pacific   Economic  

Cooperation,  2000)    

 

Despite   the   favored   groups’   flexing   of   political   muscles   to   seize   business  

opportunities,  the  economic  policy  reforms  achieved  the  development  of  a  growing  

Page 11: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 10 of 26

non-­‐oil  export  market  at  a  minimum.  (Liddle,  1988)  According  to  Soesastro  (1989),  

the  aim  of  deregulation  is  improved  economic  performance  through  a  more  efficient  

resource  allocation  and  the  most  immediate  measure  of  its  success  is  the  growth  of  

the   non-­‐oil   exports   (hitting   USD   1   billlion   monthly   in   1988   and   contributing   60  

percent   to   the   country’s   total   export   earnings   in   1989).   The   country’s   gross  

domestic  product  (GDP)  grew  by  5.4  percent   from  1979  to  1989  and  by  7  percent  

annually  on  average   from  1990   to  1994.  Likewise,  poverty   incidence  decreased   in  

the  rural  area  from  40.4  percent  in  1976  to  16.4  in  1987  and  in  the  urban  area  from  

38.8   percent   to   20.1   percent   over   the   same   period.   (Ghosh,   1996)   With   these  

figures,   one   can   conclude   that  deregulation  worked   in   Indonesia   in  propelling   the  

country’s  economic  growth  and  without  necessarily  aggravating  poverty  (although  

there  could  be  other  factors  that  have  influenced  the  decline  in  poverty  incidence).  

In  fact,  while  there  is  a  general  perception  that  the  poor  bore  the  costs  of  structural  

adjustments,   Balisacan   (1995)   cited   Indonesia   as   one   of   the   countries   whose  

transition  has  not  been  anti-­‐poor.  

 

These  results   therefore  challenges  Williamson’s  (2003)  proposition  that  structural  

adjustment  should  be  done  during  rapid  growth,  not  during  crisis.  The  whole  ASEAN  

region   was   suffering   the   consequence   of   international   recessionary   trends   in   the  

eighties  when  Indonesia  started  its  deregulation  policies.  (Bello,  2009)  Further,  the  

outcomes   serve   as   proof   of   the   state’s   capacity   to   formulate   and   implement  

appropriate  policies,  even  at  least  “during  bad  times”.  

 

Deregulation  in  the  Philippines  

While  Indonesia’s  decision  to  adopt  structural  changes  was  deemed  pragmatic,  the  

Philippines’s  was  partly  due  to  its  international  commitments  and  partly  due  to  its  

own   initiative,   expecting   that   open   economy  would   lead   to   competition,  which   in  

turn  would   lead   to  economic  efficiency.   (Orbeta)  With   this  difference   in   intention,  

the  Philippines  was  at  a  disadvantage   in   that   it  did  not  have  as  much   freehand  as  

Indonesia  to  select  and/or  calibrate  programs  that  would  suit  its  context.    

Page 12: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 11 of 26

 

Structural  adjustment  in  the  country  was  designed  to  “alter  the  balance  between  the  

market   and   the   state   in   the   Philippine   economy   in   order   to   promote   economic  

efficiency”.  (Bello,  2009)  Its  implementation  was  done  in  three  phases:  1)  from  1980  

to  1983  when   the  emphasis  was   trade   liberalization;  2)   from  1983   to  1992,  when  

debt  repayment  became  government’s  focus;  and  3)  from  1992  until  the  turn  of  the  

century,   when   free-­‐market   transformation,   rapid   deregulation,   privatization,   and  

trade   and   investment   liberalization   characterized   the   economy.   Structural  

adjustment  in  the  second  and  third  phases  was  seen  as  a  precondition  for  economic  

growth   and   debt   repayment   as   an   “unpleasant   but   temporary   condition”.   (Bello,  

2009)  

 

Under   the   regime   of   President   Fidel   Ramos   beginning   in   1992,   the   country’s  

economic  strategy  centered  on  economic  liberalization,  with  “concerted  attacks”  on  

cartels   and   monopolies.   In   his   inauguration,   the   President   explained   that   the  

political   dominance   of   the   oligarchic   groups—the   country’s   dominant   commercial  

families—is   the   reason  why   the  Philippines   lagged   so   far   behind   the  Asian   tigers.  

(de  Dios  &  Hutchcroft,  2003)  

 

Bello   (2009)   argued   that   the   slack   in   the   Philippines’   performance   could   not   be  

attributed  to  pace  of  economic  liberalization,  as  the  country’s  start-­‐off  point  did  not  

differ  from  its  neighbors.  Neither  could  it  be  attributed  to  non-­‐interventionist  states  

among   its   neighbors   because   they   are  more   intrusively   interventionists,   including  

Indonesia,  than  the  Philippines.  He  cited  two  reasons  for  the  Philippines’s  below-­‐par  

economic   performance   thus:   1)   the   national   priority   of   debt   repayment   that  

signaled   low   purchasing   power   of   the   Philippines   as   a   market   and   thus   failed   to  

attract   investors;   and   2)   doctrinal   distortion   that   brought   indiscriminate  

liberalization   instead   of   the   state   carefully   calibrating   policies—a   similar   point  

raised   by  Williamson   (2003)   regarding  Washington   Consensus   in   that   the   policy  

reforms   set  were  needed  by  a  particular   region  at   a  particular   time  and   that   they  

were  not  an  ideological  agenda  to  be  imposed  on  all  countries  at  any  and  all  times.    

Page 13: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 12 of 26

The  reforms  led  to  improvements  in  competition  but  the  gains  were  not  as  much  as  

expected,  according   to  Orbeta   (n.d.).  The  author  believed   that   this  was  so  because  

the   nature   and   extent   of   deregulation   may   have   been   inadequate   and   that   the  

government  continued  to  control  further  entry  and  to  regulate  prices.  These  claims  

may   not   prove   accurate   because   in   1996   Asia   Money   Magazine   considered   the  

Philippines   as   “one   of   the  most   deregulated   in  Asia”   (The   Philippines  Back   in   the  

Spotlight,  1996).  Besides,  the  Indonesian  government,  with  its  deliberately  selective  

deregulation  and  high  level  of  regulation  even  after  the  reforms,  was  able  to  achieve  

the  objectives  of  its  economic  reforms.  Orbeta  also  criticized  the  Philippines’s  local  

content   requirement   as   hindrance   to   firms’   access   to   more   competitive   import  

products—the   same   policy   that   worked  well   in   strengthening   the   position   of   the  

indigenous  entrepreneurs  in  Indonesia.    

 

In   the  end,  however,  Orbeta  pointed  out   the  country’s   two  main  challenges,  which  

this   paper   supports:   1)   too  many   implementing   agencies   results   in   lack   of   focus,  

expertise,   and  accountability;   and  2)   there   is  a  danger   that   regulators  become   too  

intimate  with   the   industry  players  and   thus  become  eventually  beholden   to   them.  

These  points  are  apparent  indicators  of  the  state’s  weak  capacity.    

 

Sadly,   the   results   of   the   three   decades   of   structural   adjustment   were   damaged  

industries  such  as  textile,  rubber,  and  ceramics,  among  others,  while  only  a  modest  

level   of   exportation   in   garments   and   electronic   assembly   was   established.   (Bello,  

2009)  Aggregate  poverty  also  rose  during  the  period  while  GDP  remained  at  the  3-­‐

percent  range  from  1988  to  1991.  (Balisacan,  1995)  

 

Deregulation  of  Select  Industries    

What   can  be   culled   from   the  previous  discussion   is   that   Indonesia  has  been  more  

successful  than  the  Philippines  in  using  deregulation  as  a  strategy  to  achieve  both  its  

economic  goal  (i.e.  development  of  the  non-­‐oil  export)  and  social  goal  (i.e.  wide  and  

even  distribution  of  benefits  of  deregulation  and  economic  growth).  The  state  was  

Page 14: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 13 of 26

able  to  do  this  because  of  its  strong  capacity  to  plan  and  execute  policies,  although  

not  necessarily  enforcing  laws  cleanly  and  transparently,  as  Fukuyama  defined  state  

capacity.    

 

However,   it   cannot   be   assumed   that   regulatory   agencies   in   all   industries   in   both  

countries   have   uniform   capacities.   Although   Fukuyama   (2004)   emphasized   that  

state  capacity  should  be  viewed  at  the  central  government  level  and  not  at  the  level  

of   its   various   agencies,   the   implementation   issues   related   to   regulation  would   be  

better   analyzed   at   the   agency   level   that   governs   the   industries.   The   following  

sections   show  how   Indonesia   became   successful   in   deregulating   the   air   transport  

and   automobile   industries,   and   the   Philippines   in   telecommunications;   and   how  

both  did  not  quite  succeed  in  the  electric  power  generation.    

 

Air  Transportation  

Many   of   the   Asian   newly   industrialized   countries   (NICs)   established   their   flag  

carriers  during  the  post-­‐war  period.  At  the  time,  the  states  could  not  rely  on  private  

capital  to  create  airlines  that  would  support  their  national  objectives;  besides,  it  was  

of  ideological  importance  for  the  states,  at  least  at  that  time,  to  keep  direct  control  

over   key   sectors   of   the   economy.   Further,   the   states   had   to   ensure   that   private  

companies  would  not  exploit  monopolistic  profits  and  that  the  small,  less  profitable  

markets,   which   are   usually   present   in   developing   economies,   would   be   served.  

Ironically,   the   Philippines’s   flag   carrier   Philippine   Airlines   (PAL),   established   in  

1941,  was  the  only  privately  owned  in  ASEAN  region  put  up  by  industrialists.  Other  

Asian  countries’  flag  carriers—Thailand  (1947),  Korea  (1949),  China  (1950,  closely  

linked   to   the   Taiwanese   government),   Indonesia   (1950),   Malaysia   (1972),   and  

Singapore  (1972)—were  all  state-­‐owned.  (Bowen  &  Leinbach,  1995)  

 

In   1973,   PAL   was   awarded   a   domestic   monopoly   in   exchange   for   its   service   to  

unprofitable   routes,   and  was   eventually   nationalized   in   1977.  While   PAL  was   the  

region’s   premier   international   carrier   in   the   early   post-­‐war   period,   it   was  

Page 15: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 14 of 26

overshadowed   by   its   neighboring   countries   by   the   eighties.   In   1988,   PAL’s  

monopoly  was  revoked  and  in  1992,  in  line  with  the  Aquino  government’s  thrust  to  

dismantle   state-­‐owned   enterprises,   the   flag   carrier   was   brought   back   to   private  

ownership   through   the   sale   of   shares   to   a   consortium   consisting   of   a   few   major  

players   (in   contrast   to   Singapore   Airline’s   privatization   via   public-­‐share   offerings  

that   prevented   concentration   of   ownership   among   few   individuals).     (Bowen   &  

Leinbach,  1995)  No  new  entrant  in  the  market  came  until  the  mid-­‐nineties  with  the  

launching  of  Cebu  Pacific—a  classic  example  that  deregulation  does  not  necessarily  

attract  new  players  or  investors.  One  may  ask  then  if  the  decision  to  nationalize  PAL  

and   later   to   privatize   it,   through   sale   of   shares   to   few   individuals   at   that,   was  

grounded  on  pragmatic  economic  principles.  

 

In   the   case  of   Indonesia,   the   state  deregulated   the   airline   industry   in   the   eighties,  

opening   it   to   private   players—which   were   all   related   to   the   President’s   family—

while   keeping   Garuda,   the   flag   carrier,   under   state   ownership.   However,   Garuda  

remained  protected  despite   the  presence  of  multiple   carriers.    Until   1989,  Garuda  

was   the   only   Indonesian   carrier   allowed   to   operate   jet   aircraft.   Moreover,   other  

privately-­‐owned   airlines   were   not   allowed   to   undercut   Garuda   by   more   than   15  

percent,  were  restricted  to  operate  in  less  profitable  routes,  and  were  allowed  to  fly  

only   three   times   for   every   seven   domestic   flights   served   by   Garuda.   (Bowen   &  

Leinbach,  1995)  

 

Sempati,   owned  by   a   conglomerate   controlled  by  one  of   President   Suharto’s   sons,  

entered   the   Indonesian   domestic  market   in   1989   and   the   international  market   in  

1991.   Through   its   international   operations,   the   private   company   acquired   foreign  

currencies   that   enabled   it   to   acquire   Dutch-­‐made   Fokker   aircrafts.   The   Dutch  

manufacturer   in   turn  partnered  with   a   local  manufacturer   IPTN   for  production  of  

certain   components   of   the   Fokker   jets.   Thus,   in   the   end,   these   private   company-­‐

initiated   arrangements   facilitated   technology   transfer   to   Indonesia.   (Bowen   &  

Leinbach,  1995)  

 

Page 16: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 15 of 26

As   pointed   out   by   Bowen   and   Leinbach   (1995),   political   leverage   in   the   airline  

industry  may  come  from  two  sources:  1)  a  firm’s  political  clout  based  on  its  ability  

to  fulfill  important  government  policy  objectives  and  2)  leadership  of  the  airline  by  

politically  influential  personalities.  While  Sempati  illustrates  the  first  case,  PAL  is  an  

example  of  the  second.  No  hard  data  on  these  airlines’  business  and  developmental  

performances   were   provided   but   the   fact   that   Indonesia   has   overtaken   the  

Philippines  in  terms  of  both  access/routes  in  the  international  flights  and  number  of  

players   in   the   industry   proves   that   deregulation   has   worked   better   in   Indonesia  

than  in  the  Philippines.    

 

The   airline   industry   case   thus   supports   the   arguments   that   1)   who   owns   the  

enterprises   is   not   as   crucial   as   the   capacity   of   the   state   to   define   development  

objectives,  set  sound  policy  framework,  and  regulate  and  2)  that  technology  plays  a  

key  role  in  breaking  monopolistic  barriers  and  achieving  efficiency,  which  could  not  

be  achieved  solely  through  deregulation  of  the  market.    

 

Automobile  

The  Philippine  automobile  industry  suffered  the  same  fate  as  the  airline.  Despite  its  

early  lead  in  the  region  in  the  sixties,  its  operations  proved  inefficient  beginning  in  

the  seventies  and  by  mid-­‐nineties  it  was  overtaken  by  Indonesia’s  production,  which  

was  three  times  more  than  the  Philippines’s  output.  (Hill,  2003)    

 

Indonesia,   on   the   other   hand,   protected   and   strengthened   its   deregulated  

automobile   industry   through   the   national   car   policy.   The   policy   stipulated   that  

producer   must   be   100   percent   Indonesian-­‐owned,   must   use   Indonesian   brand  

name,  must  develop   local   technology,   and  must   satisfy   local-­‐content   requirements  

(that  is,  from  20  percent  by  the  end  of  first  year,  to  40  percent  by  the  end  of  second  

year,  to  60  percent  by  the  end  of  third  year).  (Fane,  1996)  

 

Page 17: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 16 of 26

Again,  the  same  arguments  are  supported  by  the  experience  of  the  two  countries  in  

automobile  industry:  1)  ownership  of  enterprises  is  not  as  crucial  as  the  capacity  of  

the  state   in  organizational  design  and  management  and,   in   this  case,   in  promoting  

efficiency  despite  protectionist  policies;  and  2)  that  technological  innovation,  more  

than  deregulation  policy   that  does  not  automatically  attract   investors,   is  crucial   in  

development.    

 

Telecommunications  

Prior   to   deregulation,   the   privately   owned   Philippine   Long   Distance   Company  

(PLDT)  enjoyed  a  monopoly  power  in  the  telecommunications  industry  for  65  years.  

With   the   underdeveloped   industry   then,   telephone   density  was   around   1   percent  

and   complaints   on   poor   service   quality   was   estimated   at   17   percent   per   month,  

higher  than  Indonesia’s  9  percent.  (Abrenica  &  Llanto,  2003)    

 

Mercado-­‐Aldaba   (2000)   blamed   it   on   the   misguided   policy   and   the   weak   and  

corrupt  regulatory  structure  of  the  government.  The  opening  of  the  market  to  new  

players  in  1991  and  subsequently  the  mandate  of  interconnection  among  networks  

in   1993   eroded   the   dominance   of   PLDT   and   created   nine   new,   privately   owned  

telecommunications  companies.  The  country  was  recognized  to  be  among  the   first  

11  countries  to  allow  competition  in  the  local  facilities  and  among  the  first  14  to  de-­‐

monopolize   the   provision   of   international   telephone   services.   (Abrenica  &   Llanto,  

2003)  The  result  was  an  increase  in  telephone  density  of  8.07  percent  in  1997  and  

in   absolute   growth   in   mainlines   from   3.2   percent   before   deregulation   to   18.2  

percent  after  policy  reforms.  (Mercado-­‐Albada,  2000)    

 

The  emergence  of  mobile  technology  was  also  instrumental  in  breaking  the  barriers  

inherent   in   telecommunications,   especially   in   archipelagic   countries   like   the  

Philippines  and  Indonesia.  Since  the  digital  technology  does  not  require  land-­‐based  

infrastructure  (i.e.  networks  of  copper  wires)  for  connection,  it  is  able  to  reach  the  

far-­‐flung   islands   and   highlands,   thus   addressing   the   age-­‐old   issue   of   access   to  

Page 18: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 17 of 26

services   in   the   country.   Aside   from   the   absence   of   physical   barriers   in   digital  

technology,   the   carrying   capacity   of   mobile   transmission   towers   is   several   times  

larger   than   that   of   fixed   lines   so   that   the   service   fees   come   out   very   cheap,   thus  

addressing  the  problem  of  affordability.  Finally,  the  short  message  service  (SMS  or  

“texting”)   feature  of  the  mobile  technology—which  has  gone  way  too  low  with  the  

unlimited   packages   offered   by   the   mobile   companies—combined   with   the  

affordable   mobile   handsets—again,   a   product   of   technological   innovation—has  

redefined   the  way   people   communicate.  Whatever   problems   there   still   are   in   the  

fixed   line   segment   in   the   Philippines,   they   seem   to   have   been   addressed   by   the  

presence   of   other   means   of   communication,   thanks   to   mobile   technology.   Today,  

there   are   many   available   fixed   lines   that   remained   unsubscribed   because   of   the  

presence  of  mobile  services.  

 

However,  this  technological  innovation  has  regulatory  implications  as  well.  With  the  

process   becoming   more   complex   with   the   fast-­‐developing   technology,   regulators  

also   need   to   up   their   technical   skills   to   catch   up  with   it.   Since  mobile   technology  

quickly   became   popular   in   the   Philippine   market,   “regulators   faced   a   unique  

challenge  in  addressing  interconnection  problems  of  mobile  carriers—prior  to  this,  

no   other   market   in   the   world   had   drafted   and   enforced   rules   on   private   mobile  

carriers  (previous  experience  involve  fixed  line  carriers).”  (Mirandilla,  2007)  

 

Further,   mobile   technology   is   now   used   in   banking   services   in   the   Philippines,  

involving   transfers   of   electronic   money—something   that   required   a   new   set   of  

competence   from   the   regulators.   The   National   Telecommunication   Commission  

(NTC)   is   tasked   to   regulate   the   mobile   companies   while   the   Bangko   Sentral   ng  

Pilipinas   (BSP),   the   banking   sector.   The   two   agencies   agreed   that   the   BSP  would  

take   the   forefront   in   regulating  mobile   banking,  which   necessitated   the   agency   to  

train   its   examiners   in   handling   mobile-­‐based   transactions   and   processes.   In   this  

aspect,   the  Philippines  showed  competence   in   its  (banking  sector-­‐wise)  regulatory  

functions.    

 

Page 19: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 18 of 26

However,  the  same  cannot  be  said  of  the  NTC.  The  success  of  the  mobile  sector  is  not  

in  any  way  indication  that  regulation  (or  the  lack  of  it)  that  created  the  problem  in  

the   first  place  prior   to  policy  reforms  has   improved.  Today,   the  number  of  mobile  

players  has  declined  from  six  firms  in  2003  to  only  two  in  2012  as  a  result  of  merger  

and  acquisition.  The  mobile  industry  maybe  a  win  for  the  Philippines  because  of  the  

access   and   affordable   services   the   people   now   enjoy   but   unless   regulation   is  

strengthened,   the   dominant   player   PLDT   will   always   try   to   prevent   competition  

either  by   squeezing   the   smaller  players   out   of   the  market   or  buying   them  out.  As  

pointed  out  by  Abrenica  and  Llanto  (2003),  past  experience  shows  that  NTC  leaves  

critical  issues  such  as  interconnection  points  and  charges  to  contracting  parties  that  

do   not   necessarily   have   equal   bargaining   powers.   Therefore,   unless   level   playing  

field  is  ensured,  the  dominant  player  will  always  protect  its  turf.    

 

In  Indonesia,  on  the  other  hand,  although  the  government  started  loosening  its  grip  

on  the  telecommunications  industry  as  early  as  1989,  mobile  phone  players  did  not  

enter  the  market  until  19991  and  duopoly  in  fixed  line  was  mandated  until  2005.  In  

the   early   nineties,   the   country   engaged   in   build-­‐operate-­‐transfer   (BOT)   schemes  

with   overseas   telecommunications   companies   that   later   either   exited   the   deal   or  

went  to  court.  The  failure  of  BOT  was  attributed  to  different  factors:  bureaucracy  in  

the  partly   state-­‐owned  network  Telkom,   political   instability,  Asian   financial   crisis,  

and  corruption.  (Zita)  

 

Indonesia’s   second   attempt   to   liberalize   its   telecommunications   industry   was  

through  privatization  in  2002—something  inconsistent  with  the  country’s  dominant  

strategy  of  deregulation  under  Suharto’s  regime—with  the  shares  of  the  two  state-­‐

owned  companied  being  bought  by  Singaporean  government’s  investment  arm  and  

a   Malaysian   firm.   Meanwhile,   the   Indonesian   Telecommunications   Regulatory  

Agency  became  operational  only  in  2004.  (Zita)  

 

                                                                                                               1 Other source indicated various timelines between 1994 and 1996.

Page 20: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 19 of 26

The  result:   fixed   line  density  was  estimated  at  4  percent  while   the  mobile  density  

was  at  8.1  percent  in  2003.  These  figures  earned  for  the  country  the  reputation  as    

“the   least   developed   (telecommunications)   in   Asia”.   (Zita)   These   figures   pale   in  

comparison   with   the   Philippines,   where  mobile   subscribers   grew   from   66,000   in  

1991  to  22  million   in  2003  (Sebastian,  2005)  reaching  a  density  of  35  percent;  by  

2009   mobile   density   was   already   100   percent.   (Commission   on   Information   and  

Communications   Technology   ,   2010)   Perhaps   Indonesia   joined   the  

telecommunications  bandwagon  a  bit  too  late—either  that  or  the  changing  of  guards  

after   Suharto’s   resignation   in   1998  was   too   frequent   that   the   state  was   unable   to  

create  an  environment  conducive  to  new  investments.  

 

The   countries’   experience   in   telecommunications   industry   highlighted   the   role   of  

technological   innovations   in   changing   the   rules   of   the   games   and   the   need   of  

regulators  to  build  their  capacity  in  terms  of  technical  competence  and  facilities.  It  

can   also   be   hypothesized   that   whatever   NTC   lacked   in   regulatory   capacity,  

technological   innovations   in   the   mobile   market   have   made   up   for   it,   so   that   the  

industry   deregulation   resulted   in   both   economic   and   social   benefits,   even   to   the  

disadvantaged   groups.   Further,   the   case   proves   that   the   implementation   issues  

related   to   regulation   should   be   examined   at   the   agency/industry   level   because   of  

the  varying  levels  of  preparedness  and  competence  of  the  regulators,  as  exemplified  

by  the  BSP  and  the  NTC.    

 

Electric  Power  Generation  

In  the  height  of  power  failures   in  the  Philippines,   the  Ramos  administration   in  the  

early   nineties   opened   the   electric   power  market   to   privately   owned   independent  

power  producers  (IPPs).  In  its  intent  to  attract  investors,  the  Ramos  administration  

entered   into   contracts   where   the   government-­‐run   National   Power   Corporation  

absorbed  the  risks   inherent   in  such  investment  to  protect  the  private  producers—

market   risk   (government   assured  purchases   of   all   energy  produced  by   the  power  

generators),  supply  risk  (government  assured  purchases  all  inputs  such  as  coal  and  

Page 21: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 20 of 26

oil),   and   even   foreign   exchange   risk.   The   Philippine   Center   for   Investigative  

Journalism  also  pointed  out  that  the  Ramos  administration  “pushed  for  the  speedy  

approval  of  some  of  the  most  expensive  deals  and  justified  signing  more  contracts.”  

(Malaluan,  2002)  

 

The  35  IPPs  that  entered  the  market  reported  to  have  built  an  additional  capacity  of  

8,000   megawatts,   supplying   more   than   50   percent   of   the   country’s   need.   (Bello,  

2009)   However,   because   of   lower   installation   costs,   most   producers   preferred  

petroleum-­‐based  facilities  even  if  they  would  entail  high  risks  in  terms  of  price  and  

environmental  management.   The  high   costs   of   power  were   then  passed   on   to   the  

consumers.   Hence   unsurprisingly,   the   cost   of   electricity   in   Manila   (USD0.181   per  

kilowatt   hour)   is   much   higher   than   in   the   industrialized   Japan   (USD0.179   per  

kilowatt  hour)  and  the  highest  in  Asia.  (Main  Business,  2011)  

 

On   hindsight,   Llanto   (in   Bello,   2009)   concluded   that   “no   government   guarantee  

should  be   given   to   shield   private   investors   from   commercial   risks…(and   that)   the  

government   forgot   to   deal   with   the   need   to   have   an   independent   regulatory  

capacity,   leaving   regulatory   institutions   open   to   opportunistic   political  

interventions.”   (This   is   the   same   reason   for   the   failure   in   the   privatization   of   the  

water  sector:  lack  of  regulation.)  

 

Indonesia,  on  the  other  hand,  realized  during  the  1997  Asian  financial  crisis  that  the  

IPP   model   entails   high   price   of   electricity   for   the   end-­‐users   and   thus   introduced  

policy  reforms.  This  move  caused  the  geothermal  power  sector  to  slow  down  such  

that   by   2005,   it   only   had   807-­‐megawatt   (MW)   capacity   from   geothermal   plants  

when   its   potential   was   estimated   at   27   gigawatt   electrical   (GWe).   By   2003,   the  

country   enacted   the   Geothermal   Law,   which   stated   that   the   government   would  

engage  in  exploration  and  production,  taking  on  the  field  development  risk,  to  lower  

the   power   rates.   At   the   same   time,   the   government   deregulated   the   downstream  

energy   sector,   allowing   multiple   buyers   and   sellers   in   power   generation   and  

distribution   and   prioritizing   the   renewable   energy   for   domestic   needs.   Despite  

Page 22: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 21 of 26

these  deregulation  policies,  the  government  still  maintained  control  over  the  use  of  

energy   sources   in   the   country   (Suryantoro,   Dwipa,   Ariati,   &  Darma,   2005),  which  

stood  in  stark  contrast  with  the  Philippines’s  weak  regulation.    

 

In   terms   of   geothermal   capacity,   the   Philippines   has   outdone   Indonesia   with   its  

2,000-­‐MW   power   capacity.   Indonesia   expected   to   install   2,445-­‐MW   geothermal  

capacity  by  2012.  (Suryantoro,  Dwipa,  Ariati,  &  Darma,  2005)  

 

Due   to   heavy   government   subsidy,   however,   Indonesia   has   managed   to   keep   its  

rates   lower   than   that   of   the   Philippines.   Thus,   price   cannot   be   used   as   basis   for  

comparison  of  the  two  countries’  performance.    

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

As  of  2002,  the  total  energy  supply  in  Indonesia  that  stood  at  663  million  barrels  of  

oil  equivalent  (BOE)  exceeded  the  demand  at  430  million  BOE.  (Suryantoro,  Dwipa,  

Ariati,  &  Darma,  2005)  Beginning  2010  though,  Indonesia  had  started  experiencing  

power  shortages  and  suffered  from  low  electrification  rate  and  uneven  distribution  

of  electricity.    

 

On   the   other   hand,   the   Philippines   was   expected   to   have   experienced   power  

shortages   beginning   2008   escalating   until   2014   unless   investments   in   additional  

capacity  would  be  made  during  the  said  period.  (Department  of  Energy,  2004)  

 

Page 23: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 22 of 26

Hence,  one  country  is  not  necessarily  better  than  the  other  as  far  as  electric  power  

generation  is  concerned.  The  Philippines’s  loosely  regulated  energy  market  and  IPP-­‐

based   model,   and   Indonesia’s   heavily   regulated   and   subsidized   sector   with  

reformed  policies  (veering  away  from  the  IPPs)  both  resulted  in  shortage  and  high-­‐

cost   of   electric   power   supply.   As   to  what   could   the   explanatory   variables   for   this  

phenomenon   would   be   another   research   question   that   neither   state   capacity   or  

technological  innovation  could  account  for.    

 

Conclusion  

In   general,   Indonesia   has   been   more   successful   than   the   Philippines   in   using  

deregulation  as  a  strategy  to  achieve  both  its  economic  goal  (i.e.  development  of  the  

non-­‐oil   export)   and   social   goal   (i.e.   wide   and   even   distribution   of   benefits   of  

deregulation  and  economic  growth).  The   country  was  able   to  do   so  because  of   its  

strong  state  capacity,  i.e.  organizational  design  and  management,  manifested  in  the  

following:    

Clear   developmental   priorities   such   as   promoting   regional   growth   (in   the  

eastern   part   of   the   archipelago)   through   deregulation,   the   air   transport  

policies  for  example  

Pragmatic  and  selective  adoption  of  the  SAP    

Market-­‐oriented   policies   that   aimed   at   deepening   the   country’s   industrial  

structure  and  that  did  not  make  open  economy  as  an  end  in  itself  

Conscious   promotion   of   wide   and   even   distribution   of   benefits   of  

deregulation   and   economic   growth   and   initiatives   to   at   least   not   aggravate  

the  wealth  discrepancies  between  the  conglomerates  and  the  disadvantaged  

group    

Recognition   of   the   need   to   assess   deregulation’s   impact   at   the   industry   or  

sectoral  level,  especially  in  the  non-­‐tradable  markets  

Control  over  key  sectors  

Promotion   of   the   development   of   state   enterprises   and   indigenous  

entrepreneurs  that  justified  the  country’s  protectionist  policies    

Page 24: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 23 of 26

Strong  regulatory  functions  despite  market-­‐oriented  policies  

 

Indonesia  proves  that  ownership—private  is  efficient  and  public  is  inefficient—does  

not  matter  any  more.  There  are  successful  state-­‐run  or  state-­‐owned  enterprises  that  

are   able   to   employ   effective   management,   high   corporate   autonomy,   and  

technological  innovations.  (Bello,  2009)  

 

Indonesia’s   performance   also   challenges   Williamson’s   argument   that   structural  

adjustment  should  not  be  done  during  crisis.  The  country  did  exactly  that  and  bad  

times  came  to  mean  good  policies  in  its  case.    

 

The   industry   examples   in   this   paper—air   transportation,   automobile,  

telecommunications,  and  electric  power  generation,  all  of  which  used  to  be  natural  

monopolies—also  prove  that  aside   from  state  capacity,   technological   innovation   is  

indeed   key   in   successful   deregulation.   In   the   case   of   the   Philippines,   technology  

must   have   even   compensated   the   weak   regulators   in   the   telecommunications  

industry.   Deregulation   in   the   banking   sector,   although   beyond   the   scope   of   this  

paper,   would   not   have   been   successful   either   without   advance   information   and  

communication  technology.  

 

It   would   be   interesting   to   know   how   the   Philippines   could   strengthen   its   state  

capacity,   particularly   in   the   area   of   regulation.   Except   for   the   likes   of   the   BSP,  

regulatory   agencies   in   the   country   in   general   are   criticized   for   lack   of   focus,  

expertise,  and  accountability,  and  for  their  too  close  a  relationship  with  the  industry  

players   that   they   tend   to   become   beholden   to   them.   However,   if   state   officials  

remain  advocates  of  neoliberal  ideas—taking  the  concept  of  deregulation  as  leaving  

everything  to  market  forces  and  reducing  the  state  role  to  a  minimum,  among  other  

things—then  building  state  capacity  would  be  futile  cause.    

 

 

Page 25: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 24 of 26

Works  Cited    Abrenica,  M.  J.,  &  Llanto,  G.  M.  (2003).  Services.  In  A.  Balisacan,  &  H.  Hill  (Eds.),  The  

Philippine  Economy:  Development,  Policies,  and  Challenges  (pp.  254-­‐280).  Ateneo  De  Manila  University  Press.  

 Asia  Pacific  Economic  Cooperation.  (2000).  APEC  Deregulation  Report  2000  

Indonesia.  Retrieved  2012  5-­‐April  from  APEC  Agreements  and  Declarations:  http://www.asianlii.org/apec/other/agrmt/adr2000i307/  

 Balisacan,  A.  M.  (1995).  Anatomy  of  Poverty  during  Adjustments:  The  Case  of  the  

Philippines.  Economic  Development  and  Cultural  Change  ,  44  (1),  33-­‐62.    Bello,  W.  (2009).  The  Anti-­Development  State:  The  Political  Economy  of  Permanent  

Crisis  in  the  Philippines.  Manila,  Philippines:  Anvil  Publishing.    Bird,  J.  (1997).  Indonesia  in  1997:  The  Tinderbox  Year.  Asian  Survey  ,  38  (2),  168-­‐

176.    Bowen,  J.  T.,  &  Leinbach,  T.  R.  (1995).  The  State  and  Liberalization:  The  Airline  

Industry  in  the  East  Asian  NICs.  Annals  of  the  Association  of  American  Geographers  ,  85  (3).  

 Brilliantes,  A.  j.  (1993).  The  Philippines  in  1992:  Ready  for  Take  Off?  Asian  Survey,  33  

(2),  224-­‐230.    Buendia,  R.  G.  (2002).  Ethnicity  and  Sub-­‐nationalist  Independence  Movements  in  the  

Philippines  and  Indonesia.  Manila,  Philippines:  Yuchengco  Center.    Commission  on  Information  and  Communications  Technology  .  (2010).  Philippine  

Digital  Strategy.    de  Dios,  E.  S.,  &  Hutchcroft,  P.  D.  (2003).  Political  Economy.  (A.  B.  Hill,  Ed.)  Quezon  

City:  Ateneo  de  Manila  University  Press.    Department  of  Energy.  (2004).  Power  Development  Plan  2005–2014.    Fane,  G.  (1996).  Deregulation  in  Indonesia:  Two  Steps  Forward,  One  Step  Back.  

Agenda  ,  3  (3),  341-­‐350.    Fukuyama,  F.  (2004).  State-­Building:  Governance  and  World  Order  in  the  21st  

Century.  New  York:  Cornell  University  Press.    Ghosh,  J.  (1996).  Coercive  Corporatism:  The  State  in  Indonesian  Capitalism.  Social  

Scientist  ,  24  (11),  36-­‐49.  

Page 26: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 25 of 26

 Hein,  G.  (1990).  Indonesia  in  1989:  A  Question  of  Openness.  Asian  Survey  ,  30  (2),  

221-­‐230.    Hill,  H.  (2003).  Industry.  In  A.  Balisacan,  &  H.  Hill  (Eds.),  The  Philippine  Economy  

Development,  Policies,  and  Challenges  (pp.  219-­‐253).  Quezon  City,  Philippines:  Ateneo  de  Manila  University  Press.  

 Liddle,  R.  W.  (1988).  Indonesia  in  1987:  The  New  Order  at  the  Height  of  Its  Power.  

Asian  Survey  ,  28  (2),  180-­‐191.    Main  Business.  (2011  23-­‐February).  Retrieved  2012  11-­‐April  from  The  Manila  

Bulletin  Newspaper  Online:  http://www.mb.com.ph/node/305841/philippine    Malaluan,  N.  A.  (2002).  The  Philippine  Electric  Power  Industry  Reform:  A  Tragedy  of  

ADB  and  World  Bank  Private  Sector  Fundamentalism  and  Unaccountable  Government.  Asia  Power  Sector  Reform  Workshop,  (p.  59).  

 Mercado-­‐Albada,  R.  (2000).  Opening  Up  the  Philippine  Telecommunications  

Industry  to  Competition.    Milne,  R.  S.  (1992).  Privatization  in  the  ASEAN  States:  Who  Gets  What,  Why,  and  

with  What  Effect?  Pacific  Affairs  ,  65  (1),  7-­‐29.    Mirandilla,  M.  G.  (2007).  Achieving  Universal  Access  through  Liberalization,  

Regulation,  and  Deregulation:  The  Case  of  the  Philippine  Telecommunications  and  ICT  Sector.  Chennai,  India.  

 Orbeta,  M.  (n.d.).  Is  Competition  Policy  Necessary?  The  Philippine  Case.  Philippines.    Sebastian,  A.  M.  (2005).  Mobile  Phones:  Bridging  the  Divides  in  Philippine  Society.  

Makati,  Philippines.    Soesastro,  M.  H.  (1989).  The  Political  Economy  of  Deregulation  in  Indonesia.  Asian  

Survey  ,  29  (9),  853-­‐869.    Suryantoro,  S.,  Dwipa,  S.,  Ariati,  R.,  &  Darma,  S.  (2005).  Geothermal  Deregulation  and  

Energy  Policy  in  Indonesia.  Proceedings  World  Geothermal  Congress,  (pp.  1-­‐9).  Antalya.  

 The  Philippines  Back  in  the  Spotlight.  (1996,  March).  Asia  Money  Magazine  

Supplement  .    Williamson,  J.  (2010  2-­‐November).  Beijing  Consensus  Versus  Washington  

Consensus.  (S.  Weisman,  Interviewer)  Peterson  Institute  for  International  Economics.  

Page 27: AMsebastian Comparative Politics 2012 04 13: State Capacity and Deregulation in the Philippines and Indonesia

Page 26 of 26

 Williamson,  J.  (2003  12-­‐18-­‐April).  The  Washington  Consensus  and  Beyond.  

Economic  and  Political  Weekly  ,  38  (15),  pp.  1475-­‐1481.    Zita,  K.  (n.d.).  Indonesia  Telecom  Brief.