Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

121
Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 7: Monopoly

Transcript of Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Page 1: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advanced Microeconomic Theory

Chapter 7: Monopoly

Page 2: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Outline

β€’ Barriers to Entryβ€’ Profit Maximization under Monopolyβ€’ Welfare Loss of Monopolyβ€’ Multiplant Monopolistβ€’ Price Discriminationβ€’ Advertising in Monopolyβ€’ Regulation of Natural Monopoliesβ€’ Monopsony

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Page 3: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Barriers to Entry

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 3

Page 4: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Barriers to Entry

β€’ Entry barriers: elements that make the entry of potential competitors either impossible or very costly.

β€’ Three main categories:1) Legal: the incumbent firm in an industry has the

legal right to charge monopoly prices during the life of the patent – Example: newly discovered drugs

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 4

Page 5: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Barriers to Entry

2) Structural: the incumbent firm has a cost or demand advantage relative to potential entrants.– superior technology– a loyal group of customers positive network externalities (Facebook, eBay)

3) Strategic: the incumbent monopolist has a reputation of fighting off newcomers, ultimately driving them off the market.– price wars

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 5

Page 6: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization under Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 6

Page 7: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ Consider a demand function π‘₯π‘₯(𝑝𝑝), which is continuous and strictly decreasing in 𝑝𝑝, i.e., π‘₯π‘₯β€² 𝑝𝑝 < 0.

β€’ We assume that there is price �̅�𝑝 < ∞ such that π‘₯π‘₯ 𝑝𝑝 = 0 for all 𝑝𝑝 > �̅�𝑝.

β€’ Also, consider a general cost function 𝑐𝑐(π‘žπ‘ž), which is increasing and convex in π‘žπ‘ž.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 7

Page 8: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ �̅�𝑝 is a β€œchoke price”

β€’ No consumers buy positive amounts of the good for 𝑝𝑝 > �̅�𝑝.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 8

'( ) 0x p <

p

p

q

x(p)

( )=0 for all >x p p p

Page 9: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ Monopolist’s decision problem ismax𝑝𝑝

𝑝𝑝π‘₯π‘₯ 𝑝𝑝 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐(π‘₯π‘₯(𝑝𝑝))

β€’ Alternatively, using π‘₯π‘₯ 𝑝𝑝 = π‘žπ‘ž, and taking the inverse demand function 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘₯π‘₯βˆ’1(π‘žπ‘ž), we can rewrite the monopolist’s problem as

maxπ‘žπ‘žβ‰₯0

𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐(π‘žπ‘ž)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 9

Page 10: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ Differentiating with respect to π‘žπ‘ž, 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š ≀ 0

β€’ Rearranging, 𝑝𝑝(π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š) + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š

𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀=𝑑𝑑 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘žπ‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘ž

≀ 𝑐𝑐′(π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š)𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

with equality if π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š > 0.

β€’ Recall that total revenue is 𝑇𝑇𝑅𝑅 π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘ž

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 10

Page 11: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ In addition, we assume that 𝑝𝑝 0 β‰₯ 𝑐𝑐′(0).– That is, the inverse demand curve originates

above the marginal cost curve.– Hence, the consumer with the highest willingness

to pay for the good is willing to pay more than the variable costs of producing the first unit.

β€’ Then, we must be at an interior solution π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š >0, implying

𝑝𝑝(π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š) + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘šπ‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€

= 𝑐𝑐′(π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š)𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 11

Page 12: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ Note that 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š

βˆ’= 𝑐𝑐′(π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š)

β€’ Then, 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š > 𝑐𝑐′(π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š), i.e., monopoly price > 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

β€’ Moreover, we know that in competitive equilibrium 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žβˆ— = 𝑐𝑐′(π‘žπ‘žβˆ—).

β€’ Then, π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š > π‘π‘βˆ— and π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š < π‘žπ‘žβˆ—.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 12

Page 13: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 13

Page 14: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ Marginal revenue in monopoly 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š

MR describes two effects:– A direct (positive) effect: an additional unit can be

sold at 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š , thus increasing revenue by 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š .– An indirect (negative) effect: selling an additional

unit can only be done by reducing the market price of all units (the new and all previous units), ultimately reducing revenue by 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š. Inframarginal units – initial units before the marginal

increase in output.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 14

Page 15: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ Is the above FOC also sufficient?– Let’s take the FOC 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐′ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š ,

and differentiate it wrt π‘žπ‘ž,𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘ž + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘ž + 𝑝𝑝′′ π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘ž

π‘‘π‘‘π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘ž

βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐′′(π‘žπ‘ž)π‘‘π‘‘π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘ž

≀ 0

– That is, π‘‘π‘‘π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘ž

≀ π‘‘π‘‘π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘ž

.

– Since MR curve is decreasing and MC curve is weakly increasing, the second-order condition is satisfied for all π‘žπ‘ž.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 15

Page 16: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 16

p

q

x(p)

MC(q)

MR(q)

mp

mq

Page 17: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

β€’ What would happen if MC curve was decreasing in π‘žπ‘ž (e.g., concave technology given the presence of increasing returns to scale)?– Then, the slopes of MR and MC curves are both

decreasing.– At the optimum, MR curve must be steeper MC

curve.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 17

Page 18: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 18

p

q

x(p)MC(q)

MR(q)

mp

mq

Page 19: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Can we re-write the FOC in a more intuitive way? Yes.

– Just take 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž + 𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑝𝑝 + πœ•πœ•π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπ‘žπ‘ž and

multiply by 𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝

,

𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 = 𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝𝑝

+οΏ½πœ•πœ•π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž

π‘žπ‘žπ‘π‘

1/πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘

𝑝𝑝 = 𝑝𝑝 +1πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘π‘π‘

– In equilibrium, 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅(π‘žπ‘ž) = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀(π‘žπ‘ž). Hence, we can replace MR with MC in the above expression.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 19

Page 20: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Rearranging yields𝑝𝑝 βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€(π‘žπ‘ž)

𝑝𝑝= βˆ’

1πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘

β€’ This is the Lerner index of market power– The price mark-up over marginal cost that a

monopolist can charge is a function of the elasticity of demand.

β€’ Note:– If πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘ β†’ ∞, then π‘π‘βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€(π‘žπ‘ž)

𝑝𝑝→ 0 ⟹ 𝑝𝑝 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀(π‘žπ‘ž)

– If πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘ β†’ 0, then π‘π‘βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€(π‘žπ‘ž)𝑝𝑝

β†’ ∞ ⟹ substantial mark-upAdvanced Microeconomic Theory 20

Page 21: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ The Lerner index can also be written as

𝑝𝑝 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀(π‘žπ‘ž)1+ 1

πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘

which is referred to as the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule (IEPR).

β€’ Example (Perloff, 2012): – Prilosec OTC: πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘ = βˆ’1.2. Then price should be 𝑝𝑝 =

𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀(π‘žπ‘ž)1+ 1

βˆ’1.2= 6𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

– Designed jeans: πœ€πœ€π‘‘π‘‘ = βˆ’2. Then price should be 𝑝𝑝 =𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀(π‘žπ‘ž)1+ 1

βˆ’2= 2𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 21

Page 22: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 1 (linear demand):– Market inverse demand function is

𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žwhere 𝑏𝑏 > 0

– Monopolist’s cost function is 𝑐𝑐 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žβ€“ We usually assume that π‘Žπ‘Ž > 𝑐𝑐 β‰₯ 0 To guarantee 𝑝𝑝 0 > 𝑐𝑐′(0) That is, 𝑝𝑝 0 = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑏𝑏𝑏 = π‘Žπ‘Ž and 𝑐𝑐′ π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑐𝑐, thus

implying 𝑐𝑐′ 0 = 𝑐𝑐

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 22

Page 23: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 1 (continued):– Monopolist’s objective function

πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘ž = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

– FOC: π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 2π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0– SOC: βˆ’2𝑏𝑏 < 0 (concave) Note that as long as 𝑏𝑏 > 0, i.e., negatively sloped

demand function, profits will be concave in output. Otherwise (i.e., Giffen good, with positively sloped

demand function) profits will be convex in output.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 23

Page 24: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 1 (continued):– Solving for the optimal π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š in the FOC, we find

monopoly output

π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š =π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐2𝑏𝑏

– Inserting π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š = π‘Žπ‘Žβˆ’π‘π‘2𝑏𝑏

in the demand function, we obtain monopoly price

π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐2𝑏𝑏

=π‘Žπ‘Ž + 𝑐𝑐

2– Hence, monopoly profits are

πœ‹πœ‹π‘šπ‘š = π‘π‘π‘šπ‘šπ‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š =π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 2

4𝑏𝑏Advanced Microeconomic Theory 24

Page 25: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 1 (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 25

Page 26: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 1 (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 26

p

12

abβ‹…

mq ab

c’(q)

q

mp

a

MR=a-2bqp(q)=a-bq

– Non-constant marginal cost

– The cost function is convex in output𝑐𝑐(π‘žπ‘ž) = π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž2

– Marginal cost is𝑐𝑐′(π‘žπ‘ž) = 2π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

Page 27: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 2 (Constant elasticity demand):– The demand function is

π‘žπ‘ž(𝑝𝑝) = π΄π΄π‘π‘βˆ’π‘π‘

– We can show that πœ€πœ€ π‘žπ‘ž = βˆ’π‘π‘ for all π‘žπ‘ž, i.e.,

πœ€πœ€ π‘žπ‘ž =πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž(𝑝𝑝)πœ•πœ•π‘π‘

π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

= βˆ’π‘π‘ π΄π΄π‘π‘βˆ’π‘π‘βˆ’1πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž(𝑝𝑝)πœ•πœ•π‘π‘

π‘π‘π΄π΄π‘π‘βˆ’π‘π‘π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

= βˆ’π‘π‘π‘π‘βˆ’π‘π‘

π‘π‘π‘π‘π‘π‘βˆ’π‘π‘

= βˆ’π‘π‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 27

Page 28: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Profit Maximization: Lerner Index

β€’ Example 2 (continued):– We can now plug πœ€πœ€ π‘žπ‘ž = βˆ’π‘π‘ into the Lerner

index,

π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š =𝑐𝑐

1 + 1πœ€πœ€ π‘žπ‘ž

=𝑐𝑐

1 βˆ’ 1𝑏𝑏

=𝑏𝑏𝑐𝑐

𝑏𝑏 βˆ’ 1

– That is, price is a constant mark-up over marginal cost.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 28

Page 29: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 29

Page 30: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

p

q

p(q)

c’(q)

MR=p(q)+p’(q)q

mp

mq

*p

*q

( )mp qA

B CED

[ ]*

( ) '( )m

q

qp s c s dsβˆ’βˆ«

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Welfare comparison for perfect competition and monopoly.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 30

Page 31: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Consumer surplus– Perfect competition: A+B+C– Monopoly: A

β€’ Producer surplus:– Perfect competition: D+E– Monopoly: B+D

β€’ Deadweight loss of monopoly: C+E

𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷 = οΏ½π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š

π‘žπ‘žβˆ—

𝑝𝑝 𝑠𝑠 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐′(𝑠𝑠) 𝑑𝑑𝑠𝑠

β€’ DWL decreases as demand and/or supply become more elastic.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 31

Page 32: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

p

p

mq

*q

c’(q)

q

Coincides with (PC market)

( )p q p=

Welfare Loss of Monopolyβ€’ Infinitely elastic demand

𝑝𝑝′ π‘žπ‘ž = 0β€’ The inverse demand curve

becomes totally flat.β€’ Marginal revenue coincides

with inverse demand:𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž + 0 οΏ½ π‘žπ‘ž= 𝑝𝑝(π‘žπ‘ž)

β€’ Profit-maximizing π‘žπ‘žπ‘€π‘€π‘…π‘… π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 π‘žπ‘ž βŸΉπ‘π‘ π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀(π‘žπ‘ž)

β€’ Hence, π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š = π‘žπ‘žβˆ— and 𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷 = 0.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 32

Page 33: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Example (Welfare losses and elasticity):– Consider a monopolist with constant marginal and

average costs, 𝑐𝑐′ π‘žπ‘ž = 𝑐𝑐, who faces a market demand with constant elasticity

π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝 = 𝑝𝑝𝑒𝑒

where 𝑒𝑒 is the price elasticity of demand (𝑒𝑒 < βˆ’1)– Perfect competition: 𝑝𝑝𝑐𝑐 = 𝑐𝑐– Monopoly: using the IEPR

π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š =𝑐𝑐

1 + 1𝑒𝑒

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 33

Page 34: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopolyβ€’ Example (continued):

– The consumer surplus associated with any price (𝑝𝑝0) can be computed as

𝑀𝑀𝐢𝐢 = �𝑝𝑝0

βˆžπ‘„π‘„ 𝑃𝑃 𝑑𝑑𝑝𝑝 = οΏ½

𝑝𝑝0

βˆžπ‘π‘π‘’π‘’π‘‘π‘‘π‘π‘ = οΏ½

𝑝𝑝𝑒𝑒+1

𝑒𝑒 + 1𝑝𝑝0

∞

= βˆ’π‘π‘0𝑒𝑒+1

𝑒𝑒 + 1<0

> 0

– Under perfect competition, 𝑝𝑝𝑐𝑐 = 𝑐𝑐,

𝑀𝑀𝐢𝐢 = βˆ’π‘π‘π‘’π‘’+1

𝑒𝑒 + 1– Under monopoly, π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š = 𝑐𝑐

1+1/𝑒𝑒,

π‘€π‘€πΆπΆπ‘šπ‘š = βˆ’

𝑐𝑐1 + 1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒+1

𝑒𝑒 + 1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 34

Page 35: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Example (continued):– Taking the ratio of these two surpluses

π‘€π‘€πΆπΆπ‘šπ‘šπ‘€π‘€πΆπΆ

=1

1 + 1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒+1

– If 𝑒𝑒 = βˆ’2, this ratio is Β½ CS under monopoly is half of that under perfectly

competitive markets

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 35

Page 36: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Example (continued):

– The ratio π‘€π‘€πΆπΆπ‘šπ‘šπ‘€π‘€πΆπΆ

= 11+1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒+1decreases as demand becomes

more elastic (𝑒𝑒 increases in absolute value).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 36

Page 37: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Example (continued):– Monopoly profits are given by

πœ‹πœ‹π‘šπ‘š = π‘π‘π‘šπ‘šπ‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š =𝑐𝑐

1 + 1/π‘’π‘’βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š

where π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š(𝑝𝑝) = 𝑝𝑝𝑒𝑒 = 𝑐𝑐1+1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒.

– Rearranging,

πœ‹πœ‹π‘šπ‘š =βˆ’π‘π‘/𝑒𝑒

1 + 1/𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐

1 + 1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒

= βˆ’π‘π‘

1 + 1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒+1

οΏ½1𝑒𝑒

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 37

Page 38: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ Example (continued):– To find the transfer from CS into monopoly profits

that consumers experience when moving from perfect competition to a monopoly, divide monopoly profits by the competitive CS

πœ‹πœ‹π‘šπ‘š

𝑀𝑀𝐢𝐢= 𝑒𝑒+1

𝑒𝑒1

1+1/𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒+1= 𝑒𝑒

1+𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒

– If 𝑒𝑒 = βˆ’2, this ratio is ΒΌ One-fourth of the consumer surplus under perfectly

competitive markets is transferred to monopoly profitsAdvanced Microeconomic Theory 38

Page 39: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Welfare Loss of Monopoly

β€’ More social costs of monopoly:– Excessive R&D expenditure (patent race)– Persuasive (not informative) advertising– Lobbying costs (different from bribes)– Resources to avoid entry of potential firms in the

industry

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 39

Page 40: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Comparative Statics

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 40

Page 41: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

p

p(q)MR

2mq

1mp

1mq

'2 ( )c q

'1( )c q

2mp

Comparative Statics

β€’ We want to understand how π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š varies as a function of the monopolist’s marginal cost

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 41

Page 42: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Comparative Staticsβ€’ Formally, we know that at the optimum, π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š(𝑐𝑐), the

monopolist maximizes its profitsπœ•πœ•πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐

πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š= 0

β€’ Differentiating wrt 𝑐𝑐, and using the chain rule,πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐

πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž2π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐

+πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐

πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπœ•πœ•π‘π‘= 0

β€’ Solving for π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐

, we have

π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐

= βˆ’

πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπœ•πœ•π‘π‘

πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž2

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 42

Page 43: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Comparative Statics

β€’ Example:– Assume linear demand curve 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žβ€“ Then, the cross-derivative is

πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπœ•πœ•π‘π‘

=πœ•πœ• πœ•πœ• π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž π‘žπ‘ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπœ•πœ•π‘π‘

=πœ•πœ• π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 2π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐

πœ•πœ•π‘π‘= βˆ’1

and

π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐

= βˆ’

πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπœ•πœ•π‘π‘

πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž2

= βˆ’βˆ’1βˆ’2𝑏𝑏

< 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 43

Page 44: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Comparative Statics

β€’ Example (continued):– That is, an increase in marginal cost, 𝑐𝑐, decreases

monopoly output, π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š.– Similarly for any other demand. – Even if we don’t know the accurate demand

function, but know the sign of

πœ•πœ•2πœ‹πœ‹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 , π‘π‘πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπœ•πœ•π‘π‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 44

Page 45: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Comparative Statics

β€’ Example (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 45

– Marginal costs are increasing in π‘žπ‘ž

– For convex cost curve 𝑐𝑐 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž2, monopoly output isπ‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐 =

π‘Žπ‘Ž2(𝑏𝑏 + 𝑐𝑐)

– Here, π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐

= βˆ’π‘Žπ‘Ž

2 𝑏𝑏 + 𝑐𝑐 2 < 0

Page 46: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Comparative Statics

β€’ Example (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 46

– Constant marginal cost– For the constant-elasticity

demand curve π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝 = 𝑝𝑝𝑒𝑒, we have π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š = 𝑐𝑐

1+1/𝑒𝑒and

π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š(𝑐𝑐) = 𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐1+𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒

– Here,π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š 𝑐𝑐𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐

=𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐

𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐1 + 𝑒𝑒

𝑒𝑒

=π‘’π‘’π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š < 0

Page 47: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 47

Page 48: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Monopolist produces output π‘žπ‘ž1, π‘žπ‘ž2, … , π‘žπ‘žπ‘π‘ across 𝑁𝑁 plants it operates, with total costs 𝑇𝑇𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖(π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–) at each plant 𝑖𝑖 = {1,2, … ,𝑁𝑁}.

β€’ Profits-maximization problemmaxπ‘žπ‘ž1,…,π‘žπ‘žπ‘π‘

π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘βˆ‘π‘–π‘–=1𝑁𝑁 π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ‘π‘–π‘–=1𝑁𝑁 π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ βˆ‘π‘–π‘–=1𝑁𝑁 𝑇𝑇𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖(π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–)

β€’ FOCs wrt production level at every plant 𝑗𝑗

π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 2𝑏𝑏�𝑖𝑖=1

π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑗𝑗 π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘— = 0

βŸΊπ‘€π‘€π‘…π‘… 𝑄𝑄 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑗𝑗(π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘—)for all 𝑗𝑗.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 48

Page 49: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Multiplant monopolist operating two plants with marginal costs 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1 and 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 49

Page 50: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Total marginal cost is π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1 + 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2 (i.e., horizontal sum)

β€’ π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ is determined by 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 = π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ (i.e., point A)

β€’ Mapping π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ in the demand curve, we obtain price π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š (both plants selling at the same price)

β€’ At the MC level for which 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 = π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ (i.e., point A), extend a line to the left crossing 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1and 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2.

β€’ This will give us output levels π‘žπ‘ž1 and π‘žπ‘ž2 that plants 1 and 2 produce, respectively.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 50

Page 51: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Example 1 (symmetric plants):– Consider a monopolist operating 𝑁𝑁 plants, where

all plants have the same cost function 𝑇𝑇𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖 π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– =𝐹𝐹 + π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–2. Hence, all plants produce the same output level π‘žπ‘ž1 = π‘žπ‘ž2 = β‹― = π‘žπ‘žπ‘π‘ = π‘žπ‘ž and 𝑄𝑄 = π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘—. The linear demand function is given by 𝑝𝑝 = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑏𝑏𝑄𝑄.

– FOCs:π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 2π‘π‘βˆ‘π‘—π‘—=1𝑁𝑁 π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘— = 2π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘— or π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 2π‘π‘π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘— = 2π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘—

π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘— =π‘Žπ‘Ž

2(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐)Advanced Microeconomic Theory 51

Page 52: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolistβ€’ Example 1 (continued):

– Total output produced by the monopolist is

𝑄𝑄 = π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘—=π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž

2(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐)and market price is

𝑝𝑝 = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑏𝑏𝑄𝑄 = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž

2 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐=π‘Žπ‘Ž(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 2𝑐𝑐)2 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐

– Hence, the profits of every plant 𝑗𝑗 are

πœ‹πœ‹π‘—π‘— =π‘Žπ‘Ž(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 2𝑐𝑐)2 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐

π‘Žπ‘Ž2(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐)

βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž

2(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐)

2

=π‘Žπ‘Ž2

4 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + π‘π‘βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹

– Total profits become

πœ‹πœ‹π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ =π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž2

4 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + π‘π‘βˆ’ 𝑁𝑁𝐹𝐹

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 52

Page 53: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Example 1 (continued):– The optimal number of plants π‘π‘βˆ— is determined by

π‘‘π‘‘πœ‹πœ‹π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘π‘

=π‘Žπ‘Ž2

4𝑐𝑐

(𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐)2βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹 = 0

and solving for 𝑁𝑁

π‘π‘βˆ— =1𝑏𝑏

π‘Žπ‘Ž2

π‘π‘πΉπΉβˆ’ 𝑐𝑐

– π‘π‘βˆ— is decreasing in the fixed costs 𝐹𝐹– π‘π‘βˆ— is decreasing in 𝑐𝑐 as long as π‘Žπ‘Ž < 4 𝑐𝑐𝐹𝐹, since

π‘‘π‘‘π‘π‘βˆ—

𝑑𝑑𝑐𝑐=

1𝑏𝑏

π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 4 𝑀𝑀𝐹𝐹4 𝑀𝑀𝐹𝐹

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 53

Page 54: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Example 1 (continued):– Note that when 𝑁𝑁 = 1, 𝑄𝑄 = π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š and 𝑝𝑝 = π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š.– Note that an increase in 𝑁𝑁 decreases π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘— and πœ‹πœ‹π‘—π‘—, as

π‘‘π‘‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘—π‘‘π‘‘π‘π‘

= βˆ’π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘π‘

2 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐 2 < 0

π‘‘π‘‘πœ‹πœ‹π‘—π‘—π‘‘π‘‘π‘π‘

= βˆ’π‘Žπ‘Ž2𝑏𝑏

4 𝑏𝑏𝑁𝑁 + 𝑐𝑐 2 < 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 54

Page 55: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Example 2 (asymmetric plants):– Consider a monopolist operating two plants with

marginal costs 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1 π‘žπ‘ž1 = 10 + 20π‘žπ‘ž1 and 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2 π‘žπ‘ž2 =60 + 5π‘žπ‘ž2, respectively. A linear demand function is give by 𝑝𝑝 𝑄𝑄 = 120 βˆ’ 3𝑄𝑄.

– Note that π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ β‰  𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1(π‘žπ‘ž1) + 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2(π‘žπ‘ž2) This is a vertical (not a horizontal) sum.

– Instead, first invert the marginal cost functions

𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1 π‘žπ‘ž1 = 10 + 20π‘žπ‘ž1 ⟺ π‘žπ‘ž1 =𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀120

βˆ’12

𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2 π‘žπ‘ž2 = 60 + 5π‘žπ‘ž2 ⟺ π‘žπ‘ž2 =𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2

5βˆ’ 12

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 55

Page 56: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Multiplant Monopolist

β€’ Example 2 (continued):– Second,

π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = π‘žπ‘ž1 + π‘žπ‘ž2 =π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘

20βˆ’

12

+π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘

5βˆ’ 12

=14π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ βˆ’ 12.5

– Hence, π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = 50 + 4π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘β€“ Setting 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 𝑄𝑄 = 120 βˆ’ 6𝑄𝑄 = 50 + 4𝑄𝑄 = π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘, we

obtain π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = 7 and 𝑝𝑝 = 120 βˆ’ 3 οΏ½ 7 = 99.– Since 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = 120 βˆ’ 6 οΏ½ 7 = 78, then 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀1 π‘žπ‘ž1 ⟹ 78 = 10 + 20π‘žπ‘ž1 ⟹ π‘žπ‘ž1 = 3.4𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 π‘„π‘„π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘‘π‘‘ = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀2 π‘žπ‘ž2 ⟹ 78 = 60 + 5π‘žπ‘ž2 ⟹ π‘žπ‘ž2 = 3.6

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 56

Page 57: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 57

Page 58: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

p

q

MR p(q)

mp MC

*qmqSelling these units at mp p>

Selling these units at mp p<

Price Discrimination

β€’ Can the monopolist capture an even larger surplus?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 58

– Charge 𝑝𝑝 > π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š to those who buy the product at π‘π‘π‘šπ‘šand are willing to pay more

– Charge 𝑐𝑐 < 𝑝𝑝 < π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š to those who do not buy the product at π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š, but whose willingness to pay for the good is still higher than the marginal cost of production, 𝑐𝑐.

– With π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š for all units, the monopolist does not capture the surplus of neither of these segments.

Page 59: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price

Quantity

D

2q1...q

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ First-degree (perfect) price discrimination:– The monopolist charges to every customer his/her

maximum willingness to pay for the object.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 59

– Personalized price: The first buyer pays 𝑝𝑝1 for the π‘žπ‘ž1 units, the second buyer pays 𝑝𝑝2 for π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž1units, etc.

Page 60: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

– The monopolist continues doing so until the last buyer is willing to pay the marginal cost of production.

– In the limit, the monopolist captures all the area below the demand curve and above the marginal cost (i.e., consumer surplus).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 60

p

q

p(q)

' ( )c q

*q

MR

Profits

mq

Page 61: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Suppose that the monopolist can charge a fixed fee, π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿβˆ—, and an amount of the good, π‘žπ‘žβˆ—, that maximizes profits.

β€’ PMP:maxπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ,π‘žπ‘ž

π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

𝑠𝑠. 𝑑𝑑. 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘ž) β‰₯ π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿβ€’ Note that the monopolist raises the fee π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ until 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ.

Hence we can reduce the set of choice variablesmaxπ‘žπ‘ž

𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘ž) βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž

β€’ FOC: 𝑒𝑒′ π‘žπ‘žβˆ— βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0 or 𝑒𝑒′ π‘žπ‘žβˆ— = 𝑐𝑐. – Intuition: the monopolist increases output until the

marginal utility that consumers obtain from additional units coincides with the marginal cost of production

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 61

Page 62: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Given the level of production π‘žπ‘žβˆ—, the optimal fee is

π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿβˆ— = 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žβˆ—

β€’ Intuition: the monopolist charges a fee π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿβˆ— that coincides with the utility that the consumer obtains from consuming π‘žπ‘žβˆ—.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 62

p

q

p(q)

' ( )c q

*CEq q=

MR

mq

**

0Profits ( ) ( )

qp q dq c q= βˆ’βˆ«

*r

mp

Page 63: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Example:– A monopolist faces inverse demand curve 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž =

20 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž and constant marginal costs 𝑐𝑐 = $2. – No price discrimination:

𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 ⟹ 20 βˆ’ 2π‘žπ‘ž = 2 ⟹ π‘žπ‘žπ‘šπ‘š = 9π‘π‘π‘šπ‘š = $11, πœ‹πœ‹π‘šπ‘š = $81

– Price discrimination:𝑝𝑝 𝑄𝑄 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 ⟹ 20 βˆ’ 𝑄𝑄 = 2 βŸΉπ‘„π‘„ = 18

πœ‹πœ‹ =18 Γ— 20 βˆ’ 2

2= $162

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 63

Page 64: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Example (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 64

Page 65: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Summary:– Total output coincides with that in perfect

competition– Unlike in perfect competition, the consumer does

not capture any surplus– The producer captures all the surplus– Due to information requirements, we do not see

many examples of it in real applications Financial aid in undergraduate education (β€œtuition

discrimination”)Advanced Microeconomic Theory 65

Page 66: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Example (two-block pricing):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 66

– A monopolist faces a inverse demand curve 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž , with constant marginal costs 𝑐𝑐 < π‘Žπ‘Ž.

– Under two-block pricing, the monopolist sells the first π‘žπ‘ž1 units at a price 𝑝𝑝(π‘žπ‘ž1) = 𝑝𝑝1 and the remaining π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž1units at a price 𝑝𝑝(π‘žπ‘ž2) = 𝑝𝑝2.

Page 67: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Example (continued):– Profits from the first π‘žπ‘ž1 units

πœ‹πœ‹1 = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž1 οΏ½ π‘žπ‘ž1 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž1 = (π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐)π‘žπ‘ž1while from the remaining π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž1 units

πœ‹πœ‹2 = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž2 οΏ½ π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 οΏ½ (π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’π‘žπ‘ž1)= (π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐)(π‘žπ‘ž2βˆ’π‘žπ‘ž1)

– Hence total profits areπœ‹πœ‹ = πœ‹πœ‹1 + πœ‹πœ‹2= π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 π‘žπ‘ž1 + (π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐)(π‘žπ‘ž2βˆ’π‘žπ‘ž1)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 67

Page 68: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degreeβ€’ Example (continued):

– FOCs:πœ•πœ•πœ‹πœ‹πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž1

= π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 2π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 βˆ’ π‘Žπ‘Ž + π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž2 + 𝑐𝑐 = 0

πœ•πœ•πœ‹πœ‹πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž2

= βˆ’π‘π‘ π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž1 + π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0

– Solving for π‘žπ‘ž1 and π‘žπ‘ž2π‘žπ‘ž1 =

π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐3𝑏𝑏

π‘žπ‘ž2 =2(π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐)

3𝑏𝑏which entails prices of

𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž1 = π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑏𝑏 οΏ½π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐3𝑏𝑏

=2π‘Žπ‘Ž + 𝑐𝑐

3𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž2 =

π‘Žπ‘Ž + 2𝑐𝑐3

where 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž1 > 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž2 since π‘Žπ‘Ž > 𝑐𝑐.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 68

Page 69: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: First-degree

β€’ Example (continued):– The monopolist’s profits from each block are

πœ‹πœ‹1 = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 οΏ½ π‘žπ‘ž1

=2π‘Žπ‘Ž + 𝑐𝑐

3βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 οΏ½

π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐3𝑏𝑏

=2π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐

3

2

πœ‹πœ‹2 = 𝑝𝑝 π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐)(π‘žπ‘ž2 βˆ’ π‘žπ‘ž1

=π‘Žπ‘Ž + 2𝑐𝑐

3βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 οΏ½

2 π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐3𝑏𝑏

βˆ’π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐3𝑏𝑏

=1π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐

3

2

– Thus, πœ‹πœ‹ = πœ‹πœ‹1 + πœ‹πœ‹2 = π‘Žπ‘Žβˆ’π‘π‘ 2

3𝑏𝑏, which is larger than

those arising from uniform pricing , πœ‹πœ‹π‘’π‘’ = π‘Žπ‘Žβˆ’π‘π‘ 2

4𝑏𝑏.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 69

Page 70: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Third-degree β€’ Third degree price discrimination:

– The monopolist charges different prices to two or more groups of customers (each group must be easily recognized by the seller).

β€’ Example: youth vs. adult at the movies, airline tickets – Firm’s PMP:

maxπ‘₯π‘₯1,π‘₯π‘₯2

𝑝𝑝1 π‘₯π‘₯1 π‘₯π‘₯1 + 𝑝𝑝2 π‘₯π‘₯2 π‘₯π‘₯2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐π‘₯π‘₯1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐π‘₯π‘₯2– FOCs:

𝑝𝑝1 π‘₯π‘₯1 + 𝑝𝑝1β€² π‘₯π‘₯1 π‘₯π‘₯1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0 ⟹ 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅1 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑝𝑝2 π‘₯π‘₯2 + 𝑝𝑝2β€² π‘₯π‘₯2 π‘₯π‘₯2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0 ⟹ 𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅2 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

– FOCs coincides with those of a regular monopolist who serves two completely separated markets practicing uniform pricing .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 70

Page 71: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

1p

1MR

1 14x =

$10$10MC =

1 $24p =

1x

2p

2 8x =2MR

2 $12p =

2x

Market 1Adults at the movies

Market 2Seniors at the movies

1( )p x 2( )p x

Price Discrimination: Third-degree– Example: 𝑝𝑝1 π‘₯π‘₯1 = 38 βˆ’ π‘₯π‘₯1 for adults and 𝑝𝑝2 π‘₯π‘₯2 = 14 βˆ’

1/4π‘₯π‘₯2 for seniors, with 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 = $10 for both markets.𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅1 π‘₯π‘₯1 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 ⟹ 38 βˆ’ 2π‘₯π‘₯1 = 10 ⟹ π‘₯π‘₯1 = 14 𝑝𝑝1 = $24𝑀𝑀𝑅𝑅2 π‘₯π‘₯2 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 ⟹ 14 βˆ’ 1/2π‘₯π‘₯2 = 10 ⟹ π‘₯π‘₯2 = 8 𝑝𝑝2 = $12

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 71

Page 72: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Third-degree

β€’ Using the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule (IERP), we can obtain the prices

𝑝𝑝1 π‘₯π‘₯1 = 𝑐𝑐1βˆ’1/πœ€πœ€1

and 𝑝𝑝2 π‘₯π‘₯2 = 𝑐𝑐1βˆ’1/πœ€πœ€2

where 𝑐𝑐 is the common marginal costβ€’ Then, 𝑝𝑝1 π‘₯π‘₯1 > 𝑝𝑝2 π‘₯π‘₯2 if and only if

𝑐𝑐1βˆ’1/πœ€πœ€1

> 𝑐𝑐1βˆ’1/πœ€πœ€2

⟹ 1 βˆ’ 1πœ€πœ€2

< 1 βˆ’ 1πœ€πœ€1

⟹1πœ€πœ€2

>1πœ€πœ€1⟹ πœ€πœ€2 < πœ€πœ€1

β€’ Intuition: the monopolist charges lower price in the market with more elastic demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 72

Page 73: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Third-degree

β€’ Example (Pullman-Seattle route):– The price-elasticity of demand for business-class

seats is -1.15, while that for economy seats is -1.52– From the IEPR,

𝑝𝑝𝐡𝐡 =𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

1 βˆ’ 1/1.15⟹ 0.13𝑝𝑝𝐡𝐡 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

𝑝𝑝𝐸𝐸 =𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

1 βˆ’ 1/1.52⟹ 0.34𝑝𝑝𝐸𝐸 = 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀

– Hence, 0.13𝑝𝑝𝐡𝐡 = 0.34𝑝𝑝𝐸𝐸 or 𝑝𝑝𝐡𝐡 = 2.62𝑝𝑝𝐸𝐸 Airline maximizes its profits by charging business-class

seats a price 2.62 times higher than that of economy-class seats

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 73

Page 74: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Second-degree price discrimination:– The monopolist cannot observe the type of each

consumer (e.g., his willingness to pay).– Hence the monopolist offers a menu of two-part

tariffs, (𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿, π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) and (𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻, π‘žπ‘žπ»π»), with the property that the consumer with type 𝑖𝑖 = {𝐷𝐷,𝐻𝐻} has the incentive to self-select the two-part tariff (𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 , π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–)meant for him.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 74

Page 75: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Assume the utility function of type 𝑖𝑖 consumerπ‘ˆπ‘ˆπ‘–π‘– π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– ,𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 = πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘–π‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖

where – π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– is the quantity of a good consumed– 𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 is the fixed fee paid to the monopolist for π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–β€“ πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘– measures the valuation consumer assigns to the

good, where πœƒπœƒπ»π» > πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ, with corresponding probabilities 𝑝𝑝 and 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝.

β€’ The monopolist’s constant marginal cost 𝑐𝑐satisfies πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘– > 𝑐𝑐 for all 𝑖𝑖 = {𝐷𝐷,𝐻𝐻}.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 75

Page 76: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ The monopolist must guarantee that1) both types of customers are willing to

participate (β€œparticipation constraint”) the two-part tariff meant for each type of customer

provides him with a weakly positive utility level

2) customers do not have incentives to choose the two-part tariff meant for the other type of customer (β€œincentive compatibility”) type 𝑖𝑖 customer prefers (𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 , π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–) over (𝐹𝐹𝑗𝑗 , π‘žπ‘žπ‘—π‘—) where 𝑗𝑗 β‰  𝑖𝑖

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 76

Page 77: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ The participation constraints (PC) areπœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 β‰₯ 0 π‘ƒπ‘ƒπ‘€π‘€πΏπΏπœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 β‰₯ 0 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻

β€’ The incentive compatibility conditions areπœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 β‰₯ πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 πΌπΌπ‘€π‘€πΏπΏπœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 β‰₯ πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 77

Page 78: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Rearranging the four inequalities, the monopolist’s profit maximization problem becomes:

max𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿,π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ,𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻,π‘žπ‘žπ»π»

𝑝𝑝 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ»π» + 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 [𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ]

πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) β‰₯ πΉπΉπΏπΏπœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») β‰₯ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻

πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») + 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 β‰₯ πΉπΉπΏπΏπœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) + 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 β‰₯ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 78

Page 79: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Both 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 and 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 are expressed in terms of the fee 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻– The monopolist increases 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 until such fee coincides

with the lowest of πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») and πœƒπœƒπ»π»[]

𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) + 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 for all 𝑖𝑖 = {𝐷𝐷,𝐻𝐻}

– Otherwise, one (or both) constraints will be violated, leading the high-demand customer to not participate

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 79

Page 80: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 80

Page 81: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ High-demand customer:– Let us show that 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 is binding

– An indirect way to show that

𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 = πœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) + 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿

is to demonstrate that 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 < πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π»)

– Proving this by contradiction, assume that 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 = πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π»)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 81

Page 82: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree– Then, 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 can be written as

𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ + 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 β‰₯ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻⟹ 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 β‰₯ πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ)

– Combining this result with the fact that πœƒπœƒπ»π» > πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ,𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 β‰₯ πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ > πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ

which implies 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 > πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ

– However, this violates 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 We then reached a contradiction Thus, 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 < πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 is binding but 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 is not.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 82

Page 83: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Low-demand customer:– Let us show that 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 binding

– Similarly as for the high-demand customer, an indirect way to show that

𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 = πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ)is to demonstrate that 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 < πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») + 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻

– Proving this by contradiction, assume that 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 = πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπ»π» + 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 83

Page 84: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

– Then, 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 can be written as

πœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) + πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») + 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 = 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻⟹ πœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) = πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ)⟹ πœƒπœƒπ»π» = πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ

which violates the initial assumption πœƒπœƒπ»π» > πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ We reached a contradiction Thus, 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 < πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπ»π» + 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 is binding but 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 is not

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 84

Page 85: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ In summary:– From 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 binding we have

πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ = 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿– From 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 binding we have

πœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπ»π» βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ + 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 = 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻– In addition,

β€’ 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 binding implies that 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 holds, and β€’ 𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 binding entails that 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 is also satisfied, β€’ That is, all four constraints hold.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 85

Page 86: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ The monopolist’s expected PMP can then be written as unconstrained problem, as follows,

maxπ‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ,π‘žπ‘žπ»π»β‰₯0

𝑝𝑝 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ»π» + 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 [𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ]

= 𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπ»π» βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ + 𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻

βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ»π»

+ 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏπΉπΉπΏπΏ

βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ

= 𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπ»π» 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπ»π» βˆ’ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ + πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏπΉπΉπΏπΏ

βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ»π»

+ 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ= 𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπ»π» βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπ»π» βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ 𝑒𝑒 π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ»π»

+(1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝) πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’ π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 86

Page 87: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ FOC with respect to π‘žπ‘žπ»π»:𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’β€²(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0 ⟹ πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’β€²(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») = 𝑐𝑐

– which coincides with that under complete information. – That is, there is not output distortion for high-demand buyer – Informally, we say that there is β€œno distortion at the top”.

β€’ FOC with respect to π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ:𝑝𝑝 βˆ’(πœƒπœƒπ»π» βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ)𝑒𝑒′(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) + 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 πœƒπœƒπΏπΏπ‘’π‘’β€²(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐 = 0

which can be re-written as

𝑒𝑒′(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ βˆ’ π‘π‘πœƒπœƒπ»π» = 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 𝑐𝑐Advanced Microeconomic Theory 87

Page 88: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Dividing both sides by 1 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝 , we obtain

𝑒𝑒′(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) πœƒπœƒπΏπΏβˆ’π‘π‘πœƒπœƒπ»π»1βˆ’π‘π‘

= 𝑐𝑐

β€’ The above expression can alternatively be written as

𝑒𝑒′(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ βˆ’π‘π‘

1βˆ’π‘π‘πœƒπœƒπ»π» βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ = 𝑐𝑐

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 88

Page 89: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ The output offered to low-demand customers entails a distortion, i.e., π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ < π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏπ‘ π‘ π‘‘π‘‘

β€’ Per-unit price for high-type and low-type differs, i.e., 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 β‰  𝐹𝐹𝐿𝐿– Monopolist practices price

discrimination among the two types of customers.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 89

β€’ 𝑒𝑒′(π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ) οΏ½ πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ depicts the socially optimal output π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏπ‘ π‘ π‘‘π‘‘, i.e., that arising under complete information

β€’ The output offered to high-demand customers is socially efficient due to the absence of output distortion for high-type agents

Page 90: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Since constraint 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐿𝐿 binds while 𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀𝐻𝐻 does not, then only the high-demand customer retains a positive utility level, i.e., πœƒπœƒπ»π»π‘’π‘’(π‘žπ‘žπ»π») βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝐻𝐻 > 0.

β€’ The firm’s lack of information provides the high-demand customer with an β€œinformation rent.” – Intuitively, the information rent emerges from the

seller’s attempt to reduce the incentives of the high-type customer to select the contract meant for the low type.

– The seller also achieves self-selection by setting an attractive output for the low-type buyer, i.e., π‘žπ‘žπΏπΏ is lower than under complete information.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 90

Page 91: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Example:– Consider a monopolist selling a textbook to two

types of graduate students, low- and high-demand, with utility function

π‘ˆπ‘ˆπ‘–π‘–(π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– ,𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖) = π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–2

2βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘–π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖

where 𝑖𝑖 = {𝐷𝐷,𝐻𝐻} and πœƒπœƒπ»π» > πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ. – Hence, the UMP of type 𝑖𝑖 student is

maxπ‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–

π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–2

2βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘–π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ 𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 s. t. π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– + 𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 ≀ 𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖

where 𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖 > 0 denotes the student’s wealth.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 91

Page 92: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Example (continued):– By Walras’ law, the constraint binds

𝐹𝐹𝑖𝑖 = 𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–β€“ Then, the UMP can be expressed as

maxπ‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–

π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–2

2βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘–π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ (𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–)

– FOCs wrt π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– yields the direct demand function: π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘– + 𝑝𝑝 = 0 or π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– = πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘– βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 92

Page 93: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Price Discrimination: Second-degree

β€’ Example (continued):– Assume that the proportion of high-demand (low-

demand) students is 𝛾𝛾 (1 βˆ’ 𝛾𝛾, respectively).

– The monopolist’s constant marginal cost is 𝑐𝑐 > 0, which satisfies πœƒπœƒπ‘–π‘– > 𝑐𝑐 for all 𝑖𝑖 = {𝐷𝐷,𝐻𝐻}.

– Consider for simplicity that πœƒπœƒπΏπΏ > πœƒπœƒπ»π»+𝑐𝑐2

.

– This implies that each type of student would buy the textbook, both when the firm practices uniform pricing and when it sets two-part tariffs Exercise.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 93

Page 94: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advertising in Monopoly

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 94

Page 95: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advertising in Monopoly

β€’ Advertising: non-price strategy to capture surplus

β€’ The monopolist must balance the additional demand that advertising entails and its associated costs (𝐴𝐴 dollars)

β€’ The monopolist solvesmax𝐴𝐴

𝑝𝑝 οΏ½ π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,𝐴𝐴 βˆ’ 𝑇𝑇𝑀𝑀 π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,𝐴𝐴 βˆ’ 𝐴𝐴

where the demand function π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,𝐴𝐴 depends on price and advertising.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 95

Page 96: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advertising in Monopolyβ€’ Taking FOCs with respect to 𝐴𝐴,

𝑝𝑝 οΏ½ πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,π΄π΄πœ•πœ•π΄π΄

βˆ’ οΏ½πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•π‘€π‘€πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘žπ‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€

οΏ½ πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,π΄π΄πœ•πœ•π΄π΄

βˆ’ 1 = 0

Rearranging, we obtain

𝑝𝑝 βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€ πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,π΄π΄πœ•πœ•π΄π΄

= 1β€’ Let us define the advertising elasticity of demand

πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝐴𝐴 = % increse in π‘žπ‘ž% increse in 𝐴𝐴

= πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,π΄π΄πœ•πœ•π΄π΄

οΏ½ π΄π΄π‘žπ‘ž

Or, rearranging,

πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝐴𝐴 οΏ½π‘žπ‘žπ΄π΄

= πœ•πœ•π‘žπ‘ž 𝑝𝑝,π΄π΄πœ•πœ•π΄π΄

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 96

Page 97: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advertising in Monopoly

β€’ We can then rewrite the above FOC as

𝑝𝑝 βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€ πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝐴𝐴 οΏ½π‘žπ‘žπ΄π΄

πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ• 𝑝𝑝,π΄π΄πœ•πœ•π΄π΄

= 1

β€’ Dividing both sides by πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝐴𝐴 and rearranging

𝑝𝑝 βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€ = 1πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝐴𝐴

οΏ½ π΄π΄π‘žπ‘ž

β€’ Dividing both sides by π‘π‘π‘π‘βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘π‘

= 1πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝐴𝐴

οΏ½ π΄π΄π‘π‘οΏ½π‘žπ‘ž

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 97

Page 98: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advertising in Monopoly

β€’ From the Lerner index, we know that π‘π‘βˆ’π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘€π‘π‘

= βˆ’ 1πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝑝𝑝

. Hence,

βˆ’ 1πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝑝𝑝

= 1πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝐴𝐴

οΏ½ π΄π΄π‘π‘οΏ½π‘žπ‘ž

β€’ And rearranging

βˆ’πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝐴𝐴

πœ€πœ€πœ•πœ•,𝑝𝑝= 𝐴𝐴

π‘π‘οΏ½π‘žπ‘žβ€“ The right-hand side represents the advertising-to-sales

ratio.– For two markets with the same πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝑝𝑝, the advertising-to-

sales ratio must be larger in the market where demand is more sensitive to advertising (higher πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝐴𝐴).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 98

Page 99: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Advertising in Monopoly

β€’ Example: – If the price-elasticity in a given monopoly market

is πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝑝𝑝 = βˆ’1.5 and the advertising-elasticity is πœ€πœ€π‘žπ‘ž,𝐴𝐴 = 0.1, the advertising-to-sales ratio should be

π΄π΄π‘π‘οΏ½π‘žπ‘ž

= βˆ’ 0.1βˆ’1.5

= 0.067

– Advertising should account for 6.7% of this monopolist’s revenue.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 99

Page 100: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 100

Page 101: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ Natural monopolies: Monopolies that exhibit decreasing cost structures, with the MC curve lying below the AC curve.

β€’ Hence, having a single firm serving the entire market is cheaper than having multiple firms, as aggregate average costs for the entire industry would be lower.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 101

Page 102: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopoliesβ€’ Unregulated natural

monopolist maximizes profits at the point where MR=MC, producing 𝑄𝑄1units and selling them at a price 𝑝𝑝1.

β€’ Regulated natural monopolist will charge 𝑝𝑝2(where demand crosses MC) and produce 𝑄𝑄2units.

β€’ The production level 𝑄𝑄2implies a loss of 𝑝𝑝2 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐2per unit.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 102

Page 103: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ Dilemma with natural monopolies:– abandon the policy of setting prices equal to

marginal cost, OR– continue applying marginal cost pricing but

subsidize the monopolist for his lossesβ€’ Solution to the dilemma:

– A multi-price system that allows for price discrimination

– Charging some users a high price while maintaining a low price to other users

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 103

Page 104: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ Multi-price system: – a high price 𝑝𝑝1– a low price 𝑝𝑝2

β€’ Benefit: (𝑝𝑝1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐1) per unit in the interval from 0 to 𝑄𝑄1

β€’ Loss: (𝑐𝑐2 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝2) per unit in the interval (𝑄𝑄2 βˆ’ 𝑄𝑄1)

β€’ The monopolist price discriminates iff

𝑝𝑝1 βˆ’ 𝑐𝑐1 𝑄𝑄1 >(𝑐𝑐2 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝2)(𝑄𝑄2 βˆ’ 𝑄𝑄1)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 104

Page 105: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ An alternative regulation:– allow the monopolist to charge a price above

marginal cost that is sufficient to earn a β€œfair” rate of return on capital investments

β€’ Two difficulties:– what is a β€œfair” rate of return– overcapitalization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 105

Page 106: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ Overcapitalization of natural monopolies:– Suppose a production function of the form π‘žπ‘ž =𝑓𝑓(π‘˜π‘˜, 𝑙𝑙). An unregulated monopoly with profit function 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓 π‘˜π‘˜, 𝑙𝑙 βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀𝑙𝑙 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿπ‘˜π‘˜ has a rate of return on capital, π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ. Suppose furthermore that the rate of return on capital investments, π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ, is constrained by a regulatory agency to be equal to π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 106

Page 107: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ PMP:𝐷𝐷 = 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓 π‘˜π‘˜, 𝑙𝑙 βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀𝑙𝑙 βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿπ‘˜π‘˜

+πœ†πœ† 𝑀𝑀𝑙𝑙 + π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0π‘˜π‘˜ βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓(π‘˜π‘˜, 𝑙𝑙)where 0 < πœ†πœ† < 1.

β€’ FOCs:πœ•πœ•πΏπΏπœ•πœ•π‘‘π‘‘

= 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓𝑑𝑑 βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀 + πœ†πœ† 𝑀𝑀 βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓𝑑𝑑 = 0πœ•πœ•πΏπΏπœ•πœ•π‘˜π‘˜

= π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ + πœ†πœ† π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0 βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ = 0πœ•πœ•πΏπΏπœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•

= 𝑀𝑀𝑙𝑙 + π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0π‘˜π‘˜ βˆ’ 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓 π‘˜π‘˜, 𝑙𝑙 = 0Advanced Microeconomic Theory 107

Page 108: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopolies

β€’ From the first FOC:𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓𝑑𝑑 = 𝑀𝑀

β€’ From the second FOC:1 βˆ’ πœ†πœ† π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ = π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ βˆ’ πœ†πœ†π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0

and rearranging

π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ = π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿβˆ’πœ•πœ•π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ01βˆ’πœ•πœ•

= π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ βˆ’ πœ•πœ•(π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0βˆ’π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ)1βˆ’πœ•πœ•

– Since π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0 > π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ and 0 < πœ†πœ† < 1, then π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ < π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ.– Hence, the firm would hire more capital than under

unregulated condition, where π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ = π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 108

Page 109: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopoliesβ€’ π‘π‘π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜ is the value of the

marginal product of capital– It is decreasing in π‘˜π‘˜ (due to

diminishing marginal return, i.e., π‘“π‘“π‘˜π‘˜π‘˜π‘˜ < 0)

β€’ π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ and π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ βˆ’ πœ•πœ•(π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0βˆ’π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ)1βˆ’πœ•πœ•

are the marginal cost of additional units of capital in the unregulated and regulated monopoly, respectively

π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ > π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ βˆ’ πœ•πœ•(π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ0βˆ’π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ)1βˆ’πœ•πœ•

β€’ Example: electricity and water suppliers

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 109

Page 110: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Regulation of Natural Monopoliesβ€’ An alternative illustration

of the overcapitalization (Averch-Johnson effect)

β€’ Before regulation, the firm selects (𝐷𝐷𝐡𝐡𝑀𝑀 ,𝐾𝐾𝐡𝐡𝑀𝑀)

β€’ After regulation, the firm selects (𝐷𝐷𝐴𝐴𝑀𝑀 ,𝐾𝐾𝐴𝐴𝑀𝑀), where 𝐾𝐾𝐴𝐴𝑀𝑀 > 𝐾𝐾𝐡𝐡𝑀𝑀 but 𝐷𝐷𝐴𝐴𝑀𝑀 < 𝐷𝐷𝐡𝐡𝑀𝑀

β€’ The overcapitalization result only captures the substitution effect of a cheaper input.– Output effect?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 110

Page 111: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 111

Page 112: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ Monopsony: A single buyer of goods and services exercises β€œbuying power” by paying prices below those that would prevail in a perfectly competitive context.

β€’ Monopsony (single buyer) is analogous to that of a monopoly (single seller).

β€’ Examples: a coal mine, Walmart Superstore in a small town, etc.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 112

Page 113: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ Consider that the monopsony faces competition in the product market, where prices are given at 𝑝𝑝 > 0, but is a monopsony in the input market (e.g., labor services).

β€’ Assume an increasing and concave production function, i.e., 𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯ > 0 and 𝑓𝑓′′ π‘₯π‘₯ ≀ 0.– This yields a total revenue of 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓 π‘₯π‘₯ .

β€’ Consider a cost function 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯ οΏ½ π‘₯π‘₯, where 𝑀𝑀(π‘₯π‘₯) denotes the inverse supply function of labor π‘₯π‘₯. – Assume that 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯ > 0 for all π‘₯π‘₯.– This indicates that, as the firm hires more workers, labor

becomes scarce, thus increasing the wages of additional workers.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 113

Page 114: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ The monopsony PMP is maxπ‘₯π‘₯

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓 π‘₯π‘₯ βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯ π‘₯π‘₯β€’ FOC wrt the amount of labor services π‘₯π‘₯ yields

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— = 0⟹ 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

𝐴𝐴= 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— + 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

𝐡𝐡– 𝐴𝐴: β€œmarginal revenue product” of labor.– 𝐡𝐡: β€œmarginal expenditure” (ME) on labor. The additional worker entails a monetary outlay of 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— . Hiring more workers make labor become more scarce,

ultimately forcing the monopsony to raise the prevailing wage on all inframarginal workers, as captured by 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 114

Page 115: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ Monopsonist hiring and salary decisions.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 115

– The marginal revenue product of labor, 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯ , is decreasing in π‘₯π‘₯ given that 𝑓𝑓′′ π‘₯π‘₯ ≀ 0.

– The labor supply, 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯ , is increasing in π‘₯π‘₯ since 𝑀𝑀′(π‘₯π‘₯) > 0.

– The marginal expenditure (ME) on labor lies above the supply function w π‘₯π‘₯since 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯ > 0.

– The monopsony hires π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—workers at a salary of 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— .

Page 116: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ A deadweight loss from monopsony is

𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷 = ∫π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—π‘₯π‘₯𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯ βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯ 𝑑𝑑π‘₯π‘₯

β€’ That is, the area below the marginal revenue product and above the supply curve, between π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— and π‘₯π‘₯𝑃𝑃𝑀𝑀workers.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 116

Page 117: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ We can write the monopsony profit-maximizing condition, i.e., 𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— = 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— + 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—, in terms of labor supply elasticity, using the following steps:

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— = 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— + πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ• π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

πœ•πœ•π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

= 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— 1 + πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ• π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

πœ•πœ•π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

πœ•πœ• π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—β€’ And rearranging,

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— = 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— 1 + 1πœ•πœ•π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•

πœ•πœ• π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 117

Page 118: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ Since πœ•πœ•π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ• π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—represents the elasticity of labor

supply πœ€πœ€, then

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— = 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— 1 + 1πœ€πœ€

β€’ Intuitively, as πœ€πœ€ β†’ ∞ (labor supply becoming perfectly elastic), the behavior of the monopsonist approaches that of a pure competitor.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 118

Page 119: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ The equilibrium condition above is also sufficient as long as

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— βˆ’ 2𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— βˆ’ 𝑀𝑀′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— < 0

β€’ Since 𝑓𝑓′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— < 0, 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— > 0 (by assumption), we only need that either:

a) the supply function is convex, i.e., 𝑀𝑀′′(π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—) > 0; or

b) if it is concave, i.e., 𝑀𝑀′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— < 0, its concavity is not very strong, that is

𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— βˆ’ 2𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— < 𝑀𝑀′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 119

Page 120: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ Example:– Consider a monopsonist with production function 𝑓𝑓 π‘₯π‘₯ = π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘₯π‘₯, where π‘Žπ‘Ž > 0, and facing a given market price 𝑝𝑝 > 0 per unit of output.

– Labor supply is 𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯ = 𝑏𝑏π‘₯π‘₯, where 𝑏𝑏 > 0. – The marginal revenue product of hiring an

additional worker is𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′ π‘₯π‘₯ = π‘π‘π‘Žπ‘Ž

– The marginal expenditure on labor is𝑀𝑀 π‘₯π‘₯ + 𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯ π‘₯π‘₯ = 𝑏𝑏π‘₯π‘₯ + 𝑏𝑏π‘₯π‘₯ = 2𝑏𝑏π‘₯π‘₯

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 120

Page 121: Advanced Microeconomic Theory - WordPress.com

Monopsony

β€’ Example (continued):– Setting them equal to each other, π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘π‘ = 2𝑏𝑏π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—,

yields a profit-maximizing amount of labor:

π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— =π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘π‘2𝑏𝑏

– π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— increases in the price of output, 𝑝𝑝, and in the marginal productivity of labor, π‘Žπ‘Ž; but decreases in the slope of labor supply, 𝑏𝑏.

– Sufficiency holds since𝑝𝑝𝑓𝑓′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— βˆ’ 2𝑀𝑀′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— = 𝑝𝑝𝑏 βˆ’ 2𝑏𝑏 < 0 = 𝑀𝑀′′ π‘₯π‘₯βˆ— π‘₯π‘₯βˆ—

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 121