Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence ....

45
Dilip Mookherjee Stefan Napel Intergenerational Mobility and Macroeconomic History Dependence Aboa Centre for Economics Discussion Paper No. 1 Turku 2006

Transcript of Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence ....

Page 1: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Dilip Mookherjee ― Stefan Napel

Intergenerational Mobility and Macroeconomic History Dependence

Aboa Centre for Economics

Discussion Paper No. 1 Turku 2006

Page 2: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Copyrigt © Author(s)

ISSN 1796-3133

Turun kauppakorkeakoulun monistamo Turku 2006

Page 3: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Dilip Mookherjee ― Stefan Napel Intergenerational Mobility and

Macroeconomic History Dependence

Aboa Centre for Economics Discussion Paper No. 1

March 2006

ABSTRACT

That historical inequality can affect long run macroeconomic per-formance has been argued by a large literature on ‘endogenous inequality’ using models of indivisibilities in occupational choice, in the presence of borrowing constraints. These models are char-acterized by a continuum of steady states, and absence of mobility in any steady state. We augment such a model with heterogeneity in agents’ abilities in order to generate occupational mobility in steady state. Steady states with mobility are shown to be generi-cally locally unique and finite in number. We provide forms of heterogeneity for which steady state is globally unique, and others where they are non-unique. Agent heterogeneity may also cause competitive equilibrium dynamics to fail to converge, but conver-gence can be restored in the presence of sufficient ‘inertia’ or occu-pation switching costs. JEL Classification: D31, D91, E25, I21, J24, O11, O15 Keywords: Intergenerational mobility, occupational choice, human capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence

Page 4: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Contact information

Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Department of Economics 270 Bay State Road Boston MA, 02215 Fax +1-617-353-4143 [email protected] Stefan Napel University of Hamburg Department of Economics Von-Melle-Park 5 D-20146 Hamburg Fax +49-40-42838-3957 [email protected]

Acknowledgements

Napel gratefully acknowledges financial support from the German Academic Exchange Service (DAAD), and thanks the Department of Economics, Boston University for hosting his visit for a year during which this research project was started. Mookherjee ac-knowledges support from the MacArthur Foundation Inequality Network, and National Science Foundation grant no. SES-0418434. We thank two anonymous referees for extraordinarily helpful comments. We also acknowledge discussions with Alfred Müller and Jörgen Weibull, and comments of seminar participants at Hamburg, Salerno, Simon Fraser and the June 2004 Stanford SITE workshop on Development Economics, which have helped improve the paper.

Page 5: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

1 Introduction

The role of history in powerfully shaping the nature of economic developmentmany centuries later has been argued by many recent authors ([1],[6],[12]).These authors describe how historical inequality associated with colonial in-stitutions can help explain differences in economic backwardness even long afterthese institutions have disappeared. This raises the question: what preventssuch countries from catching up with more developed countries, once these colo-nial institutions have disappeared?

Theoretical explanations of the role of historical inequality in determininglong run macroeconomic performance have been based on indivisibilities in oc-cupational choice combined with credit constraints. In [7],[15], and [16], equaland unequal steady states are shown to co-exist, with historical distributionsdetermining which steady state the economy converges to. In much of the liter-ature in this field (e.g., [4-5],[13],[19],[24],[27]) a continuum of steady states areshown to exist, all of which are unequal, and involve zero mobility.1 A typicalsteady state without mobility entails strict incentives for skilled parents to investin the skills of their children, and likewise for unskilled parents not to invest:these strict incentives are preserved with small perturbations in the proportionof skilled households, thus allowing the steady state set to form a continuum.The steady states are ordered by per capita skill, income, consumption, andwage inequality; those with higher per capita income also involve lower inequal-ity (and so are representative of more developed countries). Since there is acontinuum of such steady states, small temporary shocks or policies to steadystates have permanent macro effects, and can therefore be remarkably effectivein affecting long term development.

The feature of zero mobility in income or occupations is clearly at oddswith reality: even the most unequal societies are typically characterized bysome mobility. One would expect that it would be relatively straightforwardto explain the presence of occupational mobility by enriching these models toallow heterogeneity of agents’ characteristics, in the style of [9],[20] or [22]. Forinstance, if children’s learning abilities are randomly generated, occupationalmobility would emerge owing to the tendency for unusually gifted children inpoor families to acquire education (and conversely untalented children in richfamilies would fail to become educated). Alternatively if wage incomes withinany occupation are subject to sources of randomness (as in [7] and [26]), it couldgenerate mobility (as some unskilled households earn above-normal wages, orskilled households earn below-normal wages).

1The continuum of steady states also appears in [15-16]. However, there are some papers in

which there are steady states with mobility, such as [7],[9],[20],[22],[26]. A detailed comparison

with the existing literature is provided in Section 6.

5

Page 6: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

This paper studies the implications of introducing such forms of heterogene-ity (or income risk) in a model of human capital accumulation which generatespositive mobility in steady state. The model has two occupations, skilled andunskilled. To enter the skilled occupation an agent needs to acquire an educa-tion. Agents are heterogenous with respect to their cost of getting educated,reflecting their innate learning ability; these costs are treated as i.i.d. randomvariables. We abstract from income risk for the sake of simplicity, though theeffects of such risk would be qualitatively similar to the effects of heterogenouslearning ability.2 Parents cannot borrow against their children’s future earnings:this is the key capital market imperfection.3

We explore existence and multiplicity of steady states as well as non-steady-state dynamics within this model in some generality. We provide three principalsets of theoretical results. First, steady states with mobility are (generically)locally unique and finite in number. This is in contrast to the case of homo-geneous agents and riskless incomes which generally has a continuum of steadystates.

Second, we explore conditions for global uniqueness, and show how thesedepend on the ability distribution. We provide sufficient conditions only in termsof the range (i.e., endpoints) of the distribution for both uniqueness and non-uniqueness of steady states. Global uniqueness obtains if the range of schoolingcosts is shifted down sufficiently, and preferences for schooling do not switchmore than twice with respect to a rise in the skill ratio in the economy. Incontrast, there is (generically) more than one mobile steady state if the rangeof schooling cost is shifted up sufficiently.

Third, we explore non-steady-state dynamics. With agent homogeneity andlack of income risk, competitive equilibrium with perfect foresight always con-verges to a steady state. With the introduction of heterogeneity, competitiveequilibrium may fail to converge. However global convergence can be restoredwith restrictions on the speed of ‘adjustment’. Under these conditions, multi-plicity or otherwise of steady states translates into corresponding statements ofdependence of long run outcomes on initial conditions.

We also numerically compute the set of steady states in an economy withCobb-Douglas technology, logarithmic utility and a variety of ability distribu-

2Indeed, in the case of logarithmic utility it is easily verified that the two phenomena

(heterogenous abilities and income risk) are isomorphic with respect to investment incentives

and therefore the same model and results apply to the context of income risk as well. We are

also abstracting from intergenerational transmission of ability, in the interest of simplicity.

Incorporating this would require abilities of parents and children to be correlated.

3The benchmark case of homogeneous ability corresponds to the models in [13],[19],[24].

The baseline model in this paper differs from [24] only with respect to the bequest motive:

instead of a dynastic bequest motive it is assumed that parents care about the incomes earned

by their children, apart from their own consumption.

6

Page 7: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

tions. In all examples with a continuous ability distribution (including uniform,exponential and truncated normal distributions) with a wide enough support,and with a low level poverty trap (where at low enough skill ratios, unskilledwages fall below the minimum education cost, so that unskilled parents cannotafford to educate their children), we found only one locally stable steady statewith mobility. However, examples of multiple locally stable steady states withmobility can be constructed with discrete (or sufficiently ‘jagged’ continuous)ability distributions, or with standard well-behaved distributions when a lowlevel poverty trap does not exist.

The principal implication of these results is that the extent of history de-pendence (or the steady state set) shrinks markedly upon applying arbitrarily‘small’ perturbations of a homogeneous agent economy with perfect income cer-tainty. In general, small temporary shocks do not affect long run outcomes.For suitable ranges of the distribution of ability shocks, as well as in our nu-merical examples with well-behaved continuous ability distributions and a lowlevel poverty trap, the long run outcome is unique and independent of initialconditions. For others, it is non-unique and there exist ‘large’ temporary shocksor policies with permanent impact.

The main contrast with papers such as [7],[26] is that they provide examplesof particular parameter values for which multiple steady states with mobilityexist, but do not provide more general results. For instance, they do not addressissues of local uniqueness, whether there are parameter zones with a uniquesteady state, or the general dynamic properties of the system. The contrastwith [9] or [20] is that they have a unique steady state with mobility, owingmainly to their assumption of a convex investment technology.

The intuition for our uniqueness results is somewhat akin to the effects ofenriching the occupational space to allow diversity of occupations (i.e., removingthe indivisibility in investment options). As shown in [24,25] steady states withoccupational diversity are characterized by incentive constraints in the form ofequality rather than inequality constraints: agents have to be locally indiffer-ent between their own occupation and neighboring occupations. These equalityconstraints pin down the steady state uniquely. In this paper we retain occu-pational indivisibilities and instead introduce heterogeneity in education cost.Steady states with mobility are characterized by ability thresholds for educa-tional investments among unskilled and skilled households respectively, whereagents at the threshold are indifferent between educating and not educatingtheir children. Hence the steady state is characterized by incentive constraintsfor the threshold type that take the form of equality constraints. This removesthe scope for local multiplicity of mobile steady states: small perturbations tothe skill ratio cause the steady state conditions to be violated.

A potential criticism of this paper is that long run ergodic properties may

7

Page 8: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

be of less interest than the short or intermediate run, i.e., where the extentof persistence of income or occupational status is more fundamental. Fromthis perspective the effect of introducing small shocks to income or ability to astandard endogenous inequality model is hardly dramatic. We would reply tosuch a criticism as follows. First, much of the discussion in the literature onhistorical origins of underdevelopment spans several centuries, so presumablythe long run is of some interest. Second, there is no reason to believe thatthe importance of ability heterogeneity or residual income risk is small, relativeto the effect of parental status. Empirical findings suggest that differences inparental status explains part of the difference between earnings of children, butconsiderable residual unexplained variation still remains (see, e.g., [10] for asummary of empirical results in the field, where more than 50% of variationin earnings typically remain unexplained). Hence the dynamics induced bysuch shocks may be just as important as those associated with parental status.Models where such heterogeneity or income risk are substantial would seem tobe more focal than ones where they are entirely absent. Moreover, they areneeded to explain the fact that almost every society experiences non-negligiblemobility. Hence conclusions concerning history dependence are better basedon models of this genre. And as we show, such models tend to generate longrun history dependence only under special conditions, suggesting the need forempirical research concerning the validity of such conditions as a way of testingthe hypothesis of history dependence.4

Section 2 introduces the model. Section 3 explains the baseline case of ho-mogeneous ability, where the set of steady states forms a continuum, and com-petitive equilibrium dynamics are globally convergent and history-dependent.Section 3 provides steady state uniqueness results for the model with hetero-geneity, while Section 4 discusses non-steady state dynamics. Section 5 describeshow this paper relates to existing literature in some detail. Section 6 concludeswith a discussion of future research questions concerning occupational mobility.

2 Model

There is a continuum of families indexed by j ∈ [0, 1]. At each date t = 0, 1, 2, . . .

family j is represented by an agent who lives as an adult for one period. Thisagent is also referred to by j. Any generation-t agent j has an occupationoj

t ∈ {n, s}, referring to either unskilled or skilled labor. The fraction of skilledagents in period t is denoted by λt. Each agent supplies one unit of laborinelastically, as long as the wage rate exceeds a positive reservation wage w > 0

4For instance, the conditions involved include non-monotonicity of investment incentives

of unskilled households with respect to the skill ratio in the economy, which is empirically

testable.

8

Page 9: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

which represents the value of leisure or some backyard self-employment option.The economy produces a single consumption good under conditions of perfect

competition. Output is given by a production function H which is assumed tobe twice continuously differentiable, strictly concave in both types of labor, hasconstant returns to scale, and satisfies Inada end-point conditions. The marginalproducts of the unskilled and skilled respectively are given by functions hn(λ)and hs(λ) respectively, where hn is strictly increasing, hs is strictly decreasing,hn(0) = 0 = hs(1); hn(1) = hs(0) = ∞.

Skilled workers can choose whether to work as skilled or unskilled employees,implying that the skilled wage can never fall below the unskilled wage. Letλ̄ ∈ (0, 1) be defined by the property that hn(λ̄) = hs(λ̄) ( = w̄ say). Then ifwn(λ) and ws(λ) denote wages of the unskilled and skilled respectively, and λ

denotes the skill ratio at which hn = w, it follows that equilibrium wages aregiven by5

wn(λ) =

w if λ ≤ λ

hn(λ) if λ ∈ (λ, λ̄)

hn(λ̄) if λ ≥ λ̄,

(1)

and

ws(λ) =

hs(λ) if λ ≤ λ

hs(λ) if λ ∈ (λ, λ̄)

hs(λ̄) if λ ≥ λ̄.

(2)

The ability of a child is represented by the cost x ≥ 0 (denominated in unitsof the consumption good) that its parent would have to incur in order for thechild to enter the skilled profession. These costs are i.i.d. random variables witha distribution function F on a range [x, x̄]. The endpoints are characterized bythe property that x = inf{x |F (x) > 0} and x̄ = sup{x |F (x) < 1}. Most ofour results will be stated in terms of properties of these endpoints, and will notdepend on other features of the distribution F . So as to admit a wide rangeof possible distributions, we shall allow F to be generated by a mixture of acontinuous density f and a finite number of mass points over the range [x, x̄].6

Parents have to finance their child’s education but cannot borrow againsttheir descendent’s income. So education for a generation-t agent j has to bepaid from its parent’s income wj; t−1.7 There is no way to transfer wealth be-

5If the skill ratio in the economy as a whole falls below λ, the skill ratio in the production

sector will be pegged at λ, with surplus unskilled workers withdrawing from the production

sector into leisure or self-employment.

6The only essential restriction here is that we rule out an infinite set of mass points. This is

mainly a technical simplification, one that we do not expect to have any serious consequences.

7This condition can be relaxed considerably to allow some borrowing but either subject to

a credit limit or with borrowing rates exceeding lending rates. All that matters is that the

9

Page 10: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

tween generations apart from parents’ educational investment.8 The investmentneeded to work in the unskilled profession is zero.

Let Ijt equal 1 if generation-t agent j decides to invest in his child’s education

and 0 otherwise (corresponding to ojt+1 = s and oj

t+1 = n, respectively). Theparents’ bequest motive takes a form of paternalistic altruism, where they careabout the wealth of their children, apart from their own consumption: agent j

selects Ijt to maximize

U(wj; t − xIjt ) + V (wj; t+1), (3)

where U and V are both strictly increasing, continuously differentiable functions,U is strictly concave, and wj; t+1 is determined by Ij

t and the equilibrium skillratio in the economy at t + 1.9

Given skill ratio λt in generation t, the income distribution in that generationis determined: fraction λt households earn ws(λt) while the remaining earnwn(λt). Define the benefit to a generation t parent of investing in his child’seducation: B(λt+1) ≡ V (ws(λt+1)) − V (wn(λt+1)), and the utility sacrificeCo(λt, x) ≡ U(wo(λt))−U(wo(λt)−x) entailed in this investment if the parentis in occupation o and the education cost is x. The consequent net benefit ofinvesting is go(λt, λt+1, x) ≡ B(λt+1)−Co(λt, x). Clearly g is strictly decreasingin x, going to −∞ as x → ∞ and nonnegative for x = 0. Hence we candefine a threshold cost xo(λt, λt+1) for occupation o parents as the solution togo(λt, λt+1, x) = 0, at which they are indifferent between investing and not.

Let F 0(x) denote the fraction of children with education cost strictly belowx. Then

σ(λt, λt+1) ≡ (1− λt)F 0(xn(λt, λt+1)) + λtF0(xs(λt, λt+1)) (4)

is the fraction of generation t households that strictly prefer to invest, while

in(λt, λt+1) ≡ (1− λt)[F (xn(λt, λt+1))− F 0(xn(λt, λt+1))]

is(λt, λt+1) ≡ λt[F (xs(λt, λt+1))− F 0(xs(λt, λt+1))]

cost of financing investments be higher for poorer parents.

8Consequences of allowing supplemental financial bequests are discussed in [23,25]. In-

equality is then no longer inevitable, as parents of unskilled agents can make compensating

financial bequests to allow equality of income with skilled agents. However this requires a

sufficiently strong bequest motive, relative to the span of earning differentials between occu-

pations. For less strong bequest motives, inequality is again inevitable in steady state, and

properties of that model concerning steady states and non-steady state dynamics are similar

to those in the current model where financial bequests are not allowed.

9This represents a bequest motive less far-sighted and sophisticated than a Barro-Becker

dynastic motive where parents care about the utility of their child, and thus indirectly about

the consumption of all their future descendants. But it is more sensitive to the consequences of

bequests for the well-being of their children, compared to a ‘warm-glow’ bequest motive (where

they care only about the size of the bequest apart from their own consumption) traditionally

assumed in much of the literature (e.g., [7],[15]).

10

Page 11: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

denote the measure of unskilled and skilled households respectively that areindifferent between investing and not investing.

Definition 1 λt+1 is a competitive equilibrium skill ratio in generationt + 1 given skill ratio λt at t if there exist α, β both in [0, 1] such that

λt+1 = σ(λt, λt+1) + αin(λt, λt+1) + βis(λt, λt+1). (5)

In order to avoid a trivial equilibrium, we assume:

(A1) F (0) < λ̄.

If we define a genius to be a child who acquires skill at zero cost (x = 0) then(A1) stipulates that the fraction of geniuses born is less than the skill ratio λ̄

where skilled and unskilled wages are equalized. Clearly all geniuses will acquireskill as long as skilled wages exceed unskilled wages. So if (A1) does not hold,equilibrium will involve λt ≥ λ̄ for all t: there is perfect income equality at alldates and no one with positive education cost will ever invest.

Lemma 1 Suppose (A1) holds. Given any skill ratio λt in generation t, a com-petitive equilibrium skill ratio at t + 1 exists, is unique, and less than λ̄.

The proof of the Lemma as well as of subsequent results is provided inthe Appendix. Existence and uniqueness rest on the fact that the measureφλt(λ

et+1) of households willing to invest at the current skill ratio λt is (apart

from constituting a convex-valued u.s.c. correspondence) strictly decreasing inthe skill ratio λe

t+1 they anticipate for the next generation. This is illustratedin Figure 1. Under (A1), the equilibrium skill ratio must be below λ̄, withwage inequality in every generation.10 Hereafter we denote the mapping ofequilibrium skill ratios across successive generations by λt+1 = E(λt).

Definition 2 A steady state (SS) skill ratio λ∗ is a stationary competitiveequilibrium skill ratio, i.e., a fixed point of E. If there exists a stationary com-petitive equilibrium with skill ratio λ∗ in which a positive measure of unskilled(respectively skilled) households in any given generation become skilled (resp.unskilled) in the next generation, then λ∗ is a steady state with mobility(SSM).

Steady states can be characterized in terms of equality of upward and down-ward mobility flows. Define these as follows:

u(λ) ≡{

µ | µ = (1− λ)[F 0(xn(λ, λ)) + αin(λ, λ)] for some α ∈ [0, 1]}

d(λ) ≡{

µ | µ = λ[1− F (xs(λ, λ))] + βis(λ, λ) for some β ∈ [0, 1]}

10Otherwise there are no benefits from investing, and anyone with positive x will not invest.

So the skill ratio at the next generation cannot exceed F (0), which owing to (A1) is less than

λ̄, contrary to the premise.

11

Page 12: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Then λ is a SS if and only if u(λ) ∩ d(λ) 6= ∅. It is a SSM if there exists apositive mobility flow µ ∈ u(λ) ∩ d(λ).

Proposition 1 A SS always exists.

The rest of the paper turns attention to uniqueness and stability of steadystates.

3 The Case of Homogeneous Agents

We illustrate first the case where the distribution of x is degenerate, concen-trated at a single x = x∗ > 0, so x = x̄ = x∗. This is essentially the modelconsidered by previous literature ([13],[19],[24],[27]). For the sake of complete-ness, we provide a proof of the following proposition, particular versions of whichare available in these papers.11 Figure 2 illustrates the set of steady states andthe nature of the dynamics.

Proposition 2 With homogeneous agents (x = x̄ = x∗ > 0):

(a) If x∗ is large enough that

Cs(λ, x∗) > B(λ) (6)

there is a unique SS at λ = 0;

(b) Otherwise there is a continuum of SS’s. If

Cs(λ, x∗) < B(λ) (7)

there exists an interval of steady state skill ratios within which higher λ

SS’s are associated with higher per capita income and lower skill premiumin wages;

(c) Every SS entails zero mobility;

(d) From any initial skill ratio λ0 at t = 0, the equilibrium skill ratio convergesto a SS, and the dynamics is described as follows. If λ0 is a SS thenλt = λ0 for all t. If λ0 exceeds the highest SS λ̃ then the skill ratio fallsto a SS λ∗ < λ̃ at t = 1 and stays there for ever after. If neither of thesetwo cases apply then λt increases monotonically in t and converges to thenearest SS λ̂ to the right of λ0 where the unskilled are indifferent betweeninvesting and not.

11The papers cited above confine their analysis to steady states, and use a dynastic bequest

motive. So the result here differs in its use of a different bequest motive, and a complete

description of the dynamics. Note however that a complete analysis of dynamics of the model

with a dynastic bequest motive was provided earlier by [27].

12

Page 13: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

The model exhibits an extreme form of history dependence, both at thehousehold and economy-wide level. In steady state, there cannot be any mo-bility, so a household’s occupation is determined entirely by the occupation ofits ancestors. Moreover, there is macroeconomic hysteresis, with a continuumof steady states varying in per capita income and inequality. Starting at anyinterior steady state a one-time small shock to the skill ratio induced either bydemographics, technology, endowments or policy will have a permanent macroeffect. The same is not necessarily true out of steady state, however — e.g., ifthe economy starts at a low (between λp and λ1 in Figure 2) non-steady stateskill ratio, then a small perturbation in the skill ratio will only have a shortterm effect, as the equilibrium skill ratio will converge eventually to the samesteady state λ1.

Note also that it is possible for the set of steady states to not be connected,as ilustrated in Figure 2. The model can therefore explain the phenomenon ofdistinct ‘convergence clubs’ at different ranges of per capita income and humancapital.12 This owes to possible non-monotonicity of the educational incentivesof unskilled with respect to the skill ratio. As λ increases, the benefit fromeducating children decreases, lowering educational incentives for all parents. Atthe same time, the unskilled wage increases, reducing the poverty of unskilledparents, and lowering the sacrifice entailed in educating their children. So thecost and benefit functions for the unskilled can intersect more than once. Thesenon-monotonicities will play an important role in the discussion of uniquenessin the next section.

4 Heterogeneous Ability

4.1 Examples

To illustrate the impact of introducing heterogenous abilities, consider the fol-lowing variation on the homogenous agent case, where a small fraction of chil-dren are unusual with regard to their learning abilities. Here the distributionover x is concentrated at three mass points x = 0 < x∗ < x̄. A fraction γ ofchildren are geniuses, with an educational cost of x = 0, so it will be optimal forthem to become educated in all situations. Another fraction ι of children are id-iots, with an educational cost x̄ so large that their parents will never want to tryto educate them, even if they were skilled and the skill scarcity is at its greatest(i.e., Cs(λ, x̄) > B(λ)). The remaining children are normal and have a common(fixed) educational cost of x∗, as in the previous section. Let the highest steadystate interval in the homogeneous agent economy be denoted by [λ1, λ2]. Sup-

12See [3] for a description of the relevant stylized facts concerning convergence clubs, and

an alternative explanation in terms of financial development.

13

Page 14: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

pose also that the proportion of geniuses and idiots in the population is smallenough in the sense that γ < λ2, ι < 1− λ1.

Consider the case where γι lies in between λ1

1−λ1 and λ2

1−λ2 . In this casedefine λ∗ by the property that λ∗

1−λ∗ = γι , which then falls in between the two

endpoints λ1 and λ2 of the steady state interval. For any λ in this interval to theleft of λ∗, there will be a ‘rightward’ drift in the skill ratio owing to the presenceof the unusual children. Those with normal children will behave exactly as inthe homogeneous agent economy. But not the unusual children: geniuses fromunskilled households will acquire skills, and idiots from skilled households willnot. To the left of λ∗ the upward flow of geniuses from unskilled households willdominate the downward one of idiots from skilled households, inducing the skillratio to rise. This destabilizes what would have constituted a steady state ina population constituted entirely of ‘normal’ children, except only at λ∗. Theperturbation created by introduction of a few unusual children has the effect ofsingling out a unique steady state from the continuum of steady states in thehomogenous agent economy.

Figures 3(a) and (b) illustrate upward and downward flows u(λ) and d(λ)for special numeric instances of the homogenous baseline case and its genius-idiot variation.13 Figure 3(c) shows the effect of heterogeneous costs that areuniformly distributed on a narrow interval. The extent of heterogeneity thereis insufficient to generate steady state mobility. The support of the cost distri-bution is widened in (d) to induce mobility in steady state, but then the steadystate becomes unique. In example (d), notice that the investment preferencesamongst the unskilled exhibit are non-monotone.

Figure 4 shows the effect of different truncations of a normal cost distribu-tion. In (a), the support is again too narrow for any steady state mobility, whilecosts in (b) have full support on the positive reals. Figures 4(c) and (d) showintermediate cases with a positive lower bound on costs, i.e., ruling out veryhigh ability levels. Very low ability levels are also ruled out in (c), resulting in aunique steady state with mobility in addition to an interval of immobile steadystates (the latter require a sufficiently low reservation wage). In (b) and (c) weobtain a unique steady state with mobility. A case of multiple mobile steadystates arises in (d), in which there is no lower bound to ability (i.e., educationcosts have no upper bound). However, only one of the two mobile steady statesis locally stable.

4.2 The General Case with Heterogenous Ability

Return now to the general case of heterogeneous learning abilities, where x < x̄.As explained above, this is essential in order to explain mobility in steady state.

13Figures 3–5 are based on H(λ, 1− λ) =p

λ(1− λ) and U ≡ V ≡ ln.

14

Page 15: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Indeed, there must be enough variation in ability to allow upward and downwardmobility to co-exist, so we hereafter assume that x and x̄ are sufficiently dis-parate that at some skill ratio some children from unskilled families will investand some from skilled families will not:

(A2) There exists λ̌ ∈ (0, λ̄) such that

B(λ̌)− Cn(λ̌, x) > 0 > B(λ̌)− Cs(λ̌, x̄) (8)

This is clearly a necessary condition for existence of a SS with mobility. Thefollowing Lemma provides a sufficient condition for every SS to involve mobility.

Lemma 2 Given any x̄ > 0 there exists a threshold x̂(x̄) > 0 for x below whichevery SS involves positive mobility.

We now present the first major result of the paper, concerning local unique-ness and finiteness of the set of SS’s in the presence of heterogeneity. For thiswe parameterize the altruistic component of the parental utility V (wj; t+1) =δW (wj; t+1), where δ > 0 is a scaling parameter measuring the extent of altru-ism, and W is a strictly increasing, continuously differentiable function. Genericstatements will refer to the set of values of δ for which a given property is true,and will mean that its complement is a set of zero Lebesgue measure.

Proposition 3 Suppose (A1) and (A2) hold. Then generically there are afinite number of mobile steady state skill ratios.

The main idea underlying the result is the following. Mobile steady statesare characterized by equality of upward and downward flows, which are C1

functions (a.e., on the set of continuity points of F ). A continuum of SS’snow requires an interval of values of λ where the upward and downward flowfunctions are tangent to one another. An increase in the altruism parameter δ

raises the upward flow function, and lowers the downward flow function. So asmall perturbation in δ will eliminate any such steady state with tangency ofthe upward and downward flows.

Note that the result does not apply to all steady states, only those thatare mobile. A continuum of immobile SS’s can occur quite non-pathologically,e.g., there can be an interval [0, λ∗] of immobile SS’s where both upward anddownward flows are zero. This is the case arising with homogeneous agents, forinstance, where each occupation class has a strict incentive to not switch to theother class. This essentially requires the lower endpoint x be large enough toshut off all upward mobility for a range of low values of λ. In contrast whenLemma 2 applies then Proposition 3 ensures generic finiteness of the set of allSS’s.

15

Page 16: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

As in general equilibrium theory, generic finiteness is by itself a blunt con-clusion. ‘Finite’ can stand for one as well as several million. Indeed, one canconstruct examples that involve an arbitrary number of mobile SS’s (see thediscussion following Proposition 5). However, they involve special type distri-butions involving either discrete types or continuous approximations to these.Considering a wide range of parameter constellations, our numerical computa-tions with standard ability distributions such as uniform (Figures 3(c) and (d)),truncated normal (Figure 4), or exponential have produced no more than twolocally stable SSM’s, and no more than one such SSM whenever a poverty trapexists for low values of λ (i.e., where there is a minimum education cost x ex-ceeding w, implying that the unskilled wage is insufficient to pay for educationwhenever λ < λ).14

Proposition 3 and Lemma 2 in combination imply that (generically) smalltemporary shocks to SS cannot have permanent effects (assuming that such aSS is locally stable, an issue we will explore in the next section). This conclu-sion requires only appropriate endpoint conditions on the ability distribution asstated in Lemma 2. Hence it applies to arbitrarily small ‘amounts’ of hetero-geneity: the hysteresis result of the homogeneous agent economy represented inProposition 2 is not robust.

4.3 Global Uniqueness

We now turn to the question when SS is globally unique. If SS is locally but notglobally unique then there is still scope for history dependence, and for largetemporary shocks to have permanent macro effects.

We first provide a sufficient condition for global uniqueness, in terms ofranges of the endpoints of the ability distribution, allied with a condition onpreferences and technology that prevents ‘excessive’ non-monotonicity of in-vestment incentives of the unskilled. Recall that as the skill ratio rises, thebenefit of investing falls owing to the shrinking wage premium. On the otherhand the unskilled wage rises, reducing the utility sacrifice for unskilled par-ents in educating their children. This can naturally cause their incentive tobe non-monotone with respect to the skill ratio. The following condition —which we call the double crossing property (DCP) — limits the extent of suchnon-monotonicity to at most two reversals of preference as λ increases.

DCP For any x ∈ [x, x̄] the set of steady skill ratios λ at which an unskilledfamily with education cost x prefers to invest in education is either empty,

14Steady state configurations arising from an exponential distribution on [c,∞) resemble

those arising from a similarly truncated normal distribution. When a poverty trap does not

exist, we have found instances of a second stable SSM at some λ < λ, where a positive mass

of talented children of unskilled parents get education despite the latter earning only w.

16

Page 17: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

a singleton or an interval.

Under DCP, there is at most an interval [λn1 (x), λn

2 (x)] of steady skill ratiosat which an unskilled household with an education cost of x would prefer toinvest. Below λn

1 (x) or above λn2 (x) it would prefer not to invest, so its preference

for investing switches at most twice. We show below that DCP is satisfied ifagents have logarithmic or constant elasticity utility functions with relative riskaversion at least one, and the technology is of the Cobb-Douglas form.

Lemma 3 Let the economy be defined by a Cobb-Douglas production function

H(λ, 1− λ) = λα(1− λ)1−α

for α ∈ (0, 1), utility function

U(wj; t − xIjt ) + δU (wj; t+1)

with δ > 0 and

U(c) = ln(c) or U(c) =c1−ρ

1− ρ

with ρ > 1. Then DCP is satisfied.

We now provide a sufficient condition for global uniqueness.

Proposition 4 Suppose (A1), (A2) and DCP hold, and that in addition:

(a) the upper endpoint x̄ is not too high (in the sense that there exists asteady skill ratio λ̂ where every unskilled household would prefer to invest:B(λ̂) > Cn(λ̂, x̄));

(b) the lower endpoint x is smaller than the threshold x̂(x̄) defined in Lemma 2.

Then there is a globally unique SS, and it involves positive mobility.

An instance of this situation is depicted in Figure 3(d). The proof of theProposition is simple: at skill ratio λ̂, every unskilled family wants to invest,and hence so must every skilled family. Since the downward flow is monotoneincreasing in λ, it is zero at every λ below λ̂. So there cannot be any steadystate with mobility at or below λ̂.

Next, note that at λ̂, the upward flow u is strictly positive. For all higherskill ratios, DCP implies that the upward flow must be strictly decreasing in λ

whenever it is positive.15 Since the downward flow is increasing in λ, it follows

15This is because at λ̂ all unskilled families want to invest, so λ̂ exceeds λn1 (x̄) where the

net investment gain of the highest cost type first turns positive. Further increases in λ above

λ̂ cannot increase the upward flow rate any further: it must be weakly decreasing thereafter.

If the rate is positive then the flow, which equals 1− λ times the flow rate, must be strictly

decreasing.

17

Page 18: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

there must be a unique SS above λ̂. Finally, condition (b) in conjunction withLemma 2 ensures that there cannot exist a SS with zero mobility.

Conditions (a) and (b) on the endpoints of the ability distribution are suffi-cient but clearly not necessary for uniqueness (see Figures 3(b) and 4(b)). Theirrole is that they generate enough upward mobility. Condition (b) says the lowerendpoint of the schooling cost is low enough to ensure there are smart enoughchildren among unskilled families that will move up to the skilled occupation inany steady state. Condition (a) on the upper endpoint ensures that the highestschooling cost is not too large: at some stationary skill ratio even the least ablechild from an unskilled family wants to invest. These conditions prevent lowlevel traps: steady states must lie above λ̂. And over this region investmentincentives of the unskilled are decreasing monotonically, ensuring uniqueness ofsteady state.

The next result presents in contrast a range of circumstances in which thereare multiple SS’s.

Proposition 5 Suppose (A1), (A2) hold, and also:

(a) x > w, with consumption constrained to be nonnegative; and

(b) x̄ is large enough that there will always be downward mobility: Cs(λ, x̄) >

B(λ).

Then:

(i) generically (with respect to δ): mobile SS’s if they exist are non-unique;and

(ii) λ = 0 is a SS without mobility.

This shows that mobile SS’s are generically non-unique in the presence ofa ‘poverty trap’ (where by (a) education cost is bounded away from zero andearnings of the unskilled are insufficient to cover this minimum cost) along witha sufficiently low floor to ability (defined in condition (b)). If one mobile SSexists, there must be at least another one. Figure 4(d) provides an illustrationof this. Note, however, that only one of the two mobile steady states is locallystable (in the sense that the upward flow exceeds the downward flow in a rightneighborhood of the steady state skill ratio). In particular, Proposition 5 saysnothing about the multiplicity of locally stable steady states with mobility.

One may wonder if DCP (or a generalization allowing for at most m ≥ 3preference reversals) can be used to provide bounds on the number of SSM.Figure 5 indicates why this is generally not the case. Its underlying technol-ogy and preferences are as in Figures 1-3, which satisfy DCP. However, thelatter condition merely restricts non-monotonicity of investment incentives of

18

Page 19: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

the unskilled, but does not eliminate it: the upward flow composed of unskilledinvestors can increase over some initial range before it begins to decline withrespect to increases in λ. Over this initial range it is possible to create multiplesteady states with a sufficiently ‘jagged’ ability distribution. This is illustratedin Figure 5, which uses a discrete cost distribution. Clearly, similar examplescan be created with a continuous ability distribution which approximates thediscrete distribution. In general if there are r discrete cost levels, there can existup to 2(r − 1) SSM’s.

In the event of multiple SS’s, it is interesting to note that mobile steadystates are ordered with respect to the extent of mobility:

Proposition 6 Suppose there are two steady states with positive mobility. Thenthe steady state with higher skill ratio has higher mobility, lower wage inequality,and higher per capita income.

This follows from the fact that the downward flow correspondence is strictlyincreasing in λ when it is positive. Comparing two economies with exactly thesame characteristics but operating at two distinct steady states, equality andmobility will be positively related. Richer countries will tend to be more equaland more mobile. However the positive correlation between equality and mo-bility may not obtain when examining comparative static properties of a givensteady state. For instance, if we start at a given steady state and shift the ed-ucation cost distribution downwards, the upward flow correspondence will rise,and the downward flow will fall, at every λ. The steady state skill ratio willmove to the right, but the effect on mobility is ambiguous, depending on whichflow moves more. If the downward flow falls locally ‘by more’ than the increasein the upward flow, the net effect will be to lower steady state mobility. Intu-itively, the greater incentive of the unskilled families to invest in their children’sfuture is outweighed by the greater reluctance of skilled families to allow theirchildren to descend to the unskilled occupation. This may be relevant in un-derstanding cross-country differences in mobility. For instance, [11] finds thatItaly is characterized by a lower level of mobility than the US, despite a moregenerous public education program: our model provides a possible explanationof this finding.

5 Non-Steady-State Dynamics

Agent heterogeneity complicates competitive equilibrium dynamics consider-ably. Recall that in the homogenous agent case, the competitive equilibriumis globally convergent. With even a ‘little bit’ of heterogeneity, competitiveequilibria can fail to converge, even if there should be a unique steady state.

19

Page 20: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

To illustrate this, return to the genius-idiot example. Let λo(λ) denote theskill ratio at the generation following one where it is λ, which would make afamily with occupation o today and a ‘normal’ child indifferent between investingand not. Specifically:

B(λo(λ)) = Co(λ, x).

Since skilled families are richer than unskilled families (given λ < λ̄), we knowthat the threshold is higher for skilled families: λs(λ) > λn(λ). Moreover, λs isa decreasing function, while λn is an increasing function.

Define the drift function D(λ) ≡ λ + (1− λ)γ − λι, the dynamic of the skillratio driven by the unusual children alone (with all ‘normal’ children followingtheir parents’ occupations). Then the competitive equilibrium dynamic will beas follows. If the current skill ratio is λ, the ratio λ′ at the next generation willbe given by D(λ) if this lies in between λn(λ) and λs(λ). Otherwise if D(λ) isless than λn(λ), λ′ will equal λn(λ). In this case unskilled families with normalchildren must be indifferent about investing, and a fraction of them will invest.On the other hand if D(λ) is bigger than λs(λ), then λ′ equals λs(λ): in thiscase a positive fraction of skilled families with normal children will invest, whileall unskilled families with normal children will not.

Let λ1 and λ2 denote the endpoints of the rightmost steady state intervalin the baseline case where there are no geniuses or idiots. Note that at the sta-tionary skill ratio λ1 (resp. λ2), unskilled (resp. skilled) parents are indifferentbetween investing and not. Hence λn(λ1) = λ1 and λs(λ2) = λ2. See Figures 6and 7.

If the dynamic of skill ratios follows the λn function over the entire range,the skill ratio will converge to λ1. But if instead it follows the λs function, itwill converge (to λ2) only if the slope of this function in the neighborhood ofλ2 is less than one in absolute value. If the slope exceeds one then the steadystate λ2 of the λs function is locally unstable. Whether the slope of the λs

function exceeds or falls below one depends on the parameters of the model,e.g., on the strength of the altruism motive. If this motive is sufficiently weak(i.e., the altruism parameter δ sufficiently small), then the slope will exceed onefor a large neighborhood of λ2.

However, as we have noted above, the global dynamic will not follow eitherthe λn or λs function throughout. It will switch between these two functionsand the drift function, depending on the relative values of these functions. Soin order to characterize the global dynamic, we need to distinguish betweendifferent cases, which are represented in Figures 6 and 7 respectively.

In Figure 6 the unique steady state λ∗ (defined by the condition λ∗1−λ∗ = γ

ι )lies in the interior of (λ1, λ2). Here the competitive equilibrium converges to thesteady state from arbitrary initial conditions. In the neighborhood of the steadystate the drift function lies in between the λn and λs functions, so represents the

20

Page 21: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

local dynamic. The equilibrium sequence converges because the drift functionhas a positive slope less than one (note that D is linear with a slope of 1−γ−ι).

In Figure 7 we represent the case where the proportion of geniuses is muchlarger, and γ

ι > λ2

1−λ2 . Now the unique steady state skill ratio is at λ2, becausethe rightward drift is positive even at λ2, and a positive fraction of skilledfamilies with normal children must disinvest in order to counterbalance therightward drift.16 The competitive equilibrium dynamic in the neighborhood ofthe steady state must follow the λs function (since the drift function lies above itin such a neighborhood). Recall from the above discussion that the λs functionmay well have a slope exceeding one in absolute value, in which case the steadystate is unstable. Any slight perturbation of the steady state will lead to adynamic sequence which will perpetually oscillate around the steady state. Itcan be checked that the dynamic properties of the genius-idiot example extendlocally to any finite number of cost types. So the problem is quite a general one.The failure to converge is reminiscent of failures of various learning algorithms toconverge to mixed strategy Nash equilibria or cycling of competitive equilibriumdynamics for sufficiently strong income and intertemporal substitution effectsdespite perfect foresight (see, e. g., [17]).

We now describe some modifications of the dynamic that would restore con-vergence. It is easy to verify that the competitive equilibrium dynamic has thegeneral property that if the current skill ratio is less (resp. greater) than a uniquesteady state, then the skill ratio at the next date will be higher (resp. lower)than the one prevailing today. In other words, the skill ratio moves in the direc-tion of the steady state. The same is true regarding non-repelling steady statesin general. The failure to converge stems from a tendency to overshoot just asin similar failures of, e.g., discrete time replicator or other dynamics to convergeto a unique (mixed) evolutionary stable state (for example, see [28, sect. 4.1] or[18, sect. 6])). Such a tendency would be mitigated in the presence of inertia.This is essentially what is involved in going to a continuous time dynamic (asin [7]). For instance, suppose that only a positive fraction of families considerswitching occupations in any generation, the size of which is a nondecreasingfunction of the payoff benefit from the switch (with nobody switching if thecurrent occupation of the parent is strictly optimal for the child). One interpre-tation of this is that there is a special cost advantage in learning one’s parent’soccupation (e.g., the parent may directly impart education to the child), whichdiffers randomly across families (e.g., owing to differences in effectiveness ofparental educations). Alternatively, inertia could arise from a form of boundedrationality. If the fraction of switchers is scaled down enough (for any given

16There cannot be a steady state to the right of λ2 because there all skilled families with

normal children will want to disinvest. Then the skill ratio at the following date will be γ,

which is less than λ2 by assumption.

21

Page 22: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

payoff benefit) as a result of inertia, one may speculate that overshooting canbe moderated so as to ensure convergence.

In our model, however, this is less straightforward than it might seem. Con-sider for instance the simplest formulation of inertia, where each parent recon-siders its family’s earlier investment decision with a small payoff-independentexogenous probability p < 1.17 The problem of non-convergence then persists ifthe type distribution has mass points. Consider again the divergence situationin the genius-idiot example (Figure 7). Scaling down the excess of the mass ofgeniuses newly investing over the mass of idiots disinvesting by p turns the driftfunction D towards the 45◦-line. This leaves a shrunken but still nonemptyneighborhood of the unique steady state λ2 in which dynamics are determinedby the condition that all normal skilled families are indifferent, i.e., by the func-tion λs. But this function is not affected by inertia. Given that dynamics donot converge from any λ0 in a neighborhood of λ2 under the original process(p = 1), they do not converge for small p either.

We now show that a slightly more complex form of inertia, where switch-ing probabilities depend on possible payoffs, does nevertheless restore globalconvergence.

Recall go(λt, λet+1; x) denotes the net gain from investing for a parent in

occupation o in generation t, if the child’s ability is represented by cost x ofentering the skilled profession (in the absence of any inertia). In the presence ofinertia, assume that the fraction of families in this category that will actuallyswitch occupations is given by p(∆U) ∈ [0, 1] where18

∆U ≡{

gn(λt, λet+1;x) if o = n,

−gs(λt, λet+1;x) if o = s

and p(.) satisfies the following properties: p(∆U) = 0 for ∆U < 0, and thereexists ε ≥ 0 such that p(∆U) ∈ (0, p̄) for ∆U ∈ [0, ε), and p(∆U) = p̄ ∈ (0, 1]for all ∆U ≥ ε. If ε > 0, then p is nondecreasing and differentiable withdp/d∆U ≤ lp̄/ε for some l ≥ 1 fixed independently of p̄. In this case theswitching probability is continuous in the utility gain from switching, with abounded rate of change.

Denote the resulting dynamic process in which agents have perfect foresightby Φp̄,ε. The process continues to be well-defined because the set of possibleλt+1 is for any given λt a decreasing correspondence of λe

t+1 satisfying theassumptions of Kakutani’s theorem. Perfect-foresight competitive equilibriumdynamics represent the special case where Φ ≡ Φ1,0.

17[14], for example, motivates continuous replicator dynamics in this way.

18Any fraction of indifferent skilled (resp. unskilled) families not exceeding p(0) may switch

professions.

22

Page 23: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Proposition 7 Given any ε′ > 0, there generically exist ε > 0 and p̄ ∈ (0, 1]such that:

1. For any steady state λ′ of Φp̄,ε there exists a steady state λ of Φ with|λ′ − λ| < ε′ and vice versa.

2. Φp̄,ε converges to one of its steady states from any initial state λ0.

The proof is provided in the appendix. It also shows convergence of a relateddynamic process in which families are myopic out of steady state and have staticexpectations. The incorporation of inertia and myopia results in a plausiblemodel with boundedly rational agents which has (approximately) the same longrun predictions as the dynamic process investigated in this paper.

6 Relation to Existing Literature

Models analyzing steady state mobility include [2], [7], [22] and [26]. [7] considersa model with four occupations and three income classes, with risky incomepatterns within each occupation. Mobility is induced by sufficient variabilityin ex post incomes, somewhat analogous to the variability in education costs inour model. Positive income shocks allow the poor to escape poverty and switchoccupations. These shocks eliminate steady states with zero mobility. [7] worksout the steady state set and dynamics with a discrete two-point distributionfor income risk and two specific classes of parameter values: these are shownto yield two distinct locally stable steady states. Our paper considers a simplermodel with two occupations, but yields more general results concerning steadystate uniqueness and convergence. [2] studies a model with a unique mobilesteady state, while [26] share many of the features described above for [7] andso bears the same relation to this paper.19

[22] considers a model very similar to ours, but does not address the ques-tion of steady state multiplicity, nor the convergence properties of competitiveequilibria. Instead the authors focus on the qualitative features of a ‘develop-ment process’, characterized by the movement from a low non-steady state skillratio to a steady state skill ratio. They also analyze the effects and design ofredistributive taxes along such a development process.

The relation to [13],[19],[23-25],[27] has already been discussed: steady statesin those models are characterized by zero mobility, and a continuum of unequalsteady states in the presence of occupational indivisibility. This paper can beinterpreted as studying the effect of augmenting such a model with heterogene-ity in agents’ education costs. As pointed out in the introduction, the effect of

19See [8, section 6] for a recent survey of this literature.

23

Page 24: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

introducing heterogeneous abilities is akin to the removal of investment indivis-ibility in [23]: both can transform the inequality constraints which characterizesteady states in the baseline model into equalities.

[15] does not allow any heterogeneity or income risk; consequently the steadystates in that paper do not involve any mobility. The first model in [15] is char-acterized by complete absence of pecuniary externalities, so each family followsan independent dynamic. The income dynamic has two steady states, hence atthe macro level there is a continuum of steady states varying with respect tothe proportion of families at different steady state income levels. In that con-text it is evident that adding heterogeneity of income or education costs wouldtypically eliminate this indeterminacy, and give rise to a unique steady state atthe macro level. So the conclusions of our paper would (trivially) apply to thatcontext as well. The subsequent model in [15] which incorporates pecuniaryexternalities describes two classes of steady states (associated respectively witha developed and underdeveloped economy), but does not address the questionof local indeterminacy.

[16] consider a simplified version of [7], with three occupations, homogenousagents and absence of income risk. In this model also there is a continuum ofsteady states, and absence of occupational mobility in steady state. We presumethat our results concerning the implications of introducing heterogeneity orincome risk on steady state multiplicity will also apply to their model.

Finally, earlier literature (e.g., [9],[20]) was based on a version of the neoclas-sical growth model with no indivisibilities or nonconvexities in the investmenttechnology. Their models incorporate agent heterogeneity in order to explainthe persistence of income inequality. They are characterized by a unique steadystate with mobility.

7 Conclusion

This paper has argued that when occupational mobility is sought to be explainedby heterogeneity of talent (or investment cost, or ex post income uncertainty),long run macroeconomic outcomes become less history dependent. This is truedespite the presence of borrowing constraints and nonconvexities in investmentopportunities. The local indeterminacy of steady states in models with homo-geneous agents is generally lost, even with arbitrarily ‘small’ extents of het-erogeneity. For certain classes of heterogeneity we showed that steady state isglobally unique, for some others we showed they were non-unique. Numericalcomputations with various examples of well-behaved continuous ability distri-butions and parameter constellations permitting existence of a low level povertytrap for the unskilled, showed a unique locally stable steady state with mobility.We also discussed problems with possible nonconvergence of competitive equi-

24

Page 25: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

librium dynamics in the presence of heterogeneity, and how convergence couldbe restored in the presence of inertia or investment ‘adjustment costs’.

Many questions remain to be explored. For one, there is the question of howrobust the results are with respect to the bequest motive, or presence of morethan two occupations. Robustness with respect to state dependence of abilitywithin families (e.g., if there is intergenerational transmission of genes or socialskills) or alternative formulations of agent heterogeneity is also an interestingquestion.

Second, what is the role of interventionist policies in a world with occu-pational mobility? The results suggest that temporary policies (of educationsubsidies for instance) are considerably less effective in affecting long run hu-man capital, per capita income, or inequality. But there may still be a role forpermanent policies. Is it possible that steady states involve too little investmentin human capital from an efficiency standpoint? Also as discussed in the text,permanent education subsidies may raise steady state levels of human capitaland per capita income while reducing cross-sectional inequality, but their effectson mobility are considerably less clear-cut. Issues concerning effects and optimaldesign of public policies in contexts involving occupational mobility constitutean important research agenda for the future.

References

[1] Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson and J. Robinson (2001). “The Colo-nial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.”American Economic Review 91(5), 1369–1401.

[2] Aghion, P. and P. Bolton (1997). “A Theory of Trickle-Down Growthand Development,” Review of Economic Studies 64(219), 151–172.

[3] Aghion, P., P. Howitt and D. Mayer-Foulkes (2003). “The Effect ofFinancial Development on Convergence: Theory and Evidence,” mimeo,Department of Economics, Harvard University, December 2003.

[4] Bandyopadhyay, D. (1993), Distribution of Human Capital, Income In-equality and Rate of Growth, PhD thesis, University of Minnesota.

[5] ——————– (1997). “Distribution of Human Capital and EconomicGrowth,” Working Paper no. 173, Department of Economics, AucklandBusiness School.

[6] Banerjee, A., and L. Iyer (2002). “History, Institutions and EconomicPerformance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,”mimeo, Department of Economics, MIT, June 2002.

25

Page 26: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

[7] Banerjee, A., and A. Newman (1993). “Occupational Choice and theProcess of Development.” Journal of Political Economy 101(2), 274–298.

[8] Banerjee, A., and E. Duflo (2004). “Growth Theory Through the Lensof Development Economics,” mimeo, Department of Economics, MIT,March 2004.

[9] Becker, G., and N. Tomes (1979). “An Equilibrium Theory of the Dis-tribution of Income and Intergenerational Mobility.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy 87(6), 1153–1189.

[10] Bowles, S., and H. Gintis (2002). “The Inheritance of Inequality,”Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(3), 3–30.

[11] Checchi D., A. Ichino and A. Rustichini (1999). “More Equal butLess Mobile? Education Financing and Intergenerational Mobility in Italyand in the United States.” Journal of Public Economics 74(3), 351–393.

[12] Engerman, S., and K. Sokoloff (1997). “Factor Endowments, Institu-tions and Differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies,” inS. H. Haber (Ed.), How Latin America Fell Behind, Stanford UniversityPress, Stanford, CA.

[13] Freeman, S. (1996). “Equilibrium Income Inequality among IdenticalAgents.” Journal of Political Economy 104(5), 1047–1064.

[14] Gale, J., K. Binmore, and L. Samuelson (1995). “Learning to BeImperfect: The Ultimatum Game.” Games and Economic Behavior 8(1),56–90.

[15] Galor, O., and J. Zeira (1993). “Income Distribution and Macroeco-nomics.” Review of Economic Studies 60(1), 35–52.

[16] Ghatak, M., and N. Jiang (2002). “A Simple Model of Inequality andOccupational Choice with Credit Constraints.” Journal of DevelopmentEconomics 69(1), 205-226.

[17] Grandmont, J.-M. (1985). “On Endogenous Competitive Business Cy-cles.” Econometrica 53(5), 995–1045.

[18] Kandori, M., G. J. Mailath and R. Rob (1993), “Learning, Mutation,and Long Run Equilibria in Games”, Econometrica 61(1), 29–56.

[19] Ljungqvist, L. (1993). “Economic Underdevelopment: The Case ofMissing Market for Human Capital,” Journal of Development Economics40(2), 219–239.

26

Page 27: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

[20] Loury, G. (1981). “Intergenerational Transfers and the Distribution ofEarnings.” Econometrica 49(4), 843–867.

[21] Mas-Colell, A. (1985), The Theory of General Economic Equilibrium:A Differentiable Approach, Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge.

[22] Maoz, Y., and O. Moav (1999). “Intergenerational Mobility and theProcess of Development,” Economic Journal 109 (October), 677–697.

[23] Mookherjee, D., and D. Ray (2002).“Is Equality Stable?” AmericanEconomic Review – Papers and Proceedings 92(2), 253–259.

[24] ——————– (2003). “Persistent Inequality,” Review of EconomicStudies 70(2), 369–393.

[25] ——————– (2004). “Occupational Diversity and Endogenous In-equality,” http://people.bu.edu/dilipm/wkpap/index.html.

[26] Piketty, T. (1997), “The Dynamics of the Wealth Distribution andthe Interest Rate with Credit Rationing,” Review of Economic Studies64(219), 173–189.

[27] Ray, D. (1990). Income Distribution and Macroeconomic Behavior.Mimeo, Boston University.

[28] Weibull, J.W. (1995). Evolutionary Game Theory, MIT Press, Cam-bridge, MA.

27

Page 28: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1: The proof is illustrated in Figure 1. Define the non-empty,compact and convex-valued correspondence φλt

: [0, 1] ⇒ [0, 1] by

φλt(λe

t+1) ={

λ | λ = σ(λt, λet+1)+α in(λt, λ

et+1)+β is(λt, λ

et+1) for α, β ∈ [0, 1]

}.

(9)For given λt, φλt maps expected expected skill ratio λe

t+1 to the set of all actualskill ratios λt+1 that could result from its anticipation. The latter need not bea singleton if the skill distribution has atoms.

Since threshold levels xn(λt, λet+1) and xs(λt, λ

et+1) are continuous, σ(λt, λ

et+1)

is continuous in λet+1 except at points where a positive mass of agents switches

from a strict preference for or against investment to indifference. Moreover,except at these points, φλt(λ

et+1) = {σ(λt, λ

et+1)} and thus φλt is continuous,

too. If at λet+1 a mass of agents becomes indifferent between investing or not,

all or none of them may invest. So for arbitrary λet+1 and arbitrary sequences

{λen}n≥0 and {λn}n≥0 with λen → λet+1, λn ∈ φλt(λ

en), and λn → λ′ it istrue that λ′ ∈ φλt(λ

et+1). In other words, φλt is upper semi-continuous and, by

Kakutani’s theorem, must have a fixed point λt+1 ∈ φλt(λt+1).Uniqueness follows from the fact that φλt is a decreasing correspondence

over the range [0, λ̄], i.e., that for all λ ∈ φλt(λet+1) and λ′ ∈ φλt(λ

et+1

′): λet+1 ≤

λet+1

′ ⇐⇒ λ ≥ λ′. This follows from the fact that a higher expected skill ratiodecreases the benefits of child education, while the costs are determined by thecurrently given skill ratio at t.

Proof of Proposition 1: Define the correspondence λ′(λ) from [0, 1] to itself asfollows:

λ′(λ) ≡{

λ′ = λ + µ1 − µ2 | µ1 ∈ u(λ), µ2 ∈ d(λ)}

.

A SS is a fixed point of this correspondence. Its existence follows from applyingthe Kakutani theorem, since the correspondence is non-empty, convex-valuedand u.s.c. (because u and d have these properties by construction).

Proof of Proposition 2: We first prove (c). Since (A1) holds here, any SS mustinvolve λ < λ̄, implying ws(λ) > wn(λ). So xn(λ, λ) < xs(λ, λ). If λ = 0 thensuch a SS involves no mobility. So suppose λ > 0. If x∗ /∈ [xn(λ, λ), xs(λ, λ)]then either every household or no household in the economy will invest, contra-dicting the property that λ ∈ (0, λ̄). Hence

xn(λ, λ) ≤ x∗ ≤ xs(λ, λ). (10)

Now if there is upward mobility in the SS, then x∗ = xn(λ, λ). It follows that allskilled households will invest, in which case there will be no downward mobility.Hence (c) is established.

28

Page 29: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

We can therefore restate the steady state condition as

Cn(λ, x∗) ≥ B(λ) ≥ Cs(λ, x∗) (11)

if λ > 0, andCn(λ, x∗) ≥ B(λ) (12)

if λ = 0. Now (a) follows from the fact that B is strictly decreasing whileCs(λ, x∗) is strictly increasing in λ over [λ, λ̄], and both are constant on [0, λ). If(6) holds then no SS with λ > 0 can exist, as no household will have an incentiveto invest, and λ = 0 is the unique SS. If (6) does not hold, then there existsλ̃ ∈ (0, λ̄) such that B(λ̃) = Cs(λ̃, x∗). This is a SS, since Cn(λ̃, x∗) > Cs(λ̃, x∗).Moreover every skill ratio in some left neighborhood of λ̃ is also a SS, since B

is decreasing, Cs(λ, x∗) is nondecreasing and Cn(λ, x∗) is continuous in λ. Sothere is a continuum of SS’s. If (7) holds, then λ̃ > λ and there exists aninterval (λ̃ − ε, λ̃) with λ̃ − ε > λ such that every skill ratio in this interval isa steady state, and within this interval per capita income is increasing and theskill premium decreasing as we move across SS’s with higher λ. This establishes(b).

Finally we turn to dynamics. If λ0 is a SS then the result follows from theuniqueness of equilibrium (Lemma 1).

So consider the case where λ0 > λ̃. Then

B(λ0) < B(λ̃) = Cs(λ̃, x∗) < Cs(λ0, x∗), (13)

so neither skilled nor unskilled households want to invest if λ1 = λ0.If B(λ) < Cs(λ0, x

∗), then the equilibrium must entail λ1 = 0, since thereis no skill ratio at t = 1 that would induce anyone to invest. In this case everyskill ratio from 0 to λ̃ is a SS, because B(λ) ≤ B(0) = B(λ) < Cs(λ0, x

∗) ≤Cs(λ̄, x∗) = Cn(λ̄, x∗) ≤ Cn(λ, x∗) for every λ ≤ λ̄, so the unskilled never wantto invest at any steady skill ratio below λ̄. On the other hand B(λ) ≥ Cs(λ, x∗)for all λ from 0 to λ̃, so the skilled invest at any such steady skill ratio. Henceλ1 = 0 is a SS, and then by the reasoning above, λt = λ1 = 0 for all t > 1.

On the other hand suppose that B(λ) ≥ Cs(λ0, x∗). Then there exists

λ ∈ [λ, λ̃] such that B(λ) = Cs(λ0, x∗). This is an equilibrium skill ratio (where

only λ measure of (skilled) households invest and the rest being indifferent donot invest, while no unskilled household wants to invest), and by uniquenessof equilibrium λ1 must equal this λ. Moreover λ1 is a SS because B(λ1) =Cs(λ0, x

∗) > Cs(λ1, x∗) while Cn(λ1, x

∗) > Cn(λ0, x∗) > Cs(λ0, x

∗) = B(λ1).So λt = λ1 for all t ≥ 1.

Finally consider the case where λ0 is less than λ̃ and is not a SS. Then allhouseholds in the economy want to invest at the steady skill ratio λ0. In this caseλ1 must be characterized by indifference for unskilled households’ investment

29

Page 30: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

decision: B(λ1) = Cn(λ0, x∗), and a fraction of these unskilled households

switch to the skilled occupation, while all skilled households invest. This requiresλ1 > λ0. We claim that λ1 is also less than λ̃ and therefore not a SS. This followsfrom B(λ1) = Cn(λ0, x

∗) > Cn(λ1, x∗) so the unskilled again want to invest at

a stationary skill ratio λ1, contrary to the requirement of a SS. Now the sameargument as at t = 0 applies again, hence λ2 > λ1, etc. Therefore skill ratiosrise monotonically. Since they are bounded above by λ̄ they must converge. Thelimiting ratio must involve indifference among the unskilled, and must thereforebe a SS.

Proof of Lemma 2: Define λ′(x̄) by the condition that B(λ′) = Cs(λ′, x̄) ifB(λ) > Cs(λ, x̄), and equal to λ otherwise. Then by construction λ′(x̄) ∈ [λ, λ̄).

We claim that λ ∈ (λ′(x̄), λ̄) and µ ∈ d(λ) implies µ > 0. This is becauseB(λ′(x̄)) ≤ Cs(λ′(x̄), x̄); at any λ > λ′(x̄) it is true that B(λ) < Cs(λ, x̄) so atany such steady skill ratio λ there must be downward mobility.

Next, define x̂(x̄) > 0 by the condition Cn(λ, x̂) = B(λ′(x̄)). This is well-defined because Cn(λ, x) is increasing from 0 to ∞ as x goes from 0 to ∞, andB(λ′(x̄)) > 0. Then if x < x̂(x̄) we have for any λ ≤ λ′(x̄):

Cn(λ, x) ≡ U(wn(λ))−U(wn(λ)−x) ≤ Cn(λ, x) < Cn(λ, x̂(x̄)) = B(λ′(x̄)) ≤ B(λ),

implying there must be upward mobility. Combining with the result in theprevious paragraph, Lemma 2 is established.

Proof of Proposition 3: Consider first the case where F has no mass points,i.e., F ≡ F 0 and has a continuous density f . In this case u(λ) and d(λ) arefunctions, which depend on the parameter δ; accordingly we denote these byu(λ, δ), d(λ, δ) respectively. For any given δ, let xn(λ, δ) and xs(λ, δ) denote thecosts at which unskilled and skilled households are indifferent between investingand not investing at the constant skill ratio λ. Define the net upward flow:

µ(λ, δ) ≡ u(λ, δ)− d(λ, δ)

= (1− λ)F (xn(λ, δ))− λ (1− F (xs(λ, δ)))

= F (xn(λ, δ))− λF (xn(λ, δ))− λ + λF (xs(λ, δ))

for λ ∈ [0, 1] and δ ∈ [0,∞). xn and xs are C1 and strictly increasing in δ forany λ ∈ (0, λ̄). Since F is C1, so is µ.

Lemma 4 Suppose F has no mass points, and let λ ∈ (0, λ̄) and δ > 0 be suchthat u(λ, δ) = d(λ, δ) > 0. Then

∂µ(λ, δ)∂λ

= 0 =⇒ ∂µ(λ, δ)∂δ

> 0.

30

Page 31: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Proof of Lemma 4: Consider

∂µ(λ, δ)∂λ

= f(xn(λ, δ))∂xn(λ, δ)

∂λ− F (xn(λ, δ))− λf(xn(λ, δ))

∂xn(λ, δ)∂λ

− 1 + F (xs(λ, δ)) + λf(xs(λ, δ))∂xs(λ, δ)

∂λ= 0. (14)

We claim that f(xn(λ, δ)) and f(xs(λ, δ)) cannot simultaneously equal zero.Otherwise (14) reduces to

∂µ(λ, δ)∂λ

= −F (xn(λ, δ))− 1 + F (xs(λ, δ)) = 0.

This would require F (xn(λ, δ)) = 0 and F (xs(λ, δ)) = 1, in contradiction tou(λ, δ), d(λ, δ) > 0. Therefore, f(xn(λ, δ)) > 0 or f(xs(λ, δ)) > 0 whenever∂µ(λ,δ)

∂λ = 0.We have

∂µ(λ, δ)∂δ

= f(xn(λ, δ))∂xn(λ, δ)

∂δ− λf(xn(λ, δ))

∂xn(λ, δ)∂δ

+ λf(xs(λ, δ))∂xs(λ, δ)

∂δ

= (1− λ)f(xn(λ, δ))∂xn(λ, δ)

∂δ+ λf(xs(λ, δ))

∂xs(λ, δ)∂δ

.

Now for λ ∈ (0, λ̄) and ∂µ(λ,δ)∂λ = 0, the monotonicity of threshold costs in δ

(namely, ∂xn(λ,δ)∂δ > 0 and ∂xs(λ,δ)

∂δ > 0) implies ∂µ(λ,δ)∂δ > 0.

¤Return now to the proof of Proposition 3 in the case where F has no mass

points. Define the function λ(δ) : R+ → [0, λ̄] as the constant skill ratio atwhich the lowest ability children of skilled parents with discount factor δ areindifferent between investing and not investing. Specifically, if x̄ < xs(λ, δ) itis the unique solution to xs(λ, δ) = x̄. If x̄ = xs(λ, δ) set λ(δ) = λ, and ifx̄ > xs(λ, δ) set λ(δ) = 0. Since F has no mass points, a steady state skill ratioλ at δ satisfying µ(λ, δ) = 0 has positive mobility if and only if it has positivedownward mobility, i.e., it satisfies the additional condition λ ∈ (

λ(δ), λ̄).

Therefore if we define the open manifold

Ξ = {(λ, δ) ∈ [0, λ̄]× R+ |λ ∈(λ(δ), λ̄

)} (15)

λ is a mobile steady state skill ratio at δ if and only if µ(λ, δ) = 0 and (λ, δ) ∈ Ξ.Hence the set of SSM is exactly

EM = {(λ, δ) ∈ Ξ |µ(λ, δ) = 0} (16)

i.e., if we consider the C1 map µ : Ξ → R, we have EM ≡ µ−1(0). By Lemma 4,(

∂µ(λ,δ)∂λ

∂µ(λ,δ)∂δ

)

31

Page 32: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

has rank 1 at every (λ, δ) ∈ EM . Therefore 0 is a regular value of the map µ.The Implicit Function Theorem ([21], H.2.2) then implies that µ−1(0) = EM isa C1 manifold of dimension 1.

Define the projection map π : EM → R+ by π(λ, δ) = δ. We now claim thatif λ is a critical SSM at δ, i.e., (λ, δ) ∈ EM satisfying ∂µ

∂λ = 0, then δ is a criticalvalue of π. By Lemma 4, ∂µ

∂δ > 0 at any such (λ, δ)-pair. Hence the ImplicitFunction Theorem yields ∂π

∂λ = −[∂µ∂δ ]−1 ∂µ

∂λ = 0, implying that δ is a criticalvalue of π. Now Sard’s Theorem ([21], I.1.1) implies that the set of criticalvalues of the smooth function π has Lebesgue measure zero. Hence the set ofdiscount factors at which there exists a mobile steady state skill ratio λ whichis critical, is a set of Lebesgue measure 0.

Now suppose that F has a finite number of mass points. Then the functionµ is well-defined on the open set O resulting from removing all (λ, δ)-pairs from(0, λ̄)× (0,∞) for which xn(λ, δ) or xs(λ, δ) corresponds to a mass point of F .On this set, µ is C1 and by the above arguments all its zeros are locally uniquegenerically. It remains to consider possible zeros of µ amongst the removed(λ, δ)-pairs. Now we claim that for a generic set of values of δ, only a finitenumber of λ’s were removed. This follows since for any given mass-point of x,say x∗, a (λ, δ) pair was removed if δB(λ) − U(wo(λ)) + U(wo(λ) − x∗) = 0for either o = n or o = s. Since B(λ) > 0 for every λ ∈ (0, λ̄), and thereare a finite number of mass points, application of Sard’s Theorem once againimplies that for a generic set of values of δ, a finite number of λ’s were removed.Hence generically, only finitely many more zeros can exist for the steady statecondition µ(λ, δ) = 0, implying that generic finiteness of the set of mobile steadystates continues to hold.

Proof of Lemma 3: If ρ > 1, the net benefit to an unskilled investor with cost x

is

gn ≡ (1−ρ)−1[δα1−ρη(1−α)(1−ρ)−(1+δ)(1−α)1−ρη−α(1−ρ)+{(1−α)η−α−x}1−ρ](17)

where η ≡ 1λ − 1. Hence in this case gn is nondecreasing in η if and only if

m(η) ≡ {(1− α)η−α − x}−ρ − δα−ρη1−ρ(1−α) − (1 + δ)(1− α)−ρηαρ ≥ 0. (18)

It can easily be verified that the same is true when the utility function is loga-rithmic (putting ρ = 1).

Claim: If ρ ≥ 1 and m(η) ≥ 0, then m′(η) > 0.

To prove the claim, note that the condition m′(η) > 0 is equivalent to

αρ(1−α)η−1−α{(1−α)η−α−x}−1−ρ > αρ(1+δ)(1−α)−ρηαρ−1+δ(1−ρ+αρ)α−ρηαρ−ρ

(19)

32

Page 33: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Now ρ ≥ 1 implies that αρ ≥ αρ + 1 − ρ, so m(η) ≥ 0 implies that the R.H.S.of (19) cannot exceed αρη−1{(1 − α)η−α − x}−ρ, which in turn cannot exceedthe L.H.S. of (19). This establishes the claim.

The claim implies that if m(η∗) ≥ 0 then m(η) > 0 for all η > η∗. Using(18) this implies that if (gn)′ ≥ 0 at λ∗, then (gn)′ > 0 at all λ < λ∗. If ρ ≥ 1then we know that gn is negative for λ in a right neighborhood of λ(x) definedby wn(λ(x)) = x, and also in a left neighborhood of λ̄. Hence if there existssome λ ∈ (λ(x), λ̄) where gn > 0, then gn must have a unique maximum λ∗ overthis range, and will be rising from λ(x) to λ∗ and decreasing thereafter. Hencegn is inverse U-shaped if it is positive somewhere, which implies DCP.

Proof of Proposition 5: Part (ii) of the result follows from the fact that atλ = 0 all households are unskilled, earn a wage of w which is smaller than thelowest education cost (owing to (a)), so the requirement of nonnegativity ofconsumption prevents any of them from investing.

So we turn to (i). Assumption (b) ensures that the downward flow will bepositive at all steady λ > 0, so any SS with a positive skill ratio must involvemobility. Suppose λ∗ > 0 is a SS. Then Proposition 3 says that generically λ∗

is locally unique; moreover u(λ) and d(λ) are C1 functions in a neighborhoodof λ∗ with distinct slopes. There exist right and left neighborhoods Nr and Nl

of λ∗ such that either: (A) d(λ) > u(λ) for all λ ∈ Nr and d(λ) < u(λ) for allλ ∈ Nl, or (B) d(λ) < u(λ) for all λ ∈ Nr and d(λ) > u(λ) for all λ ∈ Nl.

Suppose (A) is true. Assumption (a) implies that u = 0 in a neighborhoodNu of λ = 0 where the unskilled wage falls below x. So there is a λ1 > 0 inthis neighborhood where u = 0 < d. On the other hand u > d in Nl. Since u

and d are u.s.c. and convex-valued, there must exist an intermediate skill ratiobetween neighborhoods Nl and Nu which is a SS with mobility.

And if (B) is true, then noting that u(λ̄) = 0 < d(λ̄), there must exist a skillratio between Nr and λ̄ where upward and downward flows match. In eithercase, there must be a SS distinct from λ∗.

Proof of Proposition 7: First, note that families’ inertia has no effect whatsoeveron the location of steady states without mobility. So to prove 1. it suffices toinvestigate the distance between mobile steady states of Φ and Φp̄,ε, whichare generically locally unique.20 Second, note that steady state upward anddownward flows under Φp̄,ε – denoted by up̄,ε(λ) and dp̄,ε(λ), respectively –merely scale down u(λ) and d(λ) by factor p̄ if ε = 0. So

µp̄,0(λ) ≡ up̄,0(λ)− dp̄,0(λ) = p̄[u(λ)− d(λ)

]

20Local uniqueness implies that it is possible to choose ε small enough to ensure that Φ and

Φp̄,ε have the same number of mobile steady states.

33

Page 34: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

and steady states of processes Φ and Φp̄,0 exactly coincide for any p̄ ∈ (0, 1].We will argue that steady states of Φp̄,0 and Φp̄,ε are close to each other in thesense of 1. for small ε > 0.

A smooth transition from zero probability of switching in response to ∆U =0 up to probability p̄ in response to ∆U ≥ ε > 0 implies that flow correspon-dences up̄,ε(λ) and dp̄,ε(λ) are singleton-valued even if the cost distribution F

has atoms. Let us confirm that introducing such a smooth transition from 0 top̄ on interval [0, ε] shifts steady states continuously: Define xo

ε(λ, λ′) as the costtype with occupation o that has net switching benefits of ε, i. e.

go(λ, λ′; xoε(λ, λ′)) =

{ε if o = n,

−ε if o = s.

We abbreviate the corresponding steady state or static-expectations thresholdsand net gains by xo

ε(λ) ≡ xoε(λ, λ) and go(λ; x) ≡ go(λ, λ; x); as before let

xo(λ) ≡ xo0(λ) denote the cost that for fixed λ makes a parent with occupation

o indifferent. Investment decisions of unskilled families (skilled families) withcost x /∈ [xn

ε (λ), xn(λ)] (x /∈ [xs(λ), xsε(λ)], resp.) are the same under Φp̄,ε and

Φp̄,0. Net upward flows µp̄,0(λ) and µp̄,ε(λ) may differ – and hence also theirzeroes may differ – because for any λ there may exist unskilled families withx ∈ [xn

ε (λ), xn(λ)] for whom µp̄,0(λ) overstates the actual switching probabilityby p̄− p(gn(λ; x)), and similarly skilled families whose switching probability isoverstated.

If, for given λ, F has atoms neither at xn(λ) nor at xs(λ), both µp̄,ε(λ) andµp̄,0(λ) are singleton-valued. Then the distance between µp̄,0(λ) and µp̄,ε(λ) is

D(λ; ε) ≡ −(1− λ)

xn(λ)∫

xnε (λ)

[p̄− p(gn(λ; x)]dF (x) + λ

xsε(λ)∫

xs(λ)

[p̄− p(−gs(λ;x)]dF (x).

D(λ; ε) converges to zero as ε → 0 for any λ because xoε(λ) → xo(λ) for o = n, s.

The distance between steady states of Φp̄,0 and Φp̄,ε (=zeroes of µp̄,0(λ) andµp̄,ε(λ)) must hence converge to zero, too. In particular, it can be boundedabove by ε′ through an appropriate choice of ε.

When F has an atom at xn(λ) or xs(λ), the location of steady states isaffected by smoothing only if µp̄,0(λ) 3 {0}. While it need not be true thatthe (vertical) distance between µp̄,0(λ) and µp̄,ε(λ) becomes arbitrarily smallfor ε → 0, there must still exist δ > 0 such that {0} ∈ µp̄,ε(λ′) for someλ′ ∈ (λ − δ, λ + δ) and δ → 0 as ε → 0: Suppose first that an atom of skilledfamilies with cost xs(λ) causes µp̄,0 to turn from positive to negative at λ. Thennone of the skilled xs(λ)-types disinvests at λ under Φp̄,ε, but the same share p̄

as under Φp̄,0 does at λ′′ defined by gs(λ′′, λ′′; xs(λ)) = −ε. So µp̄,ε(λ) > 0, butµp̄,ε(λ′′) < 0 (for ε small enough so that u(·) has no upward jump between λ and

34

Page 35: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

λ′′). Choosing δ ≡ λ′′ − λ, the (singleton-valued) continuous correspondenceµp̄,ε(·) must assume zero at some λ′ ∈ (λ, λ + δ). Continuity of gs implies thatδ → 0 as ε → 0. Analogous reasoning applies if an atom of unskilled familiescauses a drop of µp̄,0(·) to below zero or a jump to above zero. This proves thefirst part of Proposition 7.

Now turn to the second part of the proposition. Denote the upward anddownward flows which would result for given λt and anticipated λe

t+1 by up̄,ε(λt, λet+1)

and dp̄,ε(λt, λet+1); treat them as real numbers (rather than sets containing a

single real number) in order to simplify notation in the following. Let λ+(λt)denote the (unique) solution to

λt + up̄,ε(λt, λ+)− dp̄,ε(λt, λ

+) = λ+.

Soνp̄,ε(λt) ≡ up̄,ε(λt, λ

+(λt))− dp̄,ε(λt, λ+(λt))

is the competitive equilibrium net upward flow characterizing Φp̄,ε. In contrast,µp̄,ε(λt) ≡ up̄,ε(λt, λt)−dp̄,ε(λt, λt) is the net flow that would result from agentshaving static expectations. It corresponds to the steady state flow investigatedabove and would produce a disequilibrium except if λt is indeed a SS. Upwardor downward adjustments under perfect foresight are bounded above by thecorresponding adjustments under static expectations:

Lemma 5 |νp̄,ε(λt)| ≤ |µp̄,ε(λt)|.Proof:Suppose νp̄,ε(λt) ≡ λ+(λt) − λt > 0, i. e. λt+1 > λt under perfect foresight.Then

νp̄,ε(λt) = up̄,ε(λt, λ+(λt))− dp̄,ε(λt, λ

+(λt))

≤ up̄,ε(λt, λt)− dp̄,ε(λt, λt)

= µp̄,ε(λt)

because unskilled families’ incentive to invest decreases in λt+1, and skilledfamilies’ incentive to disinvest increases in λt+1. Similarly, for λ+(λt) < λt, orνp̄,ε(λt) < 0, we have

νp̄,ε(λt, λ+(λt)) = up̄,ε(λt, λ

+(λt))− dp̄,ε(λt, λ+(λt))

≥ up̄,ε(λt, λt)− dp̄,ε(λt, λt)

= µp̄,ε(λt).

¤

Define the static expectations process Φ̃p̄,ε by

λt+1 ≡ λt + µp̄,ε(λt).

35

Page 36: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Note that Φp̄,ε and Φ̃p̄,ε have the same steady states, and adjustments of λt

are always in the same direction. Thus, if for suitable choice of p̄ and ε thepossible overshooting in adjustment towards a (non-repelling) steady state λ∗

is moderate enough for convergence of Φ̃p̄,ε, then Φp̄,ε must converge, too.Recall that f denotes the density of the absolutely continuous part of type

distribution F ; let η(xa) ≡ F (xa)−F 0(xa) denote the measure of F ’s atoms xa

with a ∈ A ⊂ N. Then

µp̄,ε(λ) = (1− λ)[ xn(λ)∫

x

p(gn(λ; x))f(x) dx +∑

a∈A,xa≤xn(λ)

η(xa) p(gn(λ;x))]

−λ[ x̄∫

xs(λ)

p(−gs(λ; x))f(x) dx +∑

a∈A,xa≥xs(λ)

η(xa) p(−gs(λ; x))]

Differentiating yields

dµp̄,ε(λ)dλ

= −[ xn(λ)∫

x

p(gn(λ; x))f(x) dx +∑

a∈A,xa≤xn(λ)

η(xa) p(gn(λ;x))]

+(1− λ)[p(gn(λ; xn(λ)))f(xn(λ))

dxn(λ)dλ

+

+

xn(λ)∫

x

dp(·)d∆U

∂gn(λ; x)∂λ

f(x) dx +∑

a∈A,xa≤xn(λ)

η(xa)dp(·)d∆U

∂gn(λ; x)∂λ

]

−[ x̄∫

xs(λ)

p(−gs(λ;x))f(x) dx +∑

a∈A,xa≥xs(λ)

η(xa) p(−gs(λ; x))]

−λ[− p(−gs(λ; xs(λ)))f(xs(λ))

dxs(λ)dλ

−x̄∫

xs(λ)

dp(·)d∆U

∂gs(λ; x)∂λ

f(x) dx−∑

a∈A,xa≥xs(λ)

η(xa)dp(·)d∆U

∂gs(λ;x)∂λ

].

We can concentrate on adjustment towards a steady state λ∗, so that dµp̄,ε(λ)/dλ <

0 holds near λ∗. A sufficient condition for local stability and convergence to λ∗

from any λt ∈ (λ∗ − δ, λ∗ + δ) for some δ > 0 is then that dµp̄,ε(λ)/dλ > −1.Using p(·) ≤ p̄, dp/d∆U ≥ 0, and dp/d∆U ≤ lp̄/ε, we obtain

36

Page 37: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

dµp̄,ε(λ)dλ

≥ −[p̄ + p̄

]

+(1− λ)[p̄ · k1 + lp̄/ε · k2

]

−[p̄ + p̄

]

−λ[p̄ · k3 + lp̄/ε · k4

]

with

k1 ≡ −∣∣∣ inf

λ∈[0,λ̄]f(xn(λ))

dxn(λ)dλ

∣∣∣

k2 ≡ −∣∣∣ inf

λ∈[0,λ̄]

xn(λ)∫

xnε (λ)

∂gn(λ; x)∂λ

f(x) dx∣∣∣−

∣∣∣ infλ∈[0,λ̄]

∂gn(λ; x)∂λ

∣∣∣

k3 ≡ − infλ∈[0,λ̄]

f(xs(λ))dxs(λ)

dλ≥ 0

k4 ≡ − infλ∈[0,λ̄]

x̄∫

xs(λ)

∂gs(λ;x)∂λ

f(x) dx− infλ∈[0,λ̄]

∂gs(λ;x)∂λ

> 0

or, in summary,

0 >dµp̄,ε(λ)

dλ≥ −p̄ ·K

withK ≡ 4− (1− λ)(k1 + k2l/ε) + λ(k3 + k4l/ε) > 0.

Hence, |dµp̄,ε(λ∗)/dλ| < 1 for p̄ > 0 appropriately close to zero. So for eachnon-repelling mobile steady state λ there exists a δλ > 0 such that Φ̃p̄,ε andΦp̄,ε converge to λ from any λ0 ∈ (λ− δλ, λ + δλ).

Denote the minimum of δλ over all (generically finite) steady states by δ∗.An upper bound to any one-step upward/downward adjustment of λt is given byp̄ because the maximal measure of unskilled/skilled families is one. So choosingp̄ < 2δ∗ ensures that neither Φ̃p̄,ε nor Φp̄,ε jump over the non-empty neigh-borhood of the nearest (non-repelling) mobile steady state. Since the latter isasymptotically stable, both processes must globally converge. This concludesthe proof of Proposition 7.

37

Page 38: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

lt+1

fl(le

t+1)

le

t+1

t

Figure 1: Competitive Equilibrium Given Arbitrary Current Skill Ratio λt

Page 39: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

C(n, ,x*)B( )C(s, ,x*)p 1 2

Figure 2: Homogeneous Agents: Steady States and Dynamics

Page 40: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

(b)(a)

(d)(c)

u

d

l l

ll

u

d

u

d

u

d

Figure 3: Upward and downward flows u(λ) and d(λ) for (a) homogeneous

cost 0.125; (b) measures γ = 0.075 and ι = 0.1 of geniuses and idiots, and nor-

mal agents with cost 0.125; (c) cost distributed uniformly on [0.115, 0.135];

and (d) uniformly on [0.075, 0.175]

Page 41: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

(b)(a)

(d)(c)

u

d

l l

l l

u

d

u

d

u

d

Figure 4: Upward and downward flows u(λ) and d(λ) for a (0.185, 0.3)-

normal distribution of costs truncated on (a) [0.175, 0.195]; (b) [0,∞); (c)

[0.175, 0.475]; and (d) [0.175,∞)

Page 42: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

0,3

0,5

0,4

0,4

0,20

0,1

0,10

0,3

0,5

0,2

u

d

l

Figure 5: Upward and downward flows u(λ) and d(λ) for cost types 1/8,

1/6, 3/16, and 10 having measures 0.075, 0.075, 0.075, and 0.775, respectively

Page 43: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

l1 l*

D

ln

l2

lt

ls

lt+1

Figure 6: Genius-Idiot Example: Convergent Dynamics

Page 44: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

D

l1

ln

l2

ls

lt

lt+1

Figure 7: Genius-Idiot Example: Divergent Dynamics

Page 45: Aboa Centre for Economics · capital, borrowing constraints, inequality, history-dependence . Contact information Dilip Mookherjee ... (or income risk) in a model of human capital

Aboa Centre for Economics (ACE) was founded in 1998 by the departments of economics at the Turku School of Economics and Business Administration, Åbo Akademi University and University of Turku. The aim of the Centre is to coordinate research and education related to economics in the three universities.

Contact information: Aboa Centre for Economics, Turku School of Economics and Business Admini-stration, Rehtorinpellonkatu 3, 20500 Turku, Finland.

Aboa Centre for Economics (ACE) on Turun kolmen yliopiston vuonna 1998 perustama yhteistyöelin. Sen osapuolet ovat Turun kauppakorkeakoulun kansan-taloustieteen oppiaine, Åbo Akademin national-ekonomi-oppiaine ja Turun yliopiston taloustieteen laitos. ACEn toiminta-ajatuksena on koordinoida kansantaloustieteen tutkimusta ja opetusta Turun kolmessa yliopistossa.

Yhteystiedot: Aboa Centre for Economics, Kansan-taloustiede, Turun kauppakorkeakoulu, 20500 Turku.

www.tukkk.fi/ace

ISSN 1796-3133