A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ......

52
Escaping the Last Malthusian Trap A talk by Eric Beinhocker McKinsey Global Institute Copyright © 2008 McKinsey & Company, Inc. All rights reserved Complex systems, climate change and economic growth Oxford 27 November 2008

Transcript of A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ......

Page 1: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Escaping  the Last  Malthusian  Trap

A talk byEric BeinhockerMcKinsey Global

Institute

Copyright © 2008McKinsey & Company, Inc. 

All rights reserved

Complex systems, 

climate change and 

economic growth

Oxford27 November 2008

Page 2: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

‘The ideas of economists and  political philosophers, both when  they are right and when they are  wrong, are more powerful than  is commonly understood. Indeed,  the world is ruled by little else.’

JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES

Page 3: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

‘We cannot solve problems by  using the same kind of thinking

we used when we created them.’ALBERT EINSTEIN

Page 4: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A complexityeconomics view

of growth

Why neo‐classical 

economics is the 

wrong tool for 

climate change

Escaping the 

trap: creating 

a revolution 

in carbon 

productivity

The lastMalthusian trap

Today’sdiscussion

Page 5: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A complexityeconomics view

of growth

Why neo‐classical 

economics is the 

wrong tool for 

climate change

Escaping the 

trap: creating 

a revolution 

in carbon 

productivity

The lastMalthusian

trap

Page 6: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Some 2.5 million years of economic history (in brief)

Source:  US Census Bureau Historical Estimates of 

World Population; Kremer (1993)

World populationThousands

0

1,000,000

2,000,000

3,000,000

4,000,000

5,000,000

6,000,000

7,000,000

-2,500,000 -2,000,000 -1,500,000 -1,000,000 -500,000 0 500,000

Year

World GDP per capita1990 international dollars

Source:  DeLong

(2005); data 2.5 million to 1 million B.C. 

extrapolated

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

-2,500,000 -2,000,000 -1,500,000 -1,000,000 -500,000 0 500,000

Year

Page 7: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

The Malthusian trap (circa 1000 BC to 1800 AD)

Rising population

Thousands

Source: US Census Bureau Historical Estimates 

of World Population; Kremer (1993)

900

800

600500400300

700

200100

0 500 1000 1500 1800 AD1800 AD

Stagnant incomes

Global income per person (1800 AD = 1)

Source: Clark (2007)

12

10

8

6

4

2

1000 BC 500 BC 0 500 1000 1500

Malthusian trap

0

Population

A

B

CSubsistence

Wages

Malthus in a nutshell

Page 8: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Then a third of the world escaped …

12

10

8

6

4

2

0

1000 BC 500 BC 0 500 1000 1500 2000 AD

Great Divergence

Industrial Revolution

Malthusian trap

Source: Clark (2007)

Global income per person (1800 AD = 1)

Page 9: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Source:  IPCC

AR4

WG1

(2007)

… but with an unsustainable growth model …

10,000 5000 0

Time (before 2005)

Changes in 

greenhouse 

gases from 

ice core and 

modern data

350

300

250

CO2

(ppm) Radiative

forcing (Wm2)

400

Page 10: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Source: McKinsey Global Institute

Annual household disposable income 

Number of households (millions)

… and another third of the world are poised to escape

100‐199

40‐99

25‐39

Less than 25

200 and above

Thousands RMB, real 2000 2005

1.0

8.8

71.4

107.5

1.6 

1.2

10.9

91.3

101.1

2.4 

2015

3.4

112.6

75.7

74.2

5.7 

3.3

55.1

106.0

74.1

5.5

2025

8.2

214.1

54.1

57.8

19.0 

9.5

94.9

93.1

49.9

33.1500‐999

200‐499

90‐199

Less than 90

1000 and above

CHINA

INDIA

Thousands RMB, real 2000

Page 11: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Humanity’s next, and perhaps last, Malthusian trap

Projection of surface temperatures

Source: IPCC

AR4

WG1

(2007)

Page 12: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

What we need to do, and where economics can help

The world’s to‐do list

Re‐do the Industrial 

Revolution, creating a 

sustainable economic 

system

Transition to a low‐

carbon economy with 

minimal impact on 

welfare and growth, 

especially for the 

developing world

Drive the above with 

policy –

conduct global 

social engineering on 

an unprecedented 

scale

Questions for  economics

How did the first Industrial 

Revolution occur? How 

might we create a new 

one?

What are the interactions 

between welfare, growth 

and de‐carbonisation? How 

do we assess the trade‐

offs?

What are the leverage 

points? How do we avoid 

unintended consequences?

Page 13: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A complexityeconomics view

of growth

Escaping the 

trap: creating 

a revolution 

in carbon 

productivity

The lastMalthusian trap

Whyneo‐classical 

economics is  the wrong tool  for climate 

change

Page 14: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Neoclassical economics cannot explain  key characteristics of the economy

Page 15: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

The economy is viewed as an equilibrium system

Page 16: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

The economy is viewed as an equilibrium systembut such a system cannot grow explosively, create 

novelty, nor spontaneously self‐organize 

Page 17: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

The accidental history of equilibrium in economics

Page 18: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Neoclassical failure #1: Theory of growth

Source: Bolow

(1956), Romer

(1996), Nelson (1996), Daly (1999)

Cannot explain the Industrial Revolution No connection with the physical world

Y (t)

=

Output Capital Knowledge Labour

F   (K (t)

,              A (t)

L (t)

)*

Page 19: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Neoclassical failure #2: Cost‐benefit analysis

Source: Stein (2006), Nordhaus

(2007), Weitzman (2007), Barker (2008)

Weitzman’s ‘Dismal Theorem’:

For any given n

and k, lim

E [M/λ]  =  + ∞

λ→∞

Uncertainty about climate has fat tails with power law scaling

Cost benefit analysis doesn’t work

Would pay a lot to avoid catastrophe

Prof. William Nordhaus Lord (Nicholas) Stern

“Discount rate!”‘Discount rate!’

Page 20: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Neoclassical failure #3: Human behaviour

Source: Axtell and McRae (2006a), (2006b)

Example

Society spends $1 billion today to save 10 lives per year in perpetuity

Social cost of capital equals 5%

Exponential answer

Cost = $4.76 million

per life saved

Hyperbolic answer

Cost = $1 million to $4 million

per life saved

Theory doesn’t match real world behaviour

Exponential discounting

Hyperbolicdiscounting

Page 21: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Neoclassical failure #4: Time symmetry

Source: Arrow and Fischer (1974), Frederich, Lowenstein, Donohue (2002), Dietz (2007)

Cost‐benefit analysis and discounting assume path independence and time symmetry

Samuelson :

M R S (τ, τ’) independent of C τ’’

But climate effects are highly path dependent and largely irreversible on human time scales

Page 22: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Why neo‐classical 

economics is the 

wrong tool for 

climate change

Escaping the 

trap: creating 

a revolution 

in carbon 

productivity

The lastMalthusian trap

A complexity  economics

view ofgrowth

Page 23: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Adaptive

Designs and strategies 

evolve over time

System

Macro patterns emerge 

from micro behavior

Complex

Many interacting agents and 

organizations of agents

A different explanation – the economy is a ‘complex  adaptive system’

Page 24: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.
Page 25: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.
Page 26: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Traditional economics versus complexity economics

Page 27: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A paradigm shift

TRADITIONAL ECONOMICS COMPLEXITY ECONOMICS

Economies are closed, static, linear 

systems in equilibrium

Economies are open, dynamic, 

non‐linear systems far from equilibrium

Dynamics

Homogeneous agents•

Only use rational deduction•

Make no mistakes, have no biases•

No need to learn

Heterogeneous agents•

Mix deductive/inductive decisions•

Subject to errors and biases•

Learn and adapt over time

Agents

Treats micro and macroeconomics as 

separate disciplines

Macro patterns emerge from micro 

behaviors and interactions

Emergence

Evolutionary process creates 

novelty and growing order and 

complexity over time

No endogenous mechanism for 

creating novelty or growth in order 

and complexity

Evolution

Explicitly accounts for agent‐to‐agent 

interactions and relationships

Assume agents only interact indirectly 

through market mechanisms

Networks

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 28: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

“Economic activity is fundamentally an order creating process” (Georgescu-Roegen)

Complex economic systems use energy to decrease  local entropy, create ‘fit order’

Energy inputs

CaloriesFossil

fuels

Ordered outputs:Goods and services(entropy locally decreased)

Disordered outputs:Waste products, heat, gases

(entropy universally increased)

Agents interacting

Page 29: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Evolution is a search algorithm for ‘fit order’

Create a variety of experiments

VARIATION

Select designs that are ‘fit’

SELECTIONAmplify fit designs, 

de‐amplify unfit designs

AMPLIFICATION

REPEAT

Page 30: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Long history of evolution in economics (and vice versa)

Problems• Driven by a biological metaphor for the economy • Not built on a general computational view of evolution

Page 31: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A general computational model of evolution

Design space Schema

1

0

1

1

0

0

1

0

0

0

Source: E.g. Holland (1975), Mitchell (1996), etc.

Schema reader‐builder

1011001000

Environment

Page 32: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A computational model of economic evolution

Plan 

A

Plan BPlan 

C

Plan D Plan 

E

Design space Schema reader‐builderSchema

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 33: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Economic evolution occurs in three ‘design spaces’

Physical 

technologies

Social 

technologies

Business 

plans

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 34: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Evolutionary search through ‘deductive‐tinkering’

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 35: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Technologies evolve

Page 36: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Business plans are a form of ‘design’

too

StrategyHigh‐end microprocessorsIntegrated chip setsChips/components

Social technologiesInnovation processesDirect salesCompetitive culture

Physical technologiesSemiconductor designTestingFabrication

StrategyLarge selection book superstoreSuburban malls, urban centresEnjoyable browsing experience

Social technologiesOrganized by brand/geographyValuesLogistic systems

Physical technologiesStore designComputersWarehousing

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 37: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Business A

Business B

Business C

Business D

Markets

Option A

Option B

Option C

Option D

Organizations

Business plan evolution works on three levels

Option A

Option B

Option C

Option D

Individuals ???

???

???

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 38: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

What would economic evolution look like?

Increasing variety and complexity

Non-linear wealthcreation

Spontaneous self-organization

Source: Beinhocker (2006)

Page 39: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

But we cannot avoid the Second Law of  Thermodynamics – order does not come for free

Page 40: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

A complexityeconomics view

of growth

Why neo‐classical 

economics is the 

wrong tool for 

climate change

The lastMalthusian trap

Escaping the  trap: creating 

a revolutionin carbon 

productivity

Page 41: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Solow wasn’t wrong – just incomplete

Y (t)

=

Output Capital Knowledge Labour

F   (K (t)

,              A (t)

L (t)

)*

Physical 

technologies

Social 

technologies

Business 

plans

Page 42: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Solow wasn’t wrong – just incomplete

Physical 

technologies

Social 

technologies

Business 

plans

Y (t)

=

Output Capital Knowledge Labour

F   (K (t)

,              A (t)

L (t)  

,              A (t)                       

R (t) 

)*

Physical 

technologies

Social 

technologies

Business 

plans

*

Knowledge Resources

Page 43: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

How do we evolve ‘carbon productivity’?

Kaya

identity

F p g e f= * * *

Anthropogenic(CO2

emissions)Population GDP 

percapita

Energyintensity of GDP

Carbon intensityof energy

Carbon productivity1

Non‐energy emissions 

and emissions from 

other GHGs

$GDP

CO2

ee f*+ ≈=~

Source: Beinhocker, et. al. (2008)

Page 44: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

0255075

100125150

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

0102030405060

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

To grow the economy and

reduce emissions, carbon  productivity must rise 10x to $7,300 per tonne by 2050

Global emissions, tCO2

e

Carbon productivity =

GDPEmissions

World GDP, US$ tn

(real 2000)

0

2,000

4,000

6,000

8,000

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

10x

Carbon productivity, US$ (real 2000)/tCO2

e7,300

55

20

146

41

+5.6% 

per year

+3.1% 

per year

/

‐2.4% 

per year

740

Source: Beinhocker, et. al. (2008)

Page 45: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

5.0

5.5

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

South Korea

Saudi ArabiaAustralia

Indonesia

Iran

VenezuelaNigeria

Liberia

Turkmenistan

Qatar

G8+5

Norway

France United Kingdom

Japan

Italy

GermanyMexicoUnited States

CanadaBrazilIndia

Austria

South AfricaRussia

Saint Kitts and NevisSwitzerlandMauritius

China

Sweden

Sri Lanka

Singapore

TurkeyPakistan

Bangladesh

Varied relationship between carbon productivity and  prosperity; no‐one is close to target carbon productivity

Carbon 

productivity000 US$(PPP)/tCO2e

Average carbon 

productivity

Source: McKinsey Global Institute

Carbon productivity 2007, 177 countries, all GHGs excluding LULUCF

ProsperityGDP per capita000 US$(PPP)

Adjusted for purchasing 

power parity, 2050 target = $13,300 

GDP/tonne

Page 46: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

0

2,000

4,000

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

14,000

16,000

‐2 ‐1 0 1 2 3 4 5

Source: McKinsey Global Institute

Forecast GDP growth rate 

2008‐2050, percent

Carbon productivity required to reach 20 Gt

CO2

e by 2050

US$ (real 2000)/tCO2

e

Base case forecast

GDP growth required to hit 20Gt

at 

BAU

carbon productivity growth

If emissions are capped, higher economic growth  requires higher carbon productivity

Annual real growth, %

Carbonproductivityrequired

‐2

‐1

0

1

2

3

4

5

870

1,300

2,000

3,100

4,700

7,000

10,500

15,800

Page 47: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

If we capped emissions and lived at today’s carbon  productivity, there is not much we could ‘afford’

*   Emissions from land use change not included** Based on 10Gt/year sustainable emissions and future population of 10 billion peopleSource:  McKinsey Climate Change Special Initiative

Page 48: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Carbon productivity has gradually increased over time

* 5‐year running average. Emissions data includes CO2

from fossil fuels and cement, with projections 

for CO2

from land use changes and five non‐CO2

gases (CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6) Source: McKinsey Global Institute

Page 49: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

0

2

4

6

8

10

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130Years

Index Year 0 = 1

But a carbon productivity revolution is required  three times faster than the industrial revolution

Carbon productivity growth required2008–50

US labor productivity 

growth 1830–1955

Source: Beinhocker, et. al. (2008)

Page 50: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

How do we create a carbon productivity revolution on par with Industrial 

Revolution – at three times the speed?

How do we activate the evolutionary processes of the economy to do so?

Physical technologies?

Social technologies?

Business plans?

Can we use policy to change the evolutionary fitness function of

the 

economy to include carbon?

Some questions and some hypotheses

A carbon price is necessary but far from sufficient‐

Industrial revolution did not happen because labour was expensive‐

Need mutual reinforcement between price signals and other selection

pressures (e.g., policy, social norms, competition)

Innovation in social technologies will be critical‐

New regulatory frameworks‐

New market structures‐

New business forms‐

New international institutions

We need to think more broadly than current policy debates, e.g.

Female education in developing countries

Green technology innovation clusters

Catalysing infrastructure investments‐

Changing cultural norms

Some questions

Page 51: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.

Summary: Escaping the Last Malthusian Trap

Industrial Revolution enabled a third of the population to escape the 

Malthusian trap of poverty, hardship and disease

But it created our next, and possibly last, Malthusian trap –

climate 

change

Escaping that trap will require a low‐carbon revolution on the scale of 

the Industrial Revolution, but at three times the speed

Economic revolutions are profoundly disequilibrium phenomena    

– not explained well by neoclassical theory

A complex systems view helps us understand the evolutionary 

processes that drive discontinuous innovation and growth

Climate policies should activate and leverage economic evolutionary 

processes –

policymakers need new ideas, there is much work to do!

Page 52: A talk by Escaping McKinsey Beinhocker Global the Last ... · of GDP. Carbon intensity. of ... United Kingdom. Japan. Italy. Mexico. Germany. United States. India. Brazil. ... 10,500.