A Model of Fluctuations

26
1 A Model of Fluctuations Here we begin to build a model of short term fluctuations in the economy around the long term trend.

description

A Model of Fluctuations. Here we begin to build a model of short term fluctuations in the economy around the long term trend. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of A Model of Fluctuations

Page 1: A Model of Fluctuations

1

A Model of Fluctuations

Here we begin to build a model of short term fluctuations in the

economy around the long term trend.

Page 2: A Model of Fluctuations

2

A major assumption of our short term model is that in the short run prices of goods and services are predetermined and set by firms. The prices do not change for a while. Fluctuations in demand lead to changes in output, but not prices.

Menu costs is a phrase we use to indicate the costly nature of changing prices in the short term.

If you think about a restaurant, they have price printed on a menu and if they wanted to change prices to changing conditions of daily demand they would spend a lot on changing the menu often.

By the way, the model we will study here is often called the Keynesian (rhymes with cane as in sugar cane, make it plural and add the name Ian – cane s Ian – Keynesian) model.

Page 3: A Model of Fluctuations

3

Planned Spending or Planned Aggregate Expenditure

The authors note that the output in the economy is determined by the amount people plan to spend. What people plan to spend is called planned aggregate expenditure, or planned spending.

Digress

In the national economy we said that output could be split up into the components called consumption, investment, government spending and net exports (Y = C + I + G + NX).

Part of investment is changes in inventory of the business community. Before I said investment is mainly new buildings, plant and equipment. While this is true, I now want to have you know about the changes in inventory as well.

Page 4: A Model of Fluctuations

4

To think about an example, say Coca Cola plans to add 100 cases of Coke to its inventory. Why? It wants to meet the needs of retailers and this is what it feels it needs.

Associated with this planned addition to inventory, it has a plan for how much it will sell and it will produce accordingly. Say it plans on selling 1000 cases. So it will make 1100 cases.

Now, if Coca Cola’s actual sales end up at 900 cases then

1) Actual sales (900) < planned sales (1000), and

2) Actual investment (200) > planned investment (100).

Similarly, if actual sales are 1050 cases the 1) Actual sales (1050) > planned sales (1000), and 2) Actual investment (50) < planned investment (100).

Page 5: A Model of Fluctuations

5

Now let’s think about planned spending by households, businesses, governments and the rest of the world. We will assume that households, governments and the rest of the world can actually carry out their plans. So, for example, when households plan to consume a certain amount when the time comes they do what the plan.

But, as we have seen with inventories, businesses can not always carry out their plan because folks may buy more or less than what the businesses planned and thus its actual inventory could be different than its plans.

Next let’s turn to how each group goes about its planned spending.

Page 6: A Model of Fluctuations

6

Graph we useC, I, G, X

450

Output or Income or RGDP

Here we will use a graph that puts RGDP on the horizontal axis and C, I, G, and X components on the vertical axis. These vertical axis components are planned spending amounts! We can add them up if we want.

Read this part second. If on the 45 degree line we know the horizontal amount equals the vertical amount.

Page 7: A Model of Fluctuations

7

ConsumptionIn the national economy we think the level of consumption expenditure depends on (among other things) income(RGDP).Say we have the following information:Income Consumption1000 16002000 22003000 2800

If income rises then households will consume more. The reverse is true if income falls. Define MPC = marginal propensity to consume. The MPC is the number of pennies C changes for each $1 change in income.

Page 8: A Model of Fluctuations

8

Consumption - MPCThe MPC is a fraction – the ratio of the change in consumption to the change in the income.Example:When income changes from 1000 to 2000 consumption changes from 1600 to 2200. The MPC =

(2200-1600)/(2000-1000) = 600/1000 = .6

Note the MPC is the same all along the consumption function. In the graph on the next slide the slope of the consumption function is the MPC.

Page 9: A Model of Fluctuations

9

consumption in the graph

income

C If income increases, we saw C will increase. We would move from point a to b, let’s say. We saw for every $ change in income, C changed by MPC. If from a to b income changed by 15 and MPC = .6, then Cchanged by ................?

a

b

C

(did you get 9, it took me two tries to get it, but then again I am short and slow.)

Page 10: A Model of Fluctuations

10

InvestmentInvestment is the amount of capital goods, buildings andchanges in inventories business want to undertake in thecurrent period. For now we focus on the planned investment and I will refer to it as Ip.For now we will assume all investment depends on factors other than income. For now we see it as a horizontal line representing a certain level of investment.

Page 11: A Model of Fluctuations

11

C+IpC+I

C

Ip

} Ip

}

C

Putting the C and Ip lines together meansat each income leveladd up C and Ip.

Page 12: A Model of Fluctuations

12

GovernmentIn our model the government can have an impact on the economy in two ways:1) by affecting expenditures directly by its own expenditures, what will be called G,2) by changing taxes and thus changing consumption C.

Government expenditure in this model will not depend on the level of RGDP, but instead depend on the political process. Thus G will look much like I in the model, and can change if done so in the political arena.Note, if taxes change by some amount w, C changes in the opposite direction by MPC times w because taxes take away income from spending.

Page 13: A Model of Fluctuations

13

GG

income

G1

In the RGDP diagram the level of G will not depend on the level of income. In this regard it is similar to investment. The level of G can shift up or down, as we will see shortly.

Page 14: A Model of Fluctuations

14

C, I and GG, C, I

income

G1

The expenditure line is now the C+Ip+G line

C1+Ip1+G1

Page 15: A Model of Fluctuations

15

foreign sectorX

income

X

The foreign sector can be added to the model in much the same way that the government sector could be. The net exports does not change as the level of income changes. For ease I will use X instead of NX.

Page 16: A Model of Fluctuations

16

C, I, G, and XG, C, I, X

income

X1

C1+Ip1+G1 +X1

The planned expenditure line is now the C+Ip+G + X line

Page 17: A Model of Fluctuations

17

So, in the graph on the previous screen I have income on the horizontal axis. This is the actual level of output or income generated. The 45 degree line can help me translate these horizontal actual levels into vertical levels.

The C + Ip + G + X line is the vertical planned amount of spending by the four sectors of the economy added up at each actual level of output.

What level of actual output will result? Quick answer: The actual output level will be the one where planned output = actual output. Let’s see why this is the case by looking at other output levels.

Page 18: A Model of Fluctuations

18

Where will we be?G, C, I, X

income

C1+Ip1+G1 +X1

Y1

Spending

Income (Y1)

At Y1, planned spending is more than income. Essentially firms will see inventories falling to really low levels. This will have stores call for more production. Production and income will rise. (How can you spend more than amount in income? Borrow or spend down your savings – not a recommendation, just a statement.)

Page 19: A Model of Fluctuations

19

Where will we be?G, C, I, X

income

C1+I1+G1 +X1

Y2

Spending

At Y2, planned spending is less than income. Essentially stores will see inventories building up to really high levels. Stores will then call for less production. Production and income will fall. Why make stuff if no one is buying?

Income (Y2)

Page 20: A Model of Fluctuations

20

Where will we be?G, C, I, X

income

C1+Ip1+G1 +X1

Ye

Spending

At Ye, planned spending is equal to income. Essentially stores will see inventories be about right where they want them to be so it will seem demand is what they thought it would be. Production and income will stay right here.

Income (Y*) =

This is called the spending balance point.

Page 21: A Model of Fluctuations

21

You will notice on the previous screen that the C, Ip, G, X lines add up to C1 + Ip1 + G1 + X1 and thus we get income level Ye. But if C, I, G, or X should shift we would get a new point for income.

On the next screen we will see government spending fall. Think about that. If G falls, goods the government used to buy would not be bought. Inventories would build up and we would expect firms to stop producing as much. Production and income (GDP) would fall.

Silly story: When the President of the US has a dinner with foreign dignitaries, maybe the White House has two cokes available for each guest. Then there is a change in policy – only one coke per guest. Coke wouldn’t make as much and the production and income would fall. The fall is magnified when the government really cuts spending.

Page 22: A Model of Fluctuations

22

Say G fallsG, C, I, X

income

C1+Ip1+G1 +X1 (line was here)

YeAt Ye, spending is now more than income. Inventory will be too high (or demand is too low.) Production and income will fall.

C1+Ip1+G2 +X1 (line falls to

here)

Page 23: A Model of Fluctuations

23

Output gapsG, C, I, X

income

PAE1

Y1

Spending

Income (Y*) =

Y*2Y*1

Expansionary gap Recessionary gap

Page 24: A Model of Fluctuations

24

Note on the previous screen that I have a line labeled PAE. This is just an easier way of typing C1 + Ip1 + G1 + X1.

The actual economy will gravitate to Y1 (I dropped the e part of Ye). But, if the potential output level is at a point other than Y1 we will have an output gap.

If the potential output is at Y*1, the actual output is above potential and we have an expansionary gap. Note at Y*1, Y*1 – Y1 < 0.

If the potential output is at Y*2, the actual output is below potential and we have a recessionary gap. Note at Y*2, Y*2 – Y1 > 0.

Page 25: A Model of Fluctuations

25

How do we get to these gaps?

Well, households control C, businesses control most of Ip (not the inventory part, as we said before), governments control G and the rest of the world controls X. Sometimes, folks have ideas that may mean the PAE line is not conducive to having the actual output occurring at the potential level.

Fiscal policy

Fiscal policy is a stabilization policy where the federal government influences the level of G or taxes (that affect C), or both. The idea is that perhaps the government can eliminate output gaps.

Page 26: A Model of Fluctuations

26

When there is a recessionary gap if the PAE line could be shifted up we could eliminate the gap. What do you think of this policy: have the president come on the TV and say to the people, “we have a recessionary gap and so if you just increase your spending we could eliminate the problem.”

Maybe folks would respond. We Americans often rally when the country is in trouble. But maybe we can’t given out current budgets, taxes paid and the like. So, an example of a fiscal policy is for the government to cut our taxes and thus households would increase C and the PAE line would shift up.

Another fiscal policy move would be for the government to just increase G (and not worry about changing taxes). Again PAE would shift up and the gap could be eliminated.

The opposite fiscal policy measures would be good when we have an expansionary gap.