A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the...

99
A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?" The mathematician replies "Four." The interviewer asks "Four, exactly?" The mathematician looks at the interviewer incredulously and says "Yes, four, exactly." Then the interviewer calls in the accountant and asks the same question "What do two plus two equal?" The accountant says "On average, four - give or take ten percent, but on average, four." Then the interviewer calls in the economist and poses the same question "What do two plus two equal?" The economist gets up, locks the door, closes the shade, sits down next to the interviewer and says "What do you want it to equal?" Textbook website: http://bcs.worthpublishers.com/gruber/default.asp? s=&n=&i=&v=&o=&ns=0&uid=0&rau=0

Transcript of A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the...

Page 1: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?" The mathematician replies "Four." The interviewer asks "Four, exactly?" The mathematician looks at the interviewer incredulously and says "Yes, four, exactly."

Then the interviewer calls in the accountant and asks the same question "What do two plus two equal?" The accountant says "On average, four - give or take ten percent, but on average, four."

Then the interviewer calls in the economist and poses the same question "What do two plus two equal?" The economist gets up, locks the door, closes the shade, sits down next to the interviewer and says "What do you want it to equal?" 

Textbook website:http://bcs.worthpublishers.com/gruber/default.asp?s=&n=&i=&v=&o=&ns=0&uid=0&rau=0

Page 2: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Cost-Benefit Analysis

8.4 Conclusion

8.3 Putting It All Together

8.2 Measuring the Benefits of Public Projects

8.1 Measuring the Costs of Public Projects

Chapter 8

cost-benefit analysis The comparison of costs and benefits of public goods projects to decide if they should be undertaken.

Page 3: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Cost-Benefit Analysis: Introduction

Cost-Benefit Analysis is a practical technique for determining the relative merits of alternative government projects over time.

The government uses cost-benefit analysis to compare the costs and benefits of public goods projects and decide if they should be undertaken.

Essentially 3 steps:1. Enumerate all costs and benefits of proposed

project2. Evaluate all costs and benefits in dollar terms3. Discount future net benefits

Page 4: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Introduction

In principle, such an analysis is an accounting exercise. (tracking cost expenditures and benefits)

In practice, cost-benefit analyses are rich economic exercises that combine theory and empirical work.

Page 5: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Example #1

Consider the monorail project in Seattle, which was narrowly approved in 2002. The costs consisted of construction and equipment,

buying permission from some landowners, ruined views, noise near the train, and traffic delays during construction.

The benefits consisted of reduced travel time, saved parking fees, reduced car maintenance, more reliable commuting times, fewer accidents and fatalities, better views for monorail passengers, and reduced noise from busses.

Analysts found that the monorail’s benefits were about $2.07 billion, while its costs were $1.68 billion.

The $390 million net benefit helped swing public opinion toward the project.

Page 6: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

MEASURING THE COSTS OF PUBLIC PROJECTS:

Transportation Example Consider the example of renovating a

turnpike that is in poor shape, with large potholes and crumbling shoulders that slow down traffic and pose an accident risk.

Should you repair the road? Table 1Table 1 shows the factors to consider.

Page 7: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Control-Benefit Analysis of Highway Construction Project

Quantity Price or Value

Total

Cost Asphalt 1 million bags

Labor 1 million hours

Maintenance $10 million/year

First-year cost:

Total cost over time:

Benefits

Driving time speed

500,000 hours

Lives saved 5 lives

First-year benefit:

Total benefit over time:

Benefit over time minus cost over time:

Table 1

Page 8: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Public Benefits and Costs

For private company: Benefits = revenues received Costs = firm’s payments for inputs

For public sector, market prices may not reflect social benefits and costs. Externalities, for example

Several ways of measuring benefits and costs Market prices Adjusted market prices Consumer surplus Inferences from economic behavior Valuing intangibles

Page 9: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Current Costs

The first goal is to measure current costs. The cash-flow accounting approach to costs simply adds up what the government pays for all the inputs.

This does not represent the social marginal cost we used in the theoretical public goods analysis, however.

Page 10: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Current Costs

The social marginal cost of any resource is its opportunity cost–the value of that input in its next best use. This is not necessarily its cash costs, but

by what else society could do with the input.

For the asphalt, the next best use is to sell the bag to someone else. The value of the alternative use is the market price.

Page 11: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Current Costs

If the labor market is perfectly competitive, the same logic applies–the value of an hour of labor used on the project is simply the market wage.

If there are imperfect markets, however, then there could be unemployment. For example, there could be a “living wage”

ordinance that mandates a $20/hour wage rate. This mandate, in turn, could lead to

unemployment. Imagine that those who were involuntarily

unemployed had a reservation wage of $5/hour; thus, they value their leisure at $5/hour.

Page 12: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Current Costs

In this case, the “alternative activity” is not working at another job, but rather being unemployed. This alternative activity only has an

opportunity cost of $5/hour, not $20/hour. This lowers the economic costs of the

project (but not the accounting costs). The unemployed workers derive rents,

which are simply payments to resource deliverers that exceed those necessary to employ the resource.

The Table 2Table 2 illustrates this.

Page 13: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Control-Benefit Analysis of Highway Construction Project

Quantity Price or Value

Total

Cost Asphalt 1 million bags $100/bag $100.0 m

Labor 1 million hours

½ at $20/hr½ at $5/hr

$12.5 m

Maintenance $10 million/year

First-year cost:

Total cost over time:

Benefits

Driving time speed

500,000 hours

Lives saved 5 lives

First-year benefit:

Total benefit over time:

Benefit over time minus cost over time:

Table 2

The accounting cost equals $20/hour x 1 million hours, or $20 million.

Page 14: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Future Costs

The asphalt and labor costs are immediate costs, but the last one–maintenance–is a stream of costs over time.

This cost is $10 million per year into the indefinite future. We translate this into current dollars using present discounted value.

Page 15: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Present Value:Future Dollars into the Present

Suppose someone promises to pay you $100 one year from now.

What is the maximum amount you should be willing to pay today for such a promise?

You are forgoing the interest that you could earn on the money that is being loaned.

Page 16: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Present Value:Future Dollars into the Present

The present value of a future amount of money is the maximum amount you would be willing to pay today for the right to receive the money in the future.

Page 17: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Present Value:Present Dollars into the Future

Define R = amount to be received in future r = rate of return on investment T = years of investment

The present value (PV) of the investment is:

PV

R

rT

1

Page 18: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Present Value:Future Dollars into the Present

In previous equation, r is often referred to as the discount rate, and (1+r)-T is the discount factor.

Finally, consider a promise to pay a stream of money, $R0 today, $R1 one year from now, and so on, for T years.

PV R

R

r

R

r

R

rT

T

01 2

21 1 1. . .

Page 19: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Present Value:Future Dollars into the Present

Present value is an enormously important concept

A $1,000,000 payment 20 years from now is only worth today: $376,889 if r=.05 $148,644 if r=.10

Page 20: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Control-Benefit Analysis of Highway Construction Project

Quantity Price or Value

Total

Cost Asphalt 1 million bags $100/bag $100.0 m

Labor 1 million hours

½ at $20/hr½ at $5/hr

$12.5 m

Maintenance $10 million/year

First-year cost:

Total cost over time:

Benefits

Driving time speed

500,000 hours

Lives saved 5 lives

First-year benefit:

Total benefit over time:

Benefit over time minus cost over time:

Table 2

The accounting cost equals $20/hour x 1 million hours, or $20 million.

Page 21: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Future Costs

The key question then becomes choosing the right social discount rate.

For a private firm, the answer would be the opportunity cost of what else the firm could do with the same funds, that is, the after tax rate of return.

The government should base its discount rate on the private sector opportunity cost, but the government counts both the after-tax portion of the return and the taxes collected.

Page 22: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Measuring Future Costs

In practice a variety of discount rates are used.

The Office of Management and Budget (OMB) recommended in 1992 that the government use a discount rate of 7%, the historical pre-tax rate of return on private investments, for all public investment projects.

Table 3Table 3 shows the costs.

Page 23: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Table 1. Discount rates used in different government agencies

American Government agencies and organizations

 Office of Management and Budget 7%

 Bureau of Land Management 10%

 U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service 7.8% (nominal rate)

 U.S. Forest Service 4%

 Congressional Budget Office 2%

 Government Accounting Office The average cost of Treasury debt

 Municipal Governments 3%

Page 24: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Control-Benefit Analysis of Highway Construction Project

Quantity Price or Value

Total

Cost Asphalt 1 million bags $100/bag $100.0 m

Labor 1 million hours

½ at $20/hr½ at $10/hr

$15.0 m

Maintenance $10 million/year

7% disc. rate

$143.0 m

First-year cost: $115.0 m

Total cost over time: $258.0 m

Benefits

Driving time speed

500,000 hours

Lives saved 5 lives

First-year benefit:

Total benefit over time:

Benefit over time minus cost over time:

Table 3

Page 25: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

MEASURING THE BENEFITS OF PUBLIC PROJECTS

There are three main benefits from the project: Value of driving time saved Value of reduced fatalities Value of reduced accidents

Page 26: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Driving Time Saved For consumers, we need some measure

of society’s valuation of time. There are several approaches to measuring this: Market based measures: Wages Survey based measures: Contingent

valuation Revealed preference measures

Page 27: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Driving Time Saved

How do we compute the value of commuting time saved?

For producers, the decreased costs shift the supply curve to the right (outward), leading to an increase in the total surplus. Assuming we have estimates of supply and demand in the output market, this is straightforward.

Page 28: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Driving Time Saved

If we had a perfectly functioning labor market, we could “cash out” the value of the time savings, a market-based measure.

Assuming the person can freely choose the hours he wants to work, then even if the time is spent on leisure, the appropriate valuation of the time is the wage rate.

The market based approach runs into problems that hours of work is “lumpy” and that there are non-monetary aspects of the job.

Page 29: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Driving Time Saved

Contingent valuation is a method of asking individuals to value an option they are not now choosing.

In some circumstances, this is the only feasible method for valuing a public good. For example, there is no obvious market

price to use to value saving a rare species of owl.

Page 30: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Problems with contingent Problems with contingent valuationvaluation

There are serious issues with contingent valuation, however. Isolation of issues matter: respondents value a

public good more when it is the only one asked about.

Order of issues matter: respondents place higher values on public goods asked about first.

“Embedding” matters: respondents seem to place roughly the same valuation on a public good, regardless of the quantity.

These problems suggest that part of the valuation is due to survey design, not “true” valuation.

Applicati

Applicati

onon

Page 31: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Driving Time Saved

The natural way for economists to value time is to use revealed preference–let the actions of individuals reveal their valuation.

For example, if one compared house prices for two houses, one of which was 5 minutes closer to the workplace, this would effectively “cash out” the value of saved commuting time.

Page 32: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Driving Time Saved

In practice, this approach runs into problems because the two homes are not identical.

Some of the differences (e.g., housing attributes) can be observed and accounted for with cross sectional regression. Decomposing a sale price by its attributes is the basis of hedonic market analysis.

Other differences are either hard to measure or unobserved, however, which leads to bias.

Page 33: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing time savingsValuing time savings

One clever quasi-experiment to reveal the value of saved time was conducted by Deacon and Sonstelie (1985): During the oil crisis of the 1970s, the government

imposed price ceilings on gasoline of large gasoline stations, but not independent ones.

As a consequence, long lines formed at these cheaper, corporate gasoline stations.

At Chevron stations in California, gasoline was approximately 39.5¢ lower, with an average wait time of roughly 14.6 minutes. The mean purchase was around 10.5 gallons.

Thus, the tradeoff is waiting 14.6 minutes to save about $4.15, or one hour for $17. This corresponded very closely to the average hourly wage in the U.S.

Empirical

Empirical

EvidenEviden

cece

Page 34: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

The other main benefit of the turnpike improvement is valuing saved lives due to lower traffic fatalities.

Valuing life runs into ethical issues, but almost all economists would agree that it is necessary for public policy decisions.

Page 35: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Lives

Article: Cost of Living : afraid Obamacare will put a price on human life. But we already do.

SLATE By Christopher BeamPosted Monday, Aug. 10, 2009

Death panels aside, system does put a price on life

Examples:

Buying life insurance Attorneys making assessment after accidents Higher wages for dangerous jobs

Page 36: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Great Britain system

Quality-Adjusted Life Year(QALY) (0-1.0) scaling (dead – perfect health) Applicable to different conditions Allows comparisons of different treatments for

different ailments Britain caps treatment at $50k/QALY

Page 37: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Comparative-Effectiveness Research

$1 billion in stimulus bill for CER research Goal : effectiveness Also possible to assess efficiency US tends to favor fairness over efficiency Not ready to move QALY into health debate Not yet

Page 38: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 39: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

By stating that life is priceless or should not be valued, we leave ourselves helpless when facing choices of different programs that could each save lives.

There are three main approaches to doing this: Using wages Contingent valuation Revealed preference

Page 40: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Public Benefits and Costs

Economists use two methods to assign finite values to human life: Lost earnings: Net present value of individual’s

after-tax earnings over lifetime. Taken literally, no loss for aged, infirm, or severely

handicapped Probability of death: Most projects affect probability

of death (e.g., cancer research). People are willing to accept increases in the probability of death for a finite amount of money.

Page 41: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing lifeValuing life

In 1993, consumer groups demanded that General Motors recall 5 million pickup trucks. The trucks’ side-mounted gas tanks made

them more likely to explode on impact, causing 150 deaths over a 15-year period.

The recall would cost $1 billion, and save at most 32 more lives, or $31.25 million per life saved.

GM reached a rather different settlement–provide $50 million for education about seat belts and drunk driving, and provide 200,000 child safety seats for low-income families.

Applicati

Applicati

onon

Page 42: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing lifeValuing life

The settlement was called “the most unprecedented buyout of law enforcement officials by a culpable corporation in regulation history.” – Ralph Nader.

Yet, the child safety seats alone would save 50 lives, which at a cost of $50 million, leads to a cost per life saved of just $1 million. Far more cost effective than the $31.25

million per life saved from the recall. Thus, by this measure, the settlement was

much better, but only possible because the government “valued life.”

Applicati

Applicati

onon

Page 43: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

The market-based approach uses wages; the value of the life is the present discounted value of the lifetime stream of earnings.

One key problem is that this approach does not value leisure. Keeler (2001) suggests that because of this, the value of a person’s life is about 5 to 10 times their future lifetime earnings.

Page 44: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

Keeler finds that the average 20 year-old female will have future earnings of $487,000 in net present value, but will value her life at $3.1 million.

Men have slightly higher values because of higher earnings.

Older people have lower values because they have fewer years of life remaining.

Page 45: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

The contingent valuation approach asks about the valuation of a life

There is obvious difficulty in a question like this, so it is often framed in terms of changes in the probability of dying. For example, how much more would you

pay for an airline ticket with a 1 in 500,000 chance of a crash compared with a 2 in 500,000 chance?

The estimates from contingent valuation have a very wide range, going from $825,000 to $22.3 million per life saved.

Page 46: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

The revealed preference approach examines how much individuals are willing to pay for something that reduces their odds of dying. For example, suppose a consumer

purchases an airbag for $350 that has a 1 in 10,000 chance of saving his life. The implicit valuation on life is $3.5 million.

Page 47: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

An alternative revealed preference approach examines risky jobs: Suppose that one job has a 2% higher

risk of death but pays $15,000 more in salary.

The $15,000 extra salary is known as the compensating differential.

The implicit valuation of life in this example is $3 million ($15,000/0.02).

Page 48: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

There is a large literature in economics using these revealed preference approaches. Viscusi estimates that the value of life is roughly $7 million.

There are drawbacks, however. Strong information assumptions about

probabilities. Assumes people are well prepared to evaluate

these tradeoffs. Difficult to control for other attributes of the job. Differences in valuation of life (e.g., degree of

risk aversion).

Page 49: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

www.law.georgetown.edu/gelpi/papers/pricefnl.pdf

Page 50: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

CBA Criticisms

Applications to health and environmental safety is flawed because of difficulty measuring non market items

Substituting risk of death with death is wrong CBA ignores who suffers from an

environmental or health risk problem

Page 51: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Saved Lives

Another approach focuses on how existing government spending translates into lives saved.

Recent study reviewed 76 regulatory programs; the costs per saved live varied between $100,000 for childproof cigarette lighters to $100 billion from regulation of solid waste disposal facilities.

Table 4 Table 4 shows the results.

Page 52: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Table 4

Costs Per Life Saved of Various Regulations

Regulation concerning … Year Agency

Cost per life saved

($ millions)

Childproof lighters 1993 CPSC $0.1

Food labeling 1993 FDA 0.4

Reflective devices for heavy trucks

1999 NHTSA 0.9

Children’s sleepware flammability

1973 CPSC 2.2

Rear/up/should seatbelts in cars

1989 NHTSA 4.4

Asbestos 1972 OSHA 5.5

Value of statistical life 7.0

Benezene 1987 OSHA 22

Asbestos ban 1989 EPA 78

Cattle feed 1979 FDA 170

Solid waste disposal facilities 1991 EPA 100,000

Page 53: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Discounting Future Benefits

A particularly thorny issue for cost-benefit analysis is that the costs are mostly short-term, while the benefits are mostly long term. Global warming is a good example.

This may be problematic because: The choice of discount rate will matter

enormously for benefits that are far in the future.

The benefits are spread out over current and future generations.

Page 54: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Cost-effectiveness Analysis

Finally, there may be cases when society is unwilling or unable to value the benefits of a public project.

Cost-effectiveness analysis is the search for the most cost-effective approach to providing a public good, ignoring whether the benefits warrant such a public good.

Page 55: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER

Table 5Table 5 adds in the benefits from the turnpike renovation.

Page 56: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Control-Benefit Analysis of Highway Construction Project

Quantity Price or Value

Total

Cost Asphalt 1 million bags $100/bag $100.0 m

Labor 1 million hours

½ at $20/hr½ at $10/hr

$15.0 m

Maintenance $10 million/year

7% disc. rate

$143.0 m

First-year cost: $115.0 m

Total cost over time: $258.0 m

Benefits

Driving time speed

500,000 hours $19/hr $9.5 m

Lives saved 5 lives $7 million/life

$35.0 m

First-year benefit: $44.5 m

Total benefit over time: $635.7 m

Benefit over time minus cost over time:

$377.7 m

Table 5

Page 57: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

NPV: B – C = $377.7 M

B/C ratio: $635.7M/ $258.0M = 2.46

Page 58: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER

Since the benefits exceed the costs, we would recommend the government pursue the project.

The government needs to consider one additional factor beyond the benefits and costs of the project itself: the budgetary cost of raising the funds to finance the project.

Economists typically assume some efficiency cost, or deadweight loss, from raising the tax burden to finance this spending. If the efficiency cost of raising the money is too high, some projects will not survive the cost-benefit analysis.

Page 59: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 60: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Project Evaluation

The present value criteria for project evaluation are that: A project is admissible only if its present

value is positive. When two projects are mutually exclusive,

the preferred project is the one with the highest present value.

Page 61: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Project Evaluation

Several other criteria are often used for project evaluation, but can give misleading answers Internal rate of return Benefit-cost ratio

Page 62: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Project Evaluation

The internal rate of return, ρ, is defined as the ρ that solves the equation:

01 1

0 01 1

B C

B C B CT TT

. . .

The IRR is the discount rate that would make the present value of the project equal to zero. Admissible if ρ>r. The flawed analysis would choose an admissible project

with the higher internal rate of return, ignoring scale.

Page 63: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Project Evaluation

The benefit-cost ratio divides the discounted stream of benefits by the discounted stream of costs. In this case:B=stream of benefits and C=stream of costs:

B B

B

r

B

rT

T

01

1 1. . .

C C

C

r

C

rT

T

01

1 1. . .

Page 64: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Project Evaluation

Admissibility using the benefit-cost ratio requires:

B

C1

This ratio is virtually useless for comparing across admissible projects, however.

Ratio can be manipulated by counting benefits as “negative costs” and vice-versa.

Page 65: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Valuing Public Benefits and Costs: other considerations

Consumer surplus Public sector projects can be large and

change market prices. Figure 11.1 measures the change in

consumer surplus from a government irrigation project that lowers the cost of agricultural production.

Page 66: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Figure 11.1

Page 67: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Other Issues in Cost-Benefit Analysis

There are a number of other issues in cost-benefit analysis.

These concern common “counting” mistakes and distributional concerns.

Page 68: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Other Issues in Cost-Benefit Analysis

The common counting mistakes or “games” include: Counting secondary benefits (like commerce that

is simply shifted from one area to another). Counting labor as a benefit rather than a cost. Double counting benefits (like the value of an

irrigation project to farm income, and simultaneously the increase in the value of the land)

Chain-Reaction game: Include secondary benefits to make a proposal appear more favorable, without also including the secondary costs

.

Page 69: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Other Issues in Cost-Benefit Analysis

There are also distributional concerns: The costs and benefits of a public

project do not necessarily accrue to the same individuals.

In principle, a project that improved social welfare could then involve redistribution, but in practice this rarely happens.

Page 70: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Budgetary Costs

Although we would recommend that the government pursue this project because the benefits were greater than the costs, in reality governments face limited budgets.

To assess which of many projects to pursue, the government must consider the budgetary cost of raising funds to finance the project. This involves some efficiency costs, or

deadweight loss. This cost should be factored into the

calculations.

Page 71: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Budgetary Costs

For example, consider two projects that pass the cost-benefit test: One project has benefits of $150, and

costs $100. The other has benefits of $110, and

costs $100. If the efficiency costs of raising funds is

20¢ for each $1 of revenue raised, then only the first project (with benefits that exceed $120) should be pursued.

Page 72: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Recap of Cost-Benefit Analysis

Measuring the costs of public projects Measuring the benefits of public

projects Putting it all together

Page 73: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Cost Benefit example

Analyzing a project $20 mil costs and benefits Benefits:

$14 m year 0, $5 in yr 1 $1 yr 3 Costs:

All $20 million in yr 0 Social discount rate: 10% --find B/C; NPV

Alt B: What if All $20 million construction in yr 2

Page 74: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 75: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 76: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 77: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 78: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 79: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Typical view of the ANWR 1002 area coastal plain

Page 80: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 81: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

ANWR Oil B-C Study Benefits

7.06 billion barrels of oil $53/bbl oil($2005) $374 billion (.55% of world oil reserves, <1 yr US use)

Costs Extraction costs $123 billion

Net social benefits-$37 billion state, $124b fed taxes

-$90 billion industry rents

Page 82: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Environmental costs of drilling

Environmental Impacts Vehicle traffic Pipeline and potential spills

Loss of last undeveloped wilderness area Nonmarket valuation Use vs nonuse values Nonuse valuation utilizes hypothetical markets---

Willingness to Pay WTP and

Willingness to Accept WTA

Page 83: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

WTA What is the minimum amount that individuals

would be willing to accept in order to allow drilling and development to occur in ANWR? No known WTA studies

Page 84: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Break-even analysis

At what point would these costs be greater than benefit of additional oil

Oil Benefits/ US Population (>18 y.o.) $251.4 B. /220.38 million

$1141/person or $38/yr/person for 30 years

Alternative uses of net benefits Environmental or alternative energy fund

Page 85: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

OP-ED CONTRIBUTOR

Save the Environment: Drill, Baby, Drill •E-Mail •Print •Save •Share

•Linkedin •Digg •Facebook •Mixx •YAHOO! BUZZ •Permalink

                       

By ROBERT HAHN and PETER PASSELL

Published: September 14, 2008 NY Times

1http%3a%Save%20

Americans

1194814220080915By%20ROOp%2dEdThe%20NOpinionopinionwww%2enoil%2b%2TxjdF4MF

Page 86: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 87: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 88: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 89: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 90: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Background

29 locks and dams built since the 1930’s to facilitate commerce on upper river

9 foot deep river channel has altered hydrology Shipping tonnage on the Mississippi increased rapidly

through the 1970’s Growth has slowed since then Congestion increasing at lower locks because long

barges need to uncouple

Page 91: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Beginning in late 1980’s, the Army Corps has been studying rebuilding locks

15 years and $50 million have gone into studying the issue

Page 92: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Study structure

6 alternative levels of lock improvements With 5 economic scenarios

Costs to implement and operate each alternative were estimated

Page 93: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Benefits

National Economic Development: monetary impacts to the nation of positive

effects (primarily transportation efficiencies Cost savings of barge shipping compared to

alternatives (trucking and train Environmental Mitigation

Restoration of wildlife habitat, fisheries Improved recreation opportunities (boating,

fishing

Page 94: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 95: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 96: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Recommended Plan

$2.6 billion for navigation efficiency improvements $1.79 billion for 7 new locks

$5.7 billion for ecosystem restoration

Investments to be made over 50 years

Page 97: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Major criticisms

Alternative scheduling and traffic management not fully considered

Traffic forecasts not valid Grain exports were slowing before ethanol growth

Federal funding share criticized In 2000, lead economist reported being forced to use

assumptions favoring construction Environmental benefit measurement

Page 98: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"
Page 99: A mathematician, an accountant and an economist apply for the same job. The interviewer calls in the mathematician and asks "What do two plus two equal?"

Cost Benefit example

Analyzing a project $20 mil costs and benefits Benefits:

$14 m year 0, $5 in yr 1 $1 yr 3 Costs:

All $20 million in yr 0 Social discount rate: 10% --find B/C; NPV

Alt B: What if All $20 million construction in yr 2