A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

download A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

of 25

Transcript of A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    1/25

    A Knowledge Accessing Theory ofStrategic Alliances

    Robert M. Grant and Charles Baden-FullerMcDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Washington, DC; Cass Business School,

    City University, London

    The emerging knowledge-based view of the firm offers new insight into

    the causes and management of interfirm alliances. However, the development of

    an effective knowledge-based theory of alliance formation has been inhibited by a

    simplistic view of alliances as vehicles for organizational learning in which strategic

    alliances have presumed to be motivated by firms desire to acquire knowledge from

    one another. We argue that the primary advantage of alliances over both firms and

    markets is in accessingrather than acquiringknowledge. Building upon the distinction

    between the knowledge generation (exploration) and knowledge application

    (exploitation), we show that alliances contribute to the efficiency in the applicationof knowledge; first, by improving the efficiency with which knowledge is integrated

    into the production of complex goods and services, and second, by increasing

    the efficiency with which knowledge is utilized. These static efficiency advantages

    of alliances are enhanced where there is uncertainty over future knowledge

    requirements and where new products offer early-mover advantages. Compared

    with alternative learning-based approaches to alliance formation, our proposed

    knowledge-accessing theory of alliances offers the advantages of greater theoretical

    rigour and consistency with general trends in alliance activity and corporate strategy.

    INTRODUCTION

    One of the most important trends in industrial organization of the past quarter

    century has been the growth of collaboration between independent companies.

    As large companies have pulled back their corporate borders through outsourcing

    and divestment of non-core activities, they have increasingly cooperated with

    other companies in order to engage in activities and access resources outside their

    own boundaries.

    Journal of Management Studies41:1 January 20040022-2380

    Address for reprints: Robert M. Grant, McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Wash-

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    2/25

    These interfirm alliances involve cooperative relationships that are not fully

    defined either by formal contracts or by ownership. Hence, in terms of the theory

    of economic organization, they fall between the polar models of markets and hier-

    archies. As a result, cooperative relationships between firms have been viewed as

    intermediate or hybrid organizational forms (Borys and Jemison, 1989; Powell,1987; Thorelli, 1986). To distinguish longer-term more substantial collaboration

    from more casual cooperative arrangements between firms, the term strategic

    alliance has been used to refer to agreements characterized by the commitment

    of two or more firms to reach a common goal entailing the pooling of their

    resources and activities (Teece, 1992, p. 19). Within such alliances, the parties

    . . . maintain autonomy but are bilaterally dependent to a non-trivial degree

    (Williamson, 1991, p. 271).

    Strategic alliances embrace a diversity of collaborative forms. The activities

    covered include supplier-buyer partnerships, outsourcing agreements, technical

    collaboration, joint research projects, shared new product development, shared

    manufacturing arrangements, common distribution agreements, cross-selling

    arrangements, and franchising. While the defining governance mode is the infor-

    mal relational contract, strategic alliances may involve contractual agreements

    (e.g. franchising and cross-licensing agreements) and ownership links (e.g. cross-

    equity holdings and joint ventures).[1]

    The increasing importance of strategic alliances has resulted in growing inter-

    est in theorizing about their causes and consequences. However, the diversity ofthe phenomenon challenges our ability to develop all-encompassing theories. The

    problem is not so much a lack of theory as an overabundance. Theories of alliance

    formation include the creation of market power to generate monopoly rents (Katz,

    1986; Schwartz, 1987; Stocking and Watkins, 1946), resource-dependency theory

    (Barley et al., 1992; Guetzkow, 1966; Van de Ven, 1976), strategic options (Hurry,

    1993; Kogut, 1991; Sanchez, 1993), product complementarities and network

    externalities (Rotemberg and Saloner, 1991), and transaction cost theory (Oxley,

    1997; Ring and Van De Ven, 1992; Williamson, 1991). However, the emergence

    of resource-based approaches to strategy especially those emphasizing the role

    of knowledge has provided a broader basis upon which to build a theory of inter-

    firm cooperation.

    At the same time, the usefulness of knowledge-based approaches to the analy-

    sis of strategic alliances has been limited by cursory analysis of the role of knowl-

    edge in alliance relationships and the widespread presumption that the goal of

    alliances is to facilitate organizational learning. This emphasis on learning the

    acquisition of knowledge fails to recognize the central attribute of the strategic

    alliance as an organizational mode that can reconcile the benefits of knowledgespecialization with those of flexible integration.

    Th f hi i h f i lli h f

    62 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    3/25

    resources of other firms. In doing so, we offer two main contributions to the lit-

    erature on interfirm alliances. First, we clarify alternative knowledge-based motives

    for strategic alliances within the knowledge-based economy and counter the wide-

    spread presumption that the primary motive is knowledge acquisition through

    organizational learning. Second, we develop the knowledge-accessing explanationof strategic alliances by outlining a theory of the efficiency advantages of stra-

    tegic alliances (relative to both firms and markets) in exploiting knowledge assets.

    Our theory does not purport to be a comprehensive theory of strategic alliances.

    We recognize that in as diverse a phenomenon as strategic alliances, there are likely

    to be multiple motives and that a single theory cannot address all types of alliances.

    In particular, we recognize that some alliances may be motivated by market power

    considerations, others may be formed to access resources other than knowledge,

    and even within the knowledge-view of alliances some may be created with

    the primary intention of acquiring rather than to accessing knowledge. However,

    our contention is that knowledge accessing provides the predominant motive for

    alliance formation, especially within the knowledge-based sectors where alliance

    activity has been especially prevalent (e.g. pharmaceuticals, semiconductors,

    aerospace, telecommunications, and consumer electronics).[2]

    We begin by reviewing knowledge-based approaches to the analysis of interfirm

    alliances. We then outline an analysis of knowledge-based production that permits

    us to identify the circumstances in which alliances offer efficiency advantages over

    both firms and markets.

    KNOWLEDGE AND INTERFIRM ALLIANCES

    In the same way that the knowledge-based view of the firm has grown out of

    resource-based theory of the nature and existence of firms (Grant, 1996), knowl-

    edge-based explanations of the formation of strategic alliance formation have

    their roots in resource-based approaches to alliances. Drawing upon resource-

    dependence theory (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978) and the resource-based view of

    the firm (Penrose, 1957), several studies (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1996;

    Gulati, 1999; Rothaermel, 2001; Van De Ven and Walker, 1984) have viewed

    alliances as a quest for resources. Moreover, certain types of resources appear to

    particularly influential in alliance formation. The concentration of alliances in

    R&D intensive sectors points to technology as playing a key role in alliance for-

    mation (Dickson and Weaver, 1997; Dodgson, 1992; Doz, 1988; Hagedoorn,

    1993). As technology management became absorbed within the wider field of

    knowledge management, so alliances have been viewed from a broader knowledge

    perspective. Several studies of strategic alliances have identified the sharing ofknowledge (including technology, know-how and organizational capability) as

    h i d i bj i (Cib 1 1 D d N b k 000 I k d

    Strategic Alliances 63

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    4/25

    1988; Mody, 1993; Mowery et al., 1996, 1997; Simonin, 1997, 1999). Among these

    studies, the great majority have adopted an organizational learning perspective:

    assuming that the goal of strategic alliances is to acquire the knowledge of alliance

    partners. The outcome may be a competition for learning where each alliance

    member seeks to learn at a faster rate than its partner in order to achieve a posi-tive balance of trade in knowledge (Hamel, 1991). This can destabilize the rela-

    tionship (Inkpen and Beamish, 1997), unless the alliance partners are successful in

    building relational capital that can reconcile reciprocal learning with the protec-

    tion of core knowledge assets (Kale et al., 2000).

    The knowledge-based literature identifies two conceptually distinct dimensions

    of knowledge management. First, those activities that increase an organizations

    stock of knowledge what March (1991) refers to as exploration, and Spender

    (1992) calls knowledge generation. Second, those activities that deploy existing

    knowledge to create value what March (1991) refers to as exploitation, and

    Spender (1992) calls knowledge application. In relation to strategic alliances, this

    distinction between knowledge generation and knowledge application corresponds

    to a key distinction in the ways in which knowledge is shared among alliance part-

    ners. Knowledge generation points to alliances as vehicles of learningin which each

    member firm uses the alliance to transfer and absorb the partners knowledge base.

    Knowledge application points to a form of knowledge sharing in which each

    member firm accessesits partners stock of knowledge in order to exploit comple-

    mentarities, but with the intention of maintaining its distinctive base of special-ized knowledge.

    Several prior studies have distinguished these two types of knowledge sharing

    within alliances. Hamel (1991, p. 84) notes, The crucial distinction between

    acquiring such skills in the sense of gaining access to them . . . and actually inter-

    nalising a partners skills has seldom been clearly drawn. Similarly, Inkpen

    (1998, p. 72) observed that: In some alliances, partners aggressively seek to acquire

    alliance knowledge while in others, the partners take a more passive approach

    to knowledge acquisition. From a transaction cost perspective, Hennart (1988) has

    also identified a similar competition/cooperation tension. The distinction between

    acquisition and accessing is critically important of the evolution of the alliance

    partners knowledge bases. Among Japanese-US joint ventures, Nakamura et al.

    (1996) observed technological convergence in joint ventures where the partners

    engaged in mutual organizational learning, and the opposite tendency among

    joint ventures where partner firms competitive capabilities have become dissimi-

    lar but complementary (p. 536). A similar dichotomy was detected by Mowery

    et al. (1996): the lack of significant overall trend towards either convergence or

    divergence between partners technology bases among 792 alliances appearedto disguise the fact that some alliances were converging (implying mutual

    l i ) hil h di i (i l i i li i d k l d

    64 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    5/25

    While acknowledging that learning occurs in all alliances and that some

    alliances are motivated primarily by the desire to acquire partners knowledge,[4]

    our contention is that knowledge accessing rather than knowledge acquisition is

    the primary motivation for knowledge-based alliances. This view of alliances is

    consistent with the trends in corporate strategy over the past two decades. Theprimary trend since the early 1980s has been towards refocusing: the emergence

    of truly focused companies . . . concentrated around a core set of knowledge or

    service skills (Quinn, 1992, p. 373). This trend is not obviously consistent with the

    firms using alliances to continually broaden their knowledge bases as they acquire

    their partners knowledge. On the basis of both logic (to be developed more for-

    mally in subsequent sections) and casual empiricism, we suggest a general ten-

    dency for firms to concentrate upon a few core competences and to collaborate

    with other firms in order to access additional capabilities. Thus, Daimler-Benzs

    initial collaboration with Swatch in designing its Smart car was motivated, not

    by Mercedes desire to acquire Swatchs precision engineering and microdesign

    capabilities and Swatchs desire to acquire Daimlers automotive know-how, but

    by both parties desire to create value through combining their separate knowl-

    edge bases. Similarly, Luciano Pavarottis collaboration with the Spice Girls was

    for the purposes of combining their different styles and capabilities in a music

    album, not about Pavarotti learning how to be a girl band, or the Spice Girls

    acquiring operatic skills (Pavarotti, 1998).

    A key feature of knowledge-based explanations of alliances is imprecisionaround the concepts of organizational learning, knowledge sharing, and knowl-

    edge transfer. Mowery et al. (1996) concluded that: The learning that takes

    place within alliances thus appears to be more complex than most of the litera-

    ture on this topic suggests, underlying the need for better definitions of learning

    in theoretical discussions of alliance activity and highlighting this as an area ripe

    for further study (p. 89). Our goal is to develop a more precise theory con-

    cerning the role of knowledge in alliances, emphasizing the role of alliances as

    mechanisms for knowledge accessing. We begin with a few precepts concerning

    the characteristics of knowledge and its role in economic activity from which we

    derive implications for the circumstances under which interfirm alliances are more

    efficient than both markets and firms in organizing production.

    ALLIANCES AND STATIC EFFICIENCY IN

    KNOWLEDGE APPLICATION

    Features of Knowledge-based Production

    The key challenge facing any theory of strategic alliances is to specify the cir-

    i hi h i fi lli i

    Strategic Alliances 65

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    6/25

    tional economics that has found it easy to establish the transaction costs associated

    with markets and the agency problems inherent within firms, but more difficult to

    identify the circumstances under which alliances and other hybrid forms emerge.

    Thus, Williamsons (1991) observation that hybrid forms are associated with inter-

    mediate levels of asset specificity, adaptability and incentive intensity presents theproblem that quantitative assumptions are required in order to generate qualita-

    tive predictions. Knowledge-based theory has the potential to illuminate more

    powerfully the rationale for interfirm alliances.

    Let us begin with some basic assumptions concerning knowledge and its role in

    production:

    (1) Knowledge is the overwhelmingly important productive resource in terms

    of market value and the primary source of Ricardian rents (Grant, 1996;

    Machlup, 1980).[5]

    (2) Different types of knowledge vary in their transferability: explicit knowledge

    can be articulated and easily communicated between individuals and or-

    ganizations; tacit knowledge (skills, know-how, and contextual knowledge) is

    manifest only in its application transferring it from one individual to

    another is costly and slow (Kogut and Zander, 1992; Nonaka, 1994).

    (3) Knowledge is subject to economies of scale and scope. Since the costs of

    replicating knowledge tend to be lower than the costs of the original dis-

    covery of creation of the knowledge, it is subject to economies of scale. Tothe extent that knowledge is not specific to the production of a single

    product, economies of scale imply economies of scope. The extent of

    economies of scale and scope vary considerably between different types of

    knowledge. They are especially great for explicit knowledge, information in

    particular, which is costly to produce, but cheap to reproduce (Shapiro

    and Varian, 1999, p. 3). Tacit knowledge tends to be costly to replicate, but

    these costs are lower than those incurred in its original creation (Winter,

    1995).

    (4) Knowledge is created by individual human beings and to be efficient in

    knowledge creation and storage, individuals need to specialize (Simon, 1991,

    p. 127).

    (5) Producing a good or service typically requires the application of many types

    of knowledge (Kogut and Zander, 1992).

    If we accept these (relatively uncontroversial) initial premises, we are immediately

    faced with some intriguing challenges for economic organization. In particular, the

    fundamental dichotomy between knowledge creation (exploration) and knowledgeapplication (exploitation) becomes clear: knowledge creation requires specializa-

    i ( i 3 d 4 b ) hil k l d li i i di i f

    66 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    7/25

    knowledge (point 5). Given the limited transferability of knowledge (point 2), this

    presents considerable difficulty for the institutions of production. The solution lies

    in some process of knowledge integration that permits individuals to apply their

    specialized knowledge to the production of goods and services, while preserving

    the efficiencies of specialization in knowledge acquisition (Demsetz, 1991).If we abstract, for the time being, from knowledge generation and focus upon

    knowledge application, what factors determine the efficiency with which knowl-

    edge assets are transformed into goods and services? If production requires the

    combination of many different types of specialized knowledge (point 5), each of

    which is subject to economies of scale and scope (point 3), then efficiency in knowl-

    edge application depends upon, first, the ability to integratemany different types of

    knowledge and, second, the ability to utilizeknowledge to its full capacity. Let us

    explore knowledge integration and knowledge utilization in alternative institu-

    tional mechanisms: markets, firms, and alliances.

    Alliances and the Efficiency of Knowledge Integration

    Efficiency of integration relates to the costs of combining multiple types of knowl-

    edge into goods and services. These costs depend critically upon the mode of inte-

    gration used. As Demsetz observes, it is highly inefficient for individuals to

    combine their knowledge by each learning what the other knows: Although knowl-

    edge can be learned more effectively in specialized fashion, its use to achieve highliving standards requires that a specialist somehow uses the knowledge of other

    specialists. This cannot be done only by learning what others know, for that would

    undermine gains from specialised learning (Demsetz, 1991, p. 172). Efficiency in

    knowledge integration requires modes of coordination that can avoid the high

    costs of extensive mutual learning.

    The knowledge-based view of the firm views the critical advantage of firms over

    markets as providing a superior context for supporting knowledge integration

    mechanisms. Firms are social communities in which individual and social exper-

    tise is transformed into economically-useful products and services by the applica-

    tion of a set of higher-order organizing principles (Kogut and Zander, 1992,

    p. 384). Drawing upon two streams of literature, classical organizational theory

    (e.g. Hall, 1972) and evolutionary economics (e.g. Nelson and Winter, 1982), we

    identify two primary mechanisms through which knowledge is integrated within

    the firm: direction and routine.

    Direction provides a low-cost method of communicating between specialists and

    the large number of persons who are either non-specialists or specialists in other

    fields (Demsetz, 1991, p. 172). Firms convert sophisticated specialized knowledgeinto directives, rules, and operating procedures that can be imposed through

    h i b d l i hi [6]

    Strategic Alliances 67

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    8/25

    Organizational routinesare complex patterns of co-ordination that permit different

    specialists to integrate their knowledge into the production of goods and services

    while preserving the efficiencies of knowledge specialization (Nelson and Winter,

    1982). Organizational routines require continuity of association and propinquity

    conditions most readily provided by firms.By contrast, market contracts suffer from the familiar sources of transaction cost

    that afflict exchange transactions in knowledge. Information and other forms of

    explicit knowledge suffer problems of non-exclusivity of use and the difficulty of

    concluding contracts without first revealing the knowledge involved (Arrow,

    1962).[7] Tacit knowledge is also problematical because, in order to mesh their areas

    of know-how, transacting parties are likely to require a . . . common language or

    . . . overlaps in cognitive frameworks . . . This requires time and effort: investments

    which are to some extent . . . transaction specific . . . [hence] yield issues of depen-

    dence and lock-in (Nooteboom, 1996, p. 331). Within the firm, these problems

    are ameliorated by a social context characterized by a common identity of or-

    ganizational members (Kogut and Zander, 1996) and the ability of the firm to

    appropriate knowledge rents through secrecy (Liebeskind 1996).[8] In addition,

    markets are less able than firms to support either direction or routine. While rou-

    tines develop within markets, market-based routines are often less adaptable and

    less effective in integrating the individuals specialist knowledge than those within

    a single firm.[9]

    Alliances can avoid many of the costs associated with knowledge transactionsacross markets. Alliances limit opportunism by converting single period into multi-

    period games and fostering investments in trust (Gulati, 1995; Ring and Van de

    Ven, 1992; Simonin, 1997; Teece, 1992). Yet, inevitably alliances are inferior to

    firms in terms of their inability to integrate knowledge through higher-order or-

    ganizing principles. They typically lack the authority-based relationships needed

    for rules and directives and, although many alliances are very long lasting, most

    lack the close, continuous association conducive to developing routines.[10]

    Are there circumstances where alliances can be superior to firms in knowledge

    integration? The key problem for knowledge integration within the firm is that,

    whether integration is by direction or routine, the efficiency of integration tends

    to decline as the firms knowledge domain expands. As with any complex system,

    the large-scale knowledge integration required for producing goods and services

    requires a hierarchy of integration (Simon, 1962). On the basis of intensity of

    interdependence (Thompson, 1967), knowledge can be combined into specific

    tasks, which can then be integrated in activity-related and functional capabilities

    (Grant, 1996). With loose coupling of components and sub-systems, such struc-

    tures permit adaptability and evolutionary development (Sanchez and Mahoney,1996; Weick, 1976).

    T b ffi i i i d i di i d l b d di d

    68 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    9/25

    tines: to the extent that they are embedded within organizational values and

    norms, the common culture of an organization limits the variety of routines that

    can be efficiently performed. Thus, as the range and diversity of knowledge

    increases, so integration mechanisms need to be increasingly differentiated, result-

    ing in rising marginal costs of knowledge integration within the firm. In thesecircumstances, efficiency of integration may be maximized through separate

    firms integrating knowledge at the component or subsystem level, with overall

    integration through an alliance between the firms.

    To summarize:

    Proposition 1: (a) In integrating knowledge, interfirm alliances are generally

    superior to market contracts, but are generally inferior to individual firms. (b)

    Increasing marginal costs of knowledge integration within the firm imply that,

    where products require a broad range of different knowledge types, efficiency

    of integration is maximized through separate firms specializing in different areas

    of knowledge and linked by strategic alliances.

    Illustration and evidence. Prior research points to numerous examples of companies

    turning to strategic alliances when they extend their knowledge domains to areas

    of know-how that need to be integrated with different rules and routines. The

    rapid growth in strategic alliances within biotechnology reflects the advantages of

    alliances between dedicated biotechnology companies and large, integrated phar-maceutical companies as compared to mergers and acquisitions. Any benefits of

    full merger in terms of closer integration are likely to be offset by the difficulty

    of reconciling the different routines and operating rules required in the pharma-

    ceutical business from those required for leading-edge biotechnology research

    (Barley et al., 1992; Powell, 1998). Similarly in semiconductors, although firms

    are more effective than alliances in sharing and developing knowledge (Almeida

    et al., 1998), as the range of knowledge required for the design and manufacture

    of semiconductors continues to expand, so alliances have proliferated, both

    between semiconductor design companies and between designers and fabricators

    (Macher, 2001). Even so, for alliances to achieve effective knowledge integration

    within networks of alliances typically requires one firm to act as overall system

    integrator (Lorenzoni and Baden-Fuller, 1994). This role requires some duplica-

    tion of knowledge by the integrating firm. As Prencipe (1997) has shown, the role

    of aero engine manufacturers as systems integrators for many hundreds of

    suppliers of components and sub-systems requires that they maintain a residual

    level of R&D in the component technologies that they are responsible for

    integrating.Consider too Eastman Kodaks transition from chemical to digital imaging.

    D i i fi 100 f d l K d k bli h d hi hl i d

    Strategic Alliances 69

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    10/25

    polymer, silver halide, technologies; consumer and professional markets; large-

    scale, low-cost manufacturing; and worldwide distribution. However, the digital

    imaging revolution required Kodak to extend its knowledge base into infoimag-

    ing including new technologies ranging from electronic sensing to file com-

    pression. Many of the rules and organizational routines that Kodak had developedfor managing traditional photography were not well-suited to the faster moving

    world of digital imaging (Grant and Neupert, 2003). In particular, when CEO

    George Fisher requested the company to introduce a fully digital camera for the

    consumer market, he was told that the companys standardized system of phases

    and gates would require three years of development. Through an alliance with

    Apple Computer, the camera the Apple Quicktake was developed and brought

    to market within seven months (Pinto, 2000). Digital imagings need for differen-

    tiated rules and routines to achieve fast response capability and compressed

    product development and manufacturing cycles resulted in Kodaks widespread

    use of strategic alliances in its digital imaging business.

    Alliances and the Efficiency of Knowledge Utilization

    Given economies of scale and scope in knowledge, utilizing knowledge assets to

    their full capacity represents a key challenge to the firm. These economies of scale

    and scope are reinforced by the fact that, unlike most other resources, knowledgeexpands rather than depreciates when it is used.

    Given that market contracts for knowledge are plagued by transaction costs, it

    is typically assumed that economies of scale and scope in knowledge are best

    exploited within the firm. However, once we explore the problem faced by the firm

    in reconciling its product and knowledge boundaries, we can identify circum-

    stances where alliances can offer efficiencies in knowledge utilization beyond those

    available through full internalization.

    Achieving a match between a firms knowledge domain and its product domain

    poses a significant problem for most firms because limits to firm growth within

    individual markets typically prevent full exploitation of knowledge within a single

    market. Hence, for a firm to fully exploit its knowledge resources usually means

    diversifying into additional products. However, if different types of knowledge

    have different product domains, the problem offitarises between the firms knowl-

    edge domain and its product domain.

    Conventionally, a firm is described by the products it supplies. The knowledge-

    based view implies that a firm may also be described by the range of knowledge

    that it encompasses. The two are closely related, and it is the closeness of this rela-tionship that is a critical determinant of the efficiency of knowledge utilization. If

    k l d i d ifi d i bj i f

    70 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    11/25

    1959). Efficient utilization of knowledge is achieved where the knowledge domain

    of the firm matches exactly the knowledge requirements of the product domain

    of the firm with no overlap and, thus, no underutilization of knowledge. The

    problem is that different types of knowledge are applicable to different sets of

    products. This presents difficult choices for the firm over which types of knowl-edge to possess and which products to produce.[11]

    The relationship between a firms knowledge domain and its product domain

    may be shown as an input-output matrix of knowledge and products, where inputs

    of specialized knowledge form the columns, and outputs of products form the

    rows. Consider Figure 1 which shows the product and knowledge domains of the

    ABC Corporation. Figure 1a begins with the products (rows AH) supplied by

    ABC Corporation. Figure 1a shows the knowledge inputs (columns 118) required

    to produce these products. Figure 1b then considers ABC Corporations knowl-

    edge assets (columns 110) and identifies the different products (rows AN) that

    each type of knowledge could be applied to.

    Strategic Alliances 71

    (a)

    (b)

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18

    A

    B

    CD

    E

    F

    G

    H

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    AB

    C

    D

    E

    F

    G

    H

    J

    K

    L

    M

    N

    I

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    12/25

    From the point of view of efficient knowledge utilization, the boundaries of

    ABC Corporation are determined by a combination of knowledge types and prod-

    ucts that permits ABCs knowledge resources to be utilized to the fullest extent

    possible. But, if different products have different knowledge requirements, there

    will always be a problem of under-utilized knowledge resources. Thus, in relationto product A, ABC Corporation could supply internally all the knowledge required

    for its production. In the case of knowledge types 13 and 7 and 8, the ability to

    apply these to products BH as well, means that these types of knowledge can be

    utilized fully. But what about knowledge types 1117 that are also required to

    produce product A? Because these knowledge types can be used in only two or

    three of the other products that ABC supplies, the risk is that these knowledge

    resources will be under-utilized if ABC owns them.

    Similar issues arise when we look at the core knowledge resources that ABC

    uses to supply products AH. Knowledge types 110 could also be used in one of

    more additional products (IN). These products IN could be produced by ABC;

    however, if this was so, ABC would also need access to the additional types of

    knowledge required by these products that lie beyond the columns of our table.

    Hence, if ABC expands to include products IN, this will only exacerbate the

    problem of under-utilized knowledge resources.

    Strategic alliances can help overcome the problems of under-utilized knowledge

    arising from incongruent product and knowledge domains. If ABC can source

    knowledge types 1116 from other companies, it can avoid the excess capacityproblems of providing these knowledge inputs internally. If ABC can offer knowl-

    edge types 110 through strategic alliances with other firms that specialize in sup-

    plying products IN, it can improve the utilization of knowledge types 110.[12]

    If we overlay Figures 1a and 1b, the basic patterns of knowledge-product rela-

    tionships become clear. Figure 2 identifies four quadrants. Quadrant 1 shows inter-

    nalization: internal knowledge is used to produce goods and services within the firm.

    Quadrant 2 shows knowledge imports: products supplied by the firm using knowledge

    from outside the firm. Quadrant 3 shows opportunities for knowledge exports: knowl-

    edge within the firm, which has the potential for application to products supplied

    by other firms. Quadrant 4 is an empty zone: there is no involvement by ABC.

    The greater is the mismatch between the firms product domain and its knowl-

    edge domain, then the greater are the advantages offered by collaborative arrange-

    ments with other firms in order to (a) access and integrate knowledge that can be

    more efficiently provided by other firms (quadrant 2 of Figure 2), and (b) more

    fully utilize the firms own knowledge (quadrant 3 of Figure 2). The extent of the

    mismatch is indicated by the area of quadrants 2 and 3 relative to quadrant 1.

    This will be a positive function of the number of different types of knowledgerequired by the firms products (breadth of knowledge) and the extent of

    i f i h k l d hi h d d i l k f d

    72 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    13/25

    To summarize our central prediction:

    Proposition 2: The greater the incongruity between the product domain of the

    firm and its knowledge domain, the greater its propensity to form alliances with

    other firms. The incongruity between product and knowledge domains is a

    positive function of the breadth of knowledge required by the firms products

    and the extent of economies of scope in that knowledge.

    Illustration and evidence. Returning to our example of Eastman Kodaks adaptation

    to the digital imaging, the key impact of the digitization of imaging was to upset

    the close congruity between Kodaks product and knowledge domains. Digital

    imaging was based upon a number of areas of electronic knowledge, most of

    which including electronic sensing, image storage, file compression, internet-

    protocol file transmission, and ink-jet and laser colour printing have wide

    domains of application and are subject to substantial economies of scope. Since

    internalizing these areas of knowledge would inevitably result in substantial

    underutilization, Kodak relied primarily upon strategic alliances to access these

    areas of knowledge. Alliance partners included:

    Intel for data storage expertise first used in Picture CD and other image

    storage devices and later applied to on-line image management systems.

    Microsoft for the document and image management know-how used in

    Kodaks work management software.

    AT&T and Cisco Systems for expertise in internet-protocols and digital net-working for Kodaks online image transmission networks.

    H l P k d f h l i kj h l i i d f K d k di i l

    Strategic Alliances 73

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18

    A

    B

    C

    D

    EF

    G

    H

    I

    J

    K

    L

    M

    N

    3. Knowledge exports

    1. Internalization 2. Knowledge imports

    4. Empty zone

    Figure 2. ABC Corporations product and knowledge domains combined

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    14/25

    Lockheed Martin for know-how in integrating massive information systems

    in order to develop large scale document management systems required for

    censuses, tax returns, and the like.

    Motorola for the semiconductor manufacturing expertise required for pro-

    ducing Kodaks range of CMOS image sensors.

    At the same time, Kodak resorted to alliances in order to increase the utilization

    of its internal knowledge resources. For example:

    Kodaks knowledge of optics and lens design was shared through alliances

    with the manufacturers of telescopes and for the high resolution cameras

    required for satellite imaging systems.

    Kodak supplied digital scanning and colour management software technol-

    ogy to Heidelberger Druckmachinen AG for its range of digital colour print-

    ing presses.

    Kodaks data compression, image storage, and colour management tech-

    nologies were deployed in alliances with Hewlett-Packard, Lexmark, Canon,

    and Heidelberg.

    Kodaks long-established proprietary knowledge of CCD and CMOS image

    sensors (its first patents on single sensor colour imagers were granted in 1976)

    was supplied to a number of manufacturers of cameras and other forms of

    digital imaging equipment.

    The incidence of strategic alliances both cross-sectionally and longitudinally is

    consistent with Proposition 2. Evidence from both the MERIT-CATI database

    (Hagendoorn, 2001; Hagendoorn et al., 2000) and SDCs Joint Venture and

    Strategic Alliances Database (Schilling and Steensma, 2001) shows strategic

    alliances to be concentrated in relatively few sectors notably computers and office

    equipments, communications equipment, consumer electronics, medicines and

    pharmaceuticals, and motor vehicles. These are sectors where knowledge require-

    ments tend to be broad, and where much of the knowledge tends not to be product

    specific, hence giving rise to economies of scope. By contrast, sectors with com-

    paratively few alliances include wood and wood products, steel and non-ferrous

    metals, yarn and textiles, metal fasteners, and small tools. In these sectors knowl-

    edge requirements are narrower and the knowledge deployed tends to be com-

    paratively product specific.

    Over time (certainly since the early 1980s), the number of alliances has

    increased greatly in Europe and North America. This growth coincides with a

    broadening of the range of knowledge requirements for most goods and services,and increasing importance of knowledge that is not specific to particular products

    d di i l h l i d i

    74 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    15/25

    ALLIANCES AND DYNAMIC EFFICIENCY IN

    KNOWLEDGE APPLICATION

    Uncertainty in Knowledge-Product Linkages

    In reality, input-output relationships between knowledge and products are notstatic but dynamic: knowledge is continually being created, refined, discarded,

    and reconfigured into new products. If the firm is uncertain as to the future knowl-

    edge requirements of its current products, and if acquiring and integrating new

    knowledge takes time, its knowledge investments are risky. In these circumstances,

    interfirm alliances offer two additional benefits to those outlined above. The first

    is pure risk spreading. The second is the option value of small initial investments

    in new areas of knowledge (Kogut, 1988; Sanchez, 1993). Investments in new

    products and technologies can be segmented in time; the condition is that to invest

    in any particular phase requires that the firm invests in the prior phases. In the

    face of uncertainty, investments in early phases of a project derive the major part

    of their value from the fact that they create the options to invest in the next and

    subsequent phases (Dixit and Pindyck, 1994).[14]

    To summarize:

    Proposition 3: The greater the uncertainty as to the future knowledge require-

    ments of a firms product range, the greater its propensity to engage in inter-

    firm collaborations as a means of accessing and integrating additionalknowledge.

    Illustration and evidence. The risk spreading and option creating benefits of alliances

    are evident from the widespread propensity of firms to form alliances when faced

    with technological uncertainty. In 1988, faced with uncertainty over the future of

    microcomputer operating systems, Microsoft was investing not only in its propri-

    etary MS-DOS and Windows systems but, through alliances, was developing

    OS/2 for IBM, writing Mac applications for Apple Computer, and collaborating

    in the launch of a PC version of UNIX (Beinhocker, 2000).

    Similarly with Kodaks development of digital imaging, when faced with

    technological uncertainty Kodak used alliances to take positions in rival tech-

    nologies. For example, in sensors, Kodak, long a leader in CCD sensors, allied

    with Motorola in order to develop a range of CMOS sensors. Similarly, in man-

    aging the transition from photochemical to digital imaging, uncertainty over the

    evolutionary path has encouraged Kodak to use alliances to invest in alternative

    technologies and designs in different stages of its digital infrastructure. At the

    photofinishing stage of the value chain, Kodak has partnered with HewlettPackard (Phogenix joint venture), Noritsu, Gretag, and Photome (System 88) to

    l i di i l i il b I i h i f di i l i

    Strategic Alliances 75

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    16/25

    transmission, Kodaks initial Picture Network was soon supplemented by alliances

    with AOL (Youve Got Pictures image delivery service), PictureVision (PhotoNet),

    Fotowire.com (to link consumers to link with Kodaks retail photolabs), and

    AT&T (to develop broadband and internet protocol applications) (Eastman

    Kodak, 2001).

    Early-Mover Advantage in New Products

    In appropriating the returns to knowledge, we have noted that, in general, alliances

    are superior to market contracts but inferior to internalization within the firm.[15]

    However, where knowledge is advancing rapidly, appropriating its returns often

    depends upon achieving early-mover advantage. Such advantage derives less from

    the generation of new knowledge, as from recombining knowledge into innova-

    tory products (Fleming, 2001; Galunic and Rodan, 1998). If early-mover advan-

    tage rests upon the ability to quickly identify, access, and integrate across new

    knowledge combinations, strategic alliances can greatly increase the speed with

    which a company can access the new combinations of knowledge needed to bring

    new products to market. Hence:

    Proposition 4: The greater the benefits of early-mover advantage in technologi-

    cally-dynamic environments, the greater the propensity for firms to establish

    interfirm collaborative arrangements in order to access new knowledge.

    Illustration and evidence. Finally, Kodak has been explicit in recognizing the value of

    alliances in speeding its development and introduction of new digital imaging

    products. Fishers digital imaging strategy for the consumer market was built upon

    a flow of new digital and hybrid products that linked its well-established chemical

    imaging knowledge to the electronic hardware and imaging software expertise pos-

    sessed by existing IT companies. In establishing leadership in digital image storage

    products, Kodak has increased speed to market through alliances with Intel and

    Seagate, while relying upon a joint venture with Matsushita to provide rapid access

    to the manufacturing capacity needed for speedy market penetration. In seeking

    to gain early mover advantage in the market for sensors, Kodak has moved quickly

    from prototype to mass manufacture using the manufacturing capabilities of

    Motorola and Texas Instruments. Similarly with internet-based transmission of

    digital images, Kodak alliances with AOL, Cisco, Yahoo! and AT&T enabled

    Kodak to build a market presence faster than would be possible than by internal

    development.

    Note that Propositions 3 and 4 are complementary; if there were no early-moveradvantages in a market, then the option value of investments in knowledge-

    i lli ld b ll Wi h l d fi f d

    76 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    17/25

    DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

    The ability of the knowledge-based view of the firm to provide insight into the

    nature, formation and on-going management of interfirm alliances has been

    limited by two factors. First, lack of clear specification of the role of knowledge

    in alliance formation. Second, the widespread presumption that the purpose of

    alliances is organizational learning. This study addresses both these issues. Start-

    ing from basic principles concerning knowledge and its use in production, we have

    presented a knowledge-based analysis of interfirm alliances that distinguishes

    between the knowledge generation (exploration) and knowledge application (exploita-

    tion ) goals of alliances. This distinction corresponds to the difference between

    knowledge acquisition and knowledge accessing observed in previous studies of

    alliances. On the basis that knowledge accessing takes precedence over knowledge

    acquisition in most strategic alliances, the paper establishes the circumstances inwhich strategic alliances are more efficient than internalization within a single firm

    in integrating and utilizing knowledge. Although firms are generally superior to

    both alliances and markets in integrating knowledge to produce goods and ser-

    vices, alliances can overcome the limits of firms in encompassing highly differen-

    tiated knowledge integration processes, while offering efficiencies in knowledge

    utilization. The advantages of alliances are especially apparent under conditions

    of uncertainty and early mover advantages.

    The goal of our study has been the development of better theory concerning

    the role of alliances in the knowledge-based economy and the circumstances

    conducive to their formation. In several places in the paper we have shown where

    our propositions yield predictions that are consistent with observations of recent

    alliance activity, but we offer little in the way of new or systematic empirical evi-

    dence. Nevertheless, we contend that the illustrative examples that we offer for

    example, of Eastman Kodak, Microsoft, biotechnology, and semiconductors

    together with more general observations of trends in alliance formation over time

    and across industry sectors, points to the plausibility of our propositions. Clearly

    there is a need for systematic empirical testing directed towards discriminatingbetween alternative theories of alliances. To this end, the knowledge accessing

    theory we have developed offers predictions that can be compared with those of

    the knowledge acquisition approach. Table I summarizes these.

    The predictions of the two approaches contrast sharply with regard to the evo-

    lution of firm boundaries. The alliances-as-learning thesis predicts that the knowl-

    edge bases of alliance partners will tend to converge as each partner learns from

    the other. The alliances-as-knowledge-accessing thesis predicts that alliance part-

    ners will maintain, and possibly increase their knowledge specialization. The

    approach taken by Mowery et al. (1996, 1997, 2001) in analysing convergence and

    divergence of alliance partners knowledge bases has made progress in unravel-

    Strategic Alliances 77

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    18/25

    In terms of alliance longevity and stability, the alliances-as-learning thesis pre-

    dicts that alliances will have finite lives, their very success in learning causing their

    demise, and will be unstable as a result of competition for learning. The alliances-

    as-knowledge-accessing thesis predicts that alliances will tend to be longer-term

    and, other things remaining equal, their stability will increase rather than decline

    with time.

    The approaches also have differing predictions about a firms potential for man-

    aging multiple alliances. If alliances are about acquiring knowledge, then each

    firms number of alliances will be limited by its absorptive capacity. Conversely,

    knowledge accessing alliances would permit a firm to engage in extensive networks

    of alliances.

    In terms of the external factors conducive to alliances, the greater is the rate of

    change of knowledge and uncertainty over future changes, then the greater the

    risk spreading and option values of alliances under the knowledge accessing

    approach. However, there is no reason to suppose that the value of learning

    increases under such circumstances; indeed, uncertainty might discourage invest-

    ments in learning.On the empirical front, our theory appears to have the potential to explain a

    b f b d h i l di h d d i i b

    78 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

    Table I. Contrasting the predictions of knowledge-accessing and knowledge acquisition theories of

    interfirm alliances

    Knowledge accessing approach Knowledge acquisition approach

    Development of the alliance Alliances increase knowledge Alliances cause broadening ofpartners knowledge bases specialization each firms knowledge base

    Partners knowledge bases Partners knowledge bases

    remain differentiated converge over time

    Stability of alliances If successful, alliances become As each partner absorbs

    increasingly stable over time knowledge from the other,

    alliances become less stable

    Longevity of alliances Can be long term Life span limited to the time it

    takes to acquire partners

    knowledge

    Numbers of alliances A firm can engage in multiple Limited absorptive capacityalliances simultaneously implies a limit to the number

    without sharply declining of alliances a firm can

    marginal benefit pursue simultaneously

    Impact of uncertainty over Increases the value of alliances No substantial increase in the

    future links between substantially value of alliances

    knowledge inputs and

    product outputs

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    19/25

    alliances. There is a particular need for empirical tests capable of discriminating

    more precisely between the proposed knowledge-accessing view of alliances and

    the alternative organizational learning view.

    Clearly there is a need for further theoretical development. The dichotomy

    between knowledge accessing and knowledge acquisition in strategic alliancesis not clear-cut and requires further clarification. To integrate separate areas of

    specialist knowledge, there needs to be some intersection of the separate knowl-

    edge sets in the form of common knowledge (Grant, 1996, pp. 11516). In addi-

    tion, this integration may require a distinct level of architectural knowledge

    (Henderson and Clark, 1990). Prencipe and Brusconis research into aero engines

    and other complex production systems identifies the critical importance of over-

    laps between partners knowledge bases, particularly where the firm acts as overall

    knowledge integrator (Brusoni and Prencipe, 2001; Brusoni et al., 2001; Prencipe,

    1997). This need of knowledge duplication between alliance partners means that

    a key issue for the efficiency of alliances relative to individual firms is the amount

    of common knowledge required for effective knowledge integration.

    This role of common knowledge is one among a broader set of issues con-

    cerning knowledge integration in the development and production of goods and

    services. It is clear that a knowledge-based approach to economic organization can

    enrich and extend transaction cost explanations of optimal modes of organiza-

    tion. The knowledge-based approach also links with other research streams in the

    alliance literature: the emphasis on co-ordination links with social network theory(e.g. Axelrod, 1984; Gulati, 1995; Hakansson and Johansson, 1992), and the

    knowledge-accessing role of alliances ties in with resource-dependence theory (e.g.

    Barley et al., 1992; Van de Ven, 1976). At the same time there is considerable

    scope for refining and extending our bare bones analysis. If knowledge is the most

    important resource of firms and if the primary task of production is to integrate

    a broad range of knowledge, we need to understand better the organizational

    processes to achieve this. Such extensions are important if we are to develop

    normative recommendations for the selection, design and on-going management

    of strategic alliances from our positive analysis.

    NOTES

    [1] Oxley (1997) presents a sequence of alliance types arranged from the least hierarchical (uni-lateral contractual agreements) to the most hierarchical (equity-based alliances).

    [2] Evidence on the growth of alliances over time and their sectoral distribution is available in theCooperative Agreements and Technology Indicators (CATI) database (Hagedoorn et al., 2000),the National Science Foundations CORE database (Link, 1996) and Securities DataCompanys Joint Venture and Strategic Alliances Database.

    [3] Other studies, notably Khanna et al. (1998) and Das and Teng (2000) point to the coexistenceof both cooperative (i.e. mutual knowledge accessing) and competitive (i.e. learning races)among alliance partners

    Strategic Alliances 79

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    20/25

    [5] The evidence is fragmented yet overwhelming. For a knowledge-based company such as CiscoSystems, tangible assets account for less than 4 per cent of the companys market value.Skandia, the Swedish insurance company, estimates that despite its huge financial assets, theseare greatly outweighed by knowledge capital (Edvinsson and Malone, 1997). In terms ofemployee remuneration, the fivefold difference in average earnings between unskilled workersand higher degree holders within the USA is indicative that knowledge is the primary deter-

    minant of income from employment.[6] Connor and Prahalad (1996) use the term knowledge substitution to describe the process of

    direction of an employee by a superior in the hierarchy. In practice, such direction is not simplya case of substituting the superiors knowledge for that of the subordinate. The essence of direc-tion is that it permits different individuals specialist knowledge to be integrated. Thus, the com-puter technician can give directions to the CEO as to what do in when a virus infects hiscomputer hard disk.

    [7] Patent and copyright law does establish property rights in some forms of knowledge, but typi-cally only a small fraction of the knowledge used by firms is protected.

    [8] A further advantage of firms is in overcoming the problems of metering and shirking whichteam-based cooperation gives rise to (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972).

    [9] Lloyds of London, the international insurance market, has well-established routines, many of

    which can be traced back to Lloyds origins as a seventeenth-century coffee house. Lloyds prob-lems of the late 1980s and early 1990s can be attributed, in part, to failure of these routinesto adapt and to the inefficiency of these routines in integrating information and know-how.

    [10] The presence of common production processes and dominant designs within a sector can assistthe establishment of organizational routines within between cooperating firms. More gener-ally, the presence of an institutional field within which members are located will assist thesocial processes that constitute collaboration (Phillips et al., 2000).

    [11] The problem is well known in the technology management field; both Boeing and Xerox haveexamined the problem of defining optimal technology portfolios in the face of complementary,overlapping development projects (Dickinson et al., 2001; Loutfy and Belkhir, 2001).

    [12] This analysis does not take account of Henderson and Clarks (1990) distinction between com-ponent knowledge and architectural knowledge. Busoni and Prencipe (2001) show that, once

    firms collaborate with one another in loosely-coupled networks, then the firm that acts as thesystems integrator within the network must maintain the architectural knowledge needed foroverall product integration and design.

    [13] This framework showing internal and external exploitation of knowledge bears some similar-ities to that developed by Teece (1986) which identifies the conditions under which new tech-nologies are best exploited internally or through contract. However, any similarities are onlysuperficial. The Teece framework explores conditions for appropriating the returns to innova-tions where the central issue is the extent to which the innovation is protected by intellectualproperty rights.

    [14] It is worth noting that the option value of strategic alliances is greater within our knowledge-accessing model than in the alternative knowledge acquisition model, because the cost of takingand exercising the option is much higher if the purpose of the alliance is learning as opposedto knowledge accessing.

    [15] A key exception to this generalization is where knowledge is protected by intellectual propertyrights; in such cases, market contacts (i.e. licensing) can be effective in appropriating the returnsto knowledge (Teece, 1986).

    REFERENCES

    Alchian, A. A. and Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organisation.American Economic Review, 62, 77795.

    Almeida, P., Grant, R. M. and Song, J. (1998). Firms, markets, and alliances in cross-border knowl-

    edge transfer: the case of semiconductors. In Hitt, M. A. (Ed.),Managing Strategically in an Inter-connected World. New York: Wiley.Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In National

    80 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    21/25

    Axelrod, R. (1984). The Evolution of Co-operation. New York: Basic Books.Barley, S. R., Freeman, J. and Hybels, R. C. (1992). Strategic alliances in commercial biotechnol-

    ogy. In Nohria, N. and Eccles, R. (Eds),Networks and Organizations. Cambridge, MA: HarvardUniversity Press, 31147.

    Beinhocker, E. D. (2000). On the origin of strategies. On Strategy. McKinsey Quarterly Anthologies,16776.

    Borys, B. and Jemison, D. B. (1989). Hybrid arrangements as strategic alliances: theoretical issuesin organizational combinations.Academy of Management Review, 14, 23449.

    Busoni, S. and Prencipe, A. (2001). Exploring the links between product and knowledge dynamics.Journal of Management Studies, 38, 101935.

    Busoni, S., Prencipe, A. and Pavitt, K. (2001). Knowledge specialization, organizational coupling,and the boundaries of the firm: why do firms know more than they make?.Administrative ScienceQuarterly, 46, 1185200.

    Ciborra, C. (1991). Alliances as learning experiments: co-operation, competition and change in high-tech industries. In Mytelka, L. K. (Ed.), Strategic Partnerships and the World Economy. London:Printer, 5177.

    Connor, K. R. and Prahalad, C. K. (1996). A resource-based theory of the firm: knowledge versusopportunism. Organisation Science, 7, 477501.

    Das, T. K. and Teng, B.-S. (2000). Instabilities of strategic alliances: an internal tensions perspec-tive. Organisation Science, 11, 77101

    Demsetz, H. (1991). The theory of the firm revisited. The Nature of the Firm. New York: OxfordUniversity Press, 15978.

    Dickinson, M. W., Thornton A. C. and Graves, S. (2001). Technology portfolio management:optimizing interdependent projects over multiple time periods. IEEE Transactions on EngineeringManagement, 48, 4, 51827.

    Dickson, P. H. and Weaver, K. M. (1997). Environmental determinants and individual-levelmoderators of alliance use.Academy of Management Journal, 40, 40425.

    Dixit, A. and Pindyck, L. (1994). Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Dodgson, M. (1992). The strategic management of R&D collaboration. Technology Analysis and

    Strategic Management, 4, 3, 22744.Doz, Y. (1988). Technology partnerships between larger and smaller firms. International Studies of

    Management and Organisation, 17, 4, 3157.Dyer, J. H. and Nobeoka, K. (2000). Creating and managing a high performance knowledge-sharing

    network: the Toyota case. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 34567.Eastman Kodak Company (2001). Kodakdelivers on a digital infrastructure to drive greater prof-

    itability for the entire industry. Press release, Orlando, FL, 11 Feb.Edvinsson, L. and Malone, M. S. (1997). Intellectual Capital: Realizing Your Companys True Value by Finding

    Its Hidden Brainpower. New York: HarperBusiness.Eisenhardt, K. M. and Schoonhoven, C. B. (1996). Resource-based view of strategic alliance

    formation: strategic and social effects in entrepreneurial firms. Organization Science, 7, 2, 13650.Fisher, G. M. C. (1998). Press Briefing Eastman Kodak Company, 1 May.Fleming, L. (2001). Recombinant uncertainty in technological search. Management Science, 47,

    11732.Galunic, D. C. and Rodan, S. (1998). Resource recombination in the firm: knowledge structures

    and the potential for Schumpeterian innovation. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 1193201.Grant, R. M. (1996). Prospering in dynamically-competitive environments: organisational capabil-

    ity as knowledge integration. Organisation Science, 7, 4, 37587.Grant, R. M. and Neupert, K. E. (2003). Eastman Kodak: meeting the digital challenge. In Cases

    in Contemporary Strategy Analysis, 3rd edition. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, 98121.Guetzkow, H. (1966). Relations among organizations. In Bowers, R. V. (Ed.), Studies in Behavior in

    Organizations. Athens, GA: University of Georgia Press, 1344.Gulati, R. (1995). Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual

    choice in alliances.Academy of Management Journal, 38, 85112.

    Gulati, R. (1999). Network location and learning: the influence of network resources and firmcapabilities on alliance formation. Strategic Management Journal, 20, 397420.Hagedoorn, J. (1993). Understanding the rationale for strategic technology partnering: interorgani-

    i l d l f i d l diff S i M J l 14

    Strategic Alliances 81

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    22/25

    Hagedoorn, J. (2001). Firm R&D partnership an overview of major trends and patterns since1960. Strategic Research Partnerships: Proceedings from an NSF Workshop, National ScienceFoundation, Washington, DC (http://www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs/nsf01336/start.ht m).

    Hagedoorn, J., Link, A. N. and Vonortes, N. S. (2000). Research partnerships. Research Policy, 29,56786.

    Hakansson, H. and Johansson, J. (1992). Formal and informal co-operation strategies in interna-

    tional industrial networks. In Contractor, F. J. and Lorange, P. (Eds), Cooperative Strategies in Inter-national Business. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

    Hall, R. H. (Ed.) (1972). The Formal Organisation. New York: Basic Books.Hamel, G. (1991). Competition for competence and interpartner learning within international

    strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 12, Summer Special Issue, 83103.Henderson, R. M. and Clark, K. B. (1990). Architectural innovation: the reconfiguration of exist-

    ing product technologies and the failure of established firms.Administrative Science Quarterly, 35,930.

    Hennart, J.-F. (1988). A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal,9, 36174.

    Hurry, D. (1993). Restructuring in the global economy: the consequences of strategic linkagesbetween Japanese and U.S. firms. Strategic Management Journal, 14, Summer Special Issue,

    6982.Inkpen, A. C. (1998). Learning and knowledge acquisition through international strategic alliances.

    Academy of Management Executive, 12, 4, 6980.Inkpen, A. C. and Beamish, P. W. (1997). Knowledge, bargaining power, and the instability of inter-

    national joint ventures.Academy of Management Review, 22, 177202.Inkpen, A. C. and Crossan, M. M. (1995). Believing is seeing: joint ventures and organisational

    learning.Journal of Management Studies, 32, 595618.Kale, P., Singh, H. and Perlmutter, H. (2000). Learning and protection of proprietary assets in stra-

    tegic alliances: building relational capital. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 21737.Katz, M. L. (1986). An analysis of cooperative research and development. Rand Journal of Econom-

    ics, 17, 52743.Khanna, T. (1998). The scope of strategic alliances. Organization Science, 9, 34055.Khanna, T., Gulati, R. and Nohria, N. (1998). The dynamics of learning alliances: competition,

    cooperation and relative scope. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 193210.Kogut, B. (1988). Joint ventures: theoretical and empirical perspectives. Strategic Management Journal,

    9, 31932.Kogut, B. (1991). Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire. Management Science, 37,

    1933.Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1992). Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the repli-

    cation of technology. Organisation Science, 3, 38397.Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1996). What firms do: coordination, identity, and learning. Organization

    Science, 7, 50218.Larsson, R., Bengtsson, L., Hendricksson, K. and Sparks, J. (1998). The interorganizational learn-

    ing dilemma: collective knowledge development in strategic alliances. Organisation Science, 9,28596.

    Liebeskind, J. (1996). Knowledge, strategy, and the theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal,17, Winter Special Issue, 93108.

    Link, A. N. (1996). Research joint ventures: patterns from Federal Registerfilings. Review of IndustrialOrganisation, 11, 61728.

    Lorenzoni, G. and Baden-Fuller, C. (1994). Creating a strategic centre to manage a web of part-ners. California Management Review, 37, 3, 14663.

    Loutfy, R. and Belkhir, L. (2001). Managing innovation at Xerox. Research Technology Management,44, 4, 1524.

    Lyles, M. A. (1988). Learning among joint-venture sophisticated firms. Management InternationalReview, 28, Special Issue, 8598.

    Macher, J. T. (2001). Vertical Disintegration and Process Innovation in SemiconductorManufacturing: Foundries vs. Integrated Producers. Georgetown University Working Paper.Washington, DC.

    M hl F M ( ) K l d I C i Di ib i d E i Si ifi P i NJ

    82 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

    http://www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs/nsf01336/start.htmhttp://www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs/nsf01336/start.htm
  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    23/25

    March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2,1, 7187.

    March, J. G. and Simon, H. A. (1957). Organisation. New York: Wiley.Mody, A. (1993). Learning through alliances. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 20,

    15170.Mowery, D. C., Oxley, J. E. and Silverman, B. S. (1996). Strategic alliances and interfirm knowl-

    edge transfer. Strategic Management Journal, 17, Winter special issue, 7793.Mowery, D. C., Oxley, J. E. and Silverman, B. S. (1997). Technological overlap and interfirm co-

    operation: implications of the resource-based view of the firm. Research Policy, 26, 42138.Mowery, D. C., Oxley, J. E. and Silverman, B. S. (2001). The Two Faces of Partner-Specific Absorp-

    tive Capacity: Learning and Cospecializing in Strategic Alliances. Discussion Paper 01-064.Boston, MA: Harvard Business School, Division of Research.

    Nakamura, M., Shaver, J. M. and Yeung, B. (1996). An empirical investigation of joint venturedynamics.Journal of Industrial Organization, 14, 52141.

    Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1982).An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Balkan.Nonaka, I. (1994). A dynamic theory of organizational knowledge creation. Organization Science, 5,

    1437.Nooteboom, B. (1996). Transaction costs and technological learning. In Groenewegen, J. (Ed.),

    Transaction Cost Economics and Beyond. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 32750.Oxley, J. E. (1997). Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: a transaction cost

    approach. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 13, 389407.Pavarotti, L. (1998). Pavarotti and Friends: for the children of Liberia. (Compact Disc),

    Uni/London Classics.Penrose, E. (1959). Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Oxford: Blackwell.Pfeffer, J. and Salancik, G. R. (1978). The External Control of Organisations: A Resource Dependence

    Perspective. New York: Harper & Row.Phillips, N., Lawrence, T. B. and Hardy, C. (2000). Interorganizational collaboration and the dynam-

    ics of institutional fields.Journal of Management Studies, 37, 2343.Pinto, J. (2000). Product development speed in the internet age. Controls Intelligence and Plant System

    Report, June, pp. 45.

    Powell, W. W. (1987). Hybrid organizational arrangements. California Management Review, 30, 1,6787.

    Powell, W. W. (1998). Learning from collaboration: knowledge and networks in the biotechnologyad pharmaceutical industries. California Management Review, 40, 3, 22840.

    Prencipe, A. (1997). Technical competencies and products evolutionary dynamics: a case study fromthe aero engine industry. Research Policy, 25, 126176.

    Quinn, J. B. (1992). Intelligent Enterprise. New York: Free Press.Ring, P. S. and van de Ven, A. H. (1992). Structuring cooperative relationships between organiza-

    tions. Strategic Management Journal, 13, 48398.Rotemberg, J. J. and Saloner, G. (1991). Interfirm competition and collaboration. In Scott Morton,

    M. S. (Ed.), Corporation of the 1990s: Information Technology and Organizational Transformation. NewYork: Oxford University Press, 93121.

    Rothaermel, F. T. (2001). Incumbents advantage through exploiting complementary assets via inter-firm cooperation. Strategic Management Journal, 22, Summer special issue, 68799.

    Sanchez, R. (1993). Strategic flexibility, firm organisation, and managerial work in dynamic markets:a strategic options perspective.Advances in Strategic Management, 9, 25191.

    Sanchez, R. and Mahoney, J. T. (1996). Modularity, flexibility, and knowledge management inproduct and organisation design. Strategic Management Journal, 17, Winter special issue, 6376.

    Schwartz, M. (1987). The competitive effects of vertical agreements: comments.American EconomicReview, 77, 10638.

    Schilling, M. A. and Steensma, H. K. (2001). The use of modular organizational forms: anindustry-level analysis.Academy of Management Journal, 44, 114968.

    Shapiro, C. and Varian, H. R. (1999). Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Boston,

    MA: Harvard Business School Press.Simon, H. A. (1962). The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society,106, 46782.

    Si H A ( ) B d d i li d i i l l i O i i S i 2

    Strategic Alliances 83

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    24/25

    Simonin, B. L. (1997). The importance of collaborative know-how: an empirical test of the learn-ing organisation.Academy of Management Journal, 40, 115074.

    Simonin, B. L. (1999). Ambiguity and the process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances. Strate-gic Management Journal, 20, 595623.

    Spender, J.-C. (1992). Limits to learning from the west. The International Executive, 34, Septem-ber/October, 389410.

    Stocking, G. W. and Watkins, M. W. (1946). Cartels in Action. New York: 20th Century Fund.Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collabora-

    tion, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15, 285305.Teece, D. J. (1992). Competition, co-operation, and innovation. Journal of Economic Behavior and

    Organisation, 18, 125.Thompson, J. D. (1967). Organizations in Action. New York: McGraw Hill.Thorelli, H. B. (1986). Networks: between markets and hierarchies. Strategic Management Journal, 7,

    3751. van de Ven, A. H. (1976). On the nature, formation, and maintenance of relations between

    organizations.Academy of Management Review, 1, 4, 2436. van de Ven, A. H. and Walker, G. (1984). The dynamics of interorganizational coordination.

    Administrative Science Quarterly, 29, 598621.

    Weick, K. E. (1976). Educational organizations as loosely-coupled systems. Administrative ScienceQuarterly, 21, 119.

    Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative economic organisation: the analysis of discrete structuralalternatives.Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 26996.

    Winter, S. G. (1995). Four Rs of profitability: rents, resources, routines, and replication. InMontgomery, C. (Ed.), Resource-based and Evolutionary Theories of the Firm: Towards a Synthesis.Hinham, MA: Kluwer, 14777.

    84 R. M. Grant and C. Baden-Fuller

  • 8/8/2019 A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliance_pdf1_2

    25/25