2949313 mercado

download 2949313 mercado

of 17

Transcript of 2949313 mercado

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    1/17

    Anthropological Studies of Cities

    Author(s): Richard E. BlantonReviewed work(s):Source: Annual Review of Anthropology, Vol. 5 (1976), pp. 249-264Published by: Annual ReviewsStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2949313.

    Accessed: 01/02/2012 13:00

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    Annual Reviewsis collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access toAnnual Review of

    Anthropology.

    http://www.jstor.org

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=annrevshttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2949313?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2949313?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=annrevs
  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    2/17

    Ann.

    Rev.

    AnthropoL

    1976. 5:249-64

    Copyright ?

    1976

    by

    Annual Reviews Inc. All

    rights

    reserved

    ANTHROPOLOGICAL STUDIES

    *

    9579

    OF

    CITIES

    Richard E. Blanton

    Departmentof Sociology and Anthropology,Purdue

    University,

    West Lafayette, Indiana47907

    INTRODUCTION

    In this paper I will review and expand upon a theoretical and methodological

    approach

    to

    the study of cities that, in my view, has been unduly neglected by

    anthropologists interested

    in

    cities. This approach, usually referred to as

    re-

    gional analysis, is based on the central place theory of geography.

    I

    believe

    that

    we need to

    expand our theoretical horizons because traditional theories

    of cities

    utilized by anthropologists are both misleading and limited in scope. In order

    to

    demonstrate the value

    of

    a regional approach to studies of cities,

    I

    will

    first

    critically (and very briefly) review traditional theories

    of

    cities,

    then offer

    a

    regionally based definition of cities and explore some of the implications

    of the

    regional approach for explaining the cross-cultural variability

    and

    dynamic

    features of

    cities and systems

    of

    cities.

    Perhaps the most prominent feature of traditional theories

    is that

    they regard

    cities as the sources

    of

    social

    change-they

    are

    a kind of

    special environment,

    almost

    with a

    life of their own.

    These city-centric

    theories

    have been based

    on

    Durkheim's

    The Division of Labor in Society (who,

    in

    turn,

    was influenced

    by

    Spencer's Principles of Sociology),

    on the

    sociology

    of

    George Simmel,

    and the

    philosophy

    of

    Oswald Spengler. Martindale (32)

    has

    written a

    convenient review

    of the development of these theories, which he refers to as socio-psy-

    chological

    theories

    of cities.

    Hauser

    (19),

    for

    example, following

    Durkheim

    and

    Spencer,

    writes that

    .

    . .

    aggregative living

    has

    produced

    in the

    social

    realm

    a

    major transformation

    the

    equivalent

    of

    genetic

    mutation

    in

    the

    biological

    realm. Park,

    in

    the

    classic statement

    of the

    Chicago

    School

    of

    urban

    sociology (38), described

    the

    city as a psychophysical mechanism ;

    Wirth

    (59),

    in

    the same volume, writes ofthe city that

    its . . .

    growth

    is

    so

    rapid

    and its

    energy

    so

    great

    that

    it

    changes

    its

    complexion

    almost

    daily, and,

    with

    it,

    the

    character

    of

    mankind

    itself'

    (see also 60).

    As

    proposed by

    Redfield &

    Singer

    (42),

    the

    city,

    whether the

    center of orthogenetic change ( .

    .

    .

    carrying

    forward into systematic and reflective dimensions an old culture ) or hetero-

    genetic change

    ( .

    . .

    creating of original

    modes

    of thought

    that have

    authority

    beyond

    or

    in

    conflict

    with old

    cultures and civilizations ),

    is

    . . .

    a place

    in

    which culture

    change takes place (42, p. 58).

    249

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    3/17

    250 BLANTON

    Robert Redfield's famous Folk-Urban Continuum (41)

    was developed

    under the influence of the Chicago School. This proved

    to be the focus

    of

    anthropological theorizing about

    cities for years, until gradually

    the work of a

    number of people (too numerous to review completely here) demonstrated that

    not only could the Folk-Urban Continuum not be attributed

    the status

    of

    theory, but that it could not even stand as an adequate empirical

    generalization

    (cf Hauser 20; Lewis 28, 29).

    In spite of the serious criticisms which have been leveled at the

    Simmel-Wirth-

    Redfield trio, there is no shortage of socio-psychological theories

    of cities in

    the more recent literature in anthropology and its sister disciplines.

    Friedmann

    (15) writes that cities are

    . . . an active force in the ongoing processes of social

    transformation, and, according to Epstein (13), most urban

    anthropologists

    in

    Africa assume that . . . towns inevitably act as instruments of social trans-

    formation (see also Jacobs 22 and Moore 37). Although many

    criticisms could

    be made of these traditional ways of looking at cities, the major

    objections,

    as

    I

    see

    them,

    are:

    (a)

    If

    urbanism

    is regarded as a way of life, how can one account

    for the cross-cultural and diachronic variability

    in

    cities and

    in the

    ways

    of life

    within

    cities?

    The

    attempt

    by Redfield & Singer (42) to differentiate between

    cities which are the centers of orthogenetic or heterogenetic

    change by

    no

    means does justice to the wide variety

    in

    kinds and

    functions of cities. (b)

    As

    stated

    by

    Lewis

    (28, p. 432),

    the

    . . .

    folk-urban

    conceptualization

    of social

    change

    focuses attention

    primarily

    on

    the

    city

    as the source

    of

    change,

    to the

    exclusion or neglect of other factors of an internal or external nature. The folk-

    urban continuum fails to aid

    our understanding of the rates of social change,

    or

    when and where

    change

    is likely or not likely to occur.

    In

    the remainder of this paper

    I will attempt to demonstrate that a regional

    theory of cities,

    in

    contrast

    with socio-psychological theories,

    is explicitly

    oriented to

    provide explanations

    for the cross-cultural differences

    in

    cities,

    while avoiding the fallacy of overemphasizing the role of cities

    in

    social change.

    CITIES DEFINED

    I

    will assiduously avoid the use of the terms urban and urbanism,

    for although

    both these terms have

    something

    to do with

    cities,

    no two researchers

    agree

    on

    what the association is. Similarly, much

    ink

    has been spilled

    by scholars

    over

    what cities are and what

    they

    are not, without, to date, a satisfactory

    resolution

    of

    the definitional

    problem.

    Instead of reviewing this

    bulky and frustrating

    literature

    here,

    I

    refer the

    reader to two useful summaries by

    Paul

    Wheatley (57,

    pp. 371-99; 58).

    Perhaps

    the

    greatest obstacle

    in the definition of cities- as

    a special type

    of

    human community has been the establishment of a set of indispensable criteria

    which can be

    applied

    cross-culturally.

    In the

    most widely

    read

    work on

    pre-

    industrial cities

    (Sjoberg 47),

    for

    example, it is argued that

    the presence

    of a

    literate elite is the

    single best criterion to distinguish cities

    from other types

    of

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    4/17

    STUDIES OF CITIES 251

    early settlements, clearly a cross-cultural error

    of

    no

    small magnitude. Wheatley

    (56) suggests that these definitional problems could

    be resolved

    by

    the use of his

    concept of ethnocity. Here attention is paid

    to . . . nodes of

    concentration

    of people and shelters

    in

    the continuum

    of

    population

    distribution over the face

    of the earth. Such of these as attain

    a

    certain size

    and perform appropriate

    functions are designated

    by the terms appositely translated

    in

    English

    as

    'city'

    or

    'town'. ..

    .

    These nodes

    are induced by forces operating within,

    and

    sometimes

    peculiar to,

    the

    specific culture (56, pp.

    166-67).

    This approach

    is

    desirable

    because it avoids the necessity for discovering indispensable

    criteria,

    and in-

    stead focuses on the hierarchy of central places

    in a society.

    Such a functional definition of cities emphasizes the disposition

    in

    space

    of

    what might be called

    central institutions-institutions that mediate between

    specialized subsystems within a society. In order to optimally service a popu-

    lation, these central institutions

    are not likely to be randomly dispersed

    over

    the

    landscape. Instead,

    they will tend to occur clustered

    in places

    that become

    the

    central places of the society, or, in other words, the

    cities

    and towns. Cities

    (and

    towns) then are a product

    of the process called segregation,

    one of

    the

    two

    basic

    cultural evolutionary processes

    described by Flannery (14). Segregation, ac-

    cording

    to

    Flannery,

    has to do with

    .

    . .

    the amount of internal differentiation

    and

    specialization

    of

    subsystems

    .

    . .

    (The

    other

    basic evolutionary process

    described by Flannery,

    centralization, refers to the

    .

    . .

    degree of linkage

    between

    the

    various sub-systems

    and the highest-order

    controls in the society

    ',

    and is less relevant to the discussion at hand). In the present context,

    segregation refers

    to

    the

    extent to which households or groups

    of households are

    independent-in more evolved systems they are less

    independent, necessitating

    various kinds of linkages in the society between specialized

    subsystems. Link-

    ages between specialized

    subsystems may take the form of transactions

    in

    the

    context of

    central institutions. Chieftainships, governments,

    and markets are

    examples

    of such

    central

    institutions.

    The

    general

    description

    of

    central institu-

    tions is that

    they

    link

    specialized subsystems by

    the conversion of inputs to

    outputs via a set of transactions

    (cf Meier 34). The kinds of inputs and outputs

    vary-markets involve mostly material inputs and outputs, while governments

    more often convert information inputs to outputs

    in the form of directives.

    For

    our

    purposes here,

    the most salient characteristics of central institutions

    are

    that

    they require

    energy to function, and that the transactions take time.

    Energy is supplied by subsystems of producers,

    who must work more than

    would

    be

    necessary

    in the absence of such institutions. The fact that there

    is

    always

    a

    finite amount of energy in the environment

    of any society, and

    that

    producers can be pushed or otherwise encouraged

    to produce only so much

    surplus, means

    that

    central institutions always have

    a maximum size and

    are

    always

    limited

    to

    a finite number of

    transactions per

    unit of time. These energy-

    related limitations can be circumvented by technological or organizational

    changes

    that

    bring

    energy savings or increase the society's ability

    to

    capture

    energy

    from its

    environment,

    but new

    limits

    will

    be reached

    if

    central

    institutions

    continue to

    grow.

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    5/17

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    6/17

    STUDIES

    OF CITIES 253

    population

    size of

    central places,

    as geographers

    have shown (e.g.

    Gun-

    awardena 16, Stafford

    53)

    will tend to vary depending

    on the number

    of central

    place functions

    present. In a society

    with a hierarchy of central places, cities

    are

    those communities in the highest range of the hierarchy, while towns are those

    communities

    occupying the middle and

    lower ranges of the hierarchy.

    Where the

    researcher draws

    the boundary between what are called

    cities and what are

    called

    towns is

    always arbitrary and

    will

    vary

    from society to society.

    The regional approach

    to the definition

    of cities is not peculiar to Wheatley,

    myself, or others

    who have borrowed

    from central place studies in geography.

    Wolf

    (61),

    for

    example, has written that the city is

    . . .

    a

    settlement

    in which a

    combination of functions are exercized, and which becomes

    useful because

    in

    time greater efficiency

    is obtained by

    having these functions concentrated

    in

    one

    site. And, according to Arensberg (3), the city . . . is a permanently massed,

    large concentration of people in a community

    having nodal

    function or func-

    tions, somehow

    providing

    for

    the lacing

    together (not necessarily

    the sub-

    ordination)

    of some hinterland of the

    other, perhaps lesser

    communities

    of a

    society. My

    only complaint

    with Arensberg's definition

    is

    that it

    includes

    the

    caveat that a city must have a large

    and massed concentration

    of

    people.

    This begs the question of how large is

    large enough, and how

    massed is massed

    enough

    for a

    community

    to be

    called

    a city.

    The

    advantage

    of the

    functional

    definition of cities

    I

    presented above

    is that any community

    that is a

    central

    place

    is a city or town

    (depending on its place in the central place

    hierarchy

    of the

    society), irrespective of its form or population size. Central places in societies

    smaller

    and

    less

    segregated than our

    own may lack large

    or massed

    central

    places,

    but

    they

    still have what Arensberg

    refers to as

    nodal

    functions,

    and so

    should be referred to as

    cities and

    towns.

    I

    should point

    out in concluding this

    section that while I have borrowed from

    central

    place

    studies

    in

    geography

    in

    developing this definition

    of cities,

    I

    have

    tried to word it to avoid the overemphasis

    on the movement

    of goods through

    systems, or,

    in other

    words,

    the economic functions of central places that,

    in

    my

    opinion,

    characterize this field (cf

    Haggett 17). Part of Christaller's original

    work on the

    geometry

    of

    central place systems

    had to

    do with what he

    called

    the

    administrative

    or K=7

    principle

    (10), which

    I

    will

    discuss

    in

    more detail

    below. Unfortunately, more recent

    work

    by geographers

    has

    dealt

    almost ex-

    clusively

    with the

    marketing

    and

    transport principles,

    both concerned

    with

    tertiary

    economic functions. The kinds of transactions

    I

    am

    referring

    to

    in

    the context of central institutions involve

    the movement of goods and/or

    infor-

    mation. The overemphasis

    on economic functions of central

    places has led,

    in

    my view, to some

    confusion in the literature. Coe (11), for

    example, wrote that

    interior Cambodian

    and lowland Classic

    Maya civilizations had no true

    cities. His

    argument

    is that

    since

    both geographic areas lacked

    environmental

    diversity it is not likely that there was regional economic specialization and

    trade, and therefore both areas lacked

    cities. This is not

    only overly environ-

    mentally deterministic

    (since he has almost no direct archaeological

    evidence

    for

    the lack of

    specialization

    and trade),

    but it also overlooks the fact that there were

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    7/17

    254

    BLANTON

    obviously central places,

    manifested

    as large groupings

    of

    civic-ceremonial

    buildings and

    palaces. Even if it were

    true that

    these were not economic

    centers,

    they were clearly centers

    of information

    processing and so should be referred to

    as cities as defined above. Donna Taylor (54) has demonstrated for a group of

    East African middle

    range

    hierarchical societies a . . .

    close

    positive re-

    lationship between

    settlement

    hierarchy and

    political-jurisdictional

    hierarchy

    and

    that

    . . .

    in hierarchical

    societies the relative

    size of the

    centers of

    higher rank is

    closely

    related to the extent of

    centralization in

    decision-pro-

    cessing (54, p. 13).

    Interestingly, this

    set of East African

    chiefdoms and simple

    states, unlike those

    portrayed in the generalized

    descriptions

    of societies

    of

    this

    type

    by

    Service (46) and Sahlins

    (44), .

    . .

    were not typically redistributive

    societies.

    .

    .

    .

    Local

    groups tended

    to be largely

    self-sufficient in material ...

    needs, and the organized collection and redistribution of regional production

    specialties

    is

    described for only one

    of the most centrally

    organized

    societies

    examined

    (54, p. 81).

    From the same

    perspective I must

    add a criticism to

    Wheatley's

    contention

    that

    the

    early

    cult

    centers

    (as

    he calls

    them)

    that

    evolved

    in

    regions of

    primary state

    formation were centers of

    redistribution

    (57,

    p. 389). The

    presence or

    absence of redistribution

    in ancient

    central places must

    always

    remain

    hypothetical until

    demonstrated by

    direct archaeological

    evidence.

    In

    the next section I

    will explore

    some of the

    interrelationships

    between

    information

    processing

    central place

    hierarchies and

    economic central place

    hierarchies. This point of view, I argue, will contribute to an understanding of

    the nature and

    dynamic properties of

    systems of

    cities and towns.

    THE

    LOCATIONAL

    PATTERNS

    Anthropologists interested

    in

    the application of

    central place

    theory to problems

    in

    peasant

    marketing systems have found

    Christaller's (10) original

    formulation

    most applicable

    (cf

    Crissman 12, Hodder &

    Hassall 21, Johnson 24,

    Skinner 48,

    and

    Smith

    52).

    According

    to

    some

    geographers (cf

    5), the transformations

    of the

    Christallerian model

    proposed by Losch

    (30)

    may prove

    to

    be

    a

    more

    accurate

    representation of reality for

    modern

    industrialized

    societies, but there

    is

    no

    concensus

    on

    this

    point.

    For

    these

    reasons,

    and because

    Losch

    was

    relatively

    less

    interested

    in

    administrative

    location,

    I will

    also depend

    here

    primarily

    on

    Christaller's

    formulation.

    Rather

    than

    repeat

    the

    assumptions

    and

    geometric

    properties of the

    Christallerian model, I

    refer the reader to a recent

    synthesis

    by

    Smith

    (5 1).

    The

    major difference

    between Christaller's two

    economically

    relevant

    lo-

    cational

    principles (the

    K=3

    marketing principle,

    and

    the

    K=4

    transport

    principle) on the

    one hand, and the

    K=7

    administrative principle

    on

    the other

    hand, has to do with the extent to which competition can occur between centers

    of

    the same level

    in

    the

    hierarchy. (The

    K

    numbers

    refer to the ratio

    of low-order

    places to

    high-order

    places, a matter not

    relevant

    to

    this

    discussion.

    I

    use the

    K

    designations

    only

    as a

    convenient means

    of

    referring

    to

    the

    different

    locational

    patterns.)

    In

    the case of the two

    economic

    principles,

    centers

    of

    a lower level

    in

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    8/17

    STUDIES OF CITIES 255

    the settlement

    hierarchy are nested midway in space between centers

    of

    the

    next highest rank.

    In the K=3 case, such centers are

    located between three

    higher-level centers, while in the case of the K=4

    pattern, such centers are

    located midway between two higher level centers, on the road between them.

    Centers of the

    same level

    in

    hierarchy, therefore, compete

    to service

    lower-level

    centers, particularly

    near the edges of their maximum spheres of influence. As a

    consequence, all

    consumers tend to be served equally,

    without monopolistic

    pricing. As

    Christaller correctly perceived, the locations

    of administrative cen-

    ters should differ

    from the K=3 or K=4 patterns, since they do not compete for

    customers ; instead, they should have discrete, tightly

    bounded ranges, with

    the center conveniently situated near the center of the

    servicing region. As

    Smith

    (52, p. 98)

    notes,

    the

    K=7 principle

    .

    .

    .

    is

    admirably suited to carving up

    administrative districts, since each higher-order center controls its dependent

    centers

    and

    hinterland

    exclusively. Although I will not deal explicitly here with

    religious-administrative hierarchies (which are usually

    inextricably woven with

    political administration), in those cases where they are

    discrete, autonomous

    institutions (such as

    in Medieval Europe), they should exhibit the K=7 pattern,

    since each parish

    is a discrete unit, and competition is not likely to occur.

    IMPLICATIONS

    OF THE LOCATIONAL

    PATTERNS FOR

    UNDERSTANDING VARIABILITY

    IN

    CENTRAL

    PLACE

    HIERARCHIES

    In

    the following sections, I will outline the basic patterns of

    articulation

    between

    economic

    central

    institutions and decision-making central institutions,

    and ex-

    plore the

    implications of these patterns for understanding some

    of the cross-

    cultural

    variability

    in

    sizes and functions of central

    places,

    and certain

    of

    their

    dynamic

    features.

    I

    do this

    in

    three sections.

    The first two

    sections,

    which

    deal

    with

    primate

    centers and disembedded capitals, pertain

    to the

    interaction

    of economic

    and

    decision-making central institutions

    at

    the

    upper

    levels

    of

    central

    place

    hierarchies,

    while

    the last section deals

    with

    the

    patterns

    of

    articulation of these central institutions on the lower levels.

    Primate Centers

    Purely from

    theoretical considerations, one should not expect locational

    iso-

    morphism between

    administrative and economic central place hierarchies,

    since

    the two locational

    patterns are

    incompatible (cf Skinner 48, p. 31).

    There are

    two

    major exceptions to

    this general rule.

    REDISTRIBUTIVE SYSTEMS

    In

    redistributive

    economic

    systems,

    in which ex-

    change

    is

    entirely

    administered,

    the

    centers

    of

    redistribution

    are also

    centers

    of

    decision-making.

    PRIMATE

    SYSTEMS In a marketing central place

    hierarchy

    in which the

    range

    of the

    highest

    order

    functions is equivalent to the maximum

    extent

    of the

    society

    as

    a

    whole, only one

    highest ranking center will exist, since only that center

    will

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    9/17

    256 BLANTON

    be able to offer the entire range

    of products n the system. This centercan also be

    the highest rankingadministrative enter, since the maximum

    range of these

    functions is also equivalent to

    the maximumextent of the whole

    society. The

    combinationof the widest possiblerangeof economic and administrativeunc-

    tions in one place can produce a primate distribution in

    the settlement

    hierarchy, .e. a situation n which

    the major entralplace is exceptionally arge

    relativeto other centers (Berry

    4). A largecenter of this type can

    actuallyretard

    the growth of lower-ranking

    enters, thereby intensifying its

    regional domi-

    nance,

    for

    the following reasons:

    (a)

    One of the

    assumptions

    of Christaller'sclassical formulation

    of central

    place theory is that consumers

    will always go to the closest market,

    n order to

    minimize he energy and time

    costs of transportation.Crissman

    12) has argued

    that this will not always be true because . . . motivations for marketing at one

    place rather hananotherare exceedingly

    complex and varyfromone context to

    another. Specifically, Crissmansuggests that . .

    .

    marketing

    areas for par-

    ticulargoods associated with

    given levels in the central place

    hierarchy, vary

    significently n size dependingon the level in the hierarchyof

    the center sup-

    plying them (12, pp. 347, 393). Trips to higher-order enters

    may be more

    frequent than theoretically predicted,he argues, because of the

    possibilityof

    multipurpose trips, . . . price differentials between low and high-level

    centers

    owing to fewer middlemen at the former. . . , and lower prices

    in larger centers

    due to

    . . .

    competition between

    multiple firms offering the same goods

    .

    .

    Added to these economic considerations,he argues, are a variety of social,

    political, religious, and recreationalreasons for going to

    one town rather

    han

    another. We

    might expect that the beauty and impressiveness

    of

    the massive

    civic, ceremonial,and palace

    constructions, manifesting he power

    of the high-

    est

    administrativeevel, would

    be an added ncentive to visit the

    majorpolitical

    center

    in

    spite

    of

    the

    tribulations

    of travel. For a variety of reasonsthen,

    the

    presence of a primatecentercould retard he growth of other centers

    because

    people

    will

    tend

    to

    go

    out of

    their way to complete transactions

    n the

    large

    center, bypassingbetter-locatedplaces.

    (b) Carol

    Smith

    (52)

    has described a situation

    in

    highlandGuatemala

    which

    may add to

    our

    understanding

    f the nature of primate settlement

    distribu-

    tions. There the massedpurchasingpower of the Ladinoelites,

    who control

    the

    government

    from a few centers, has resulted in a situation

    in which

    rural

    production

    s

    oriented

    to

    these

    largecenters alone. Thus all economic

    networks

    in

    the region

    . .

    . converge on a single center rather than

    on

    different

    nodes

    of

    a

    multi-centered,unboundedsystem. Because of this convergence,

    there

    is

    no

    competitionamongequivalent

    centers for the

    commerce

    of

    smaller

    centers

    (52

    p. 100).

    The

    outcome of these

    processes,

    she

    argues,

    will be

    the

    growth

    of

    solar

    or

    dendritic

    market

    ystemsinwhich secondarycenters

    in

    the

    region

    are poorly developed, and most production s gearedfor the primatecenter.

    Such

    situations lend themselves

    to

    poor economic development

    of

    the hinter-

    land,

    since

    populations

    ar

    away

    from

    the maincenter cannotparticipate

    n the

    society's

    economic

    system as

    effectively as those closer in (52;see also

    Johnson

    23).

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    10/17

    STUDIES

    OF

    CITIES

    257

    (c)

    According to central

    place

    theory,

    secondary

    centers

    should

    arise far

    away

    from the

    majorcenter,

    where

    the

    pull of the

    major

    center is weakest due

    to

    the

    friction of distance.

    This is

    not realizable

    in

    some

    cases, however,

    because

    secondary centers far enough away from the major center to effectively compete

    with it

    may be near

    the

    borders of

    the society.

    Because

    their

    market

    ranges are

    therefore

    distorted

    and

    smaller than

    necessary

    to support

    higher level

    functions,

    they will

    tend to

    remain poorly

    developed,

    the

    demand

    being

    met

    for higher-

    order goods

    only

    at the main

    center.

    According

    to Johnson

    (23, p.

    131), border

    .

    . .

    cities are inherently

    fragile economically

    since

    national

    borders

    artificially

    cut

    up

    geographically

    complementary

    regions

    (see also 51,

    p.

    179).

    (d)

    Because

    long-distance

    exchange

    is

    often

    directly

    administered

    or is at

    least

    under

    some

    degree

    of political

    control,

    high-ranking

    administrative

    centers

    are

    often also the foci of interregional exchange activities, and this, too, could add to

    the already

    overbearing

    domination of

    a region

    by a primate

    center

    (cf

    Vap-

    narsky

    55).

    Disembedded

    Capitals

    In cases

    where

    the highest-order

    goods

    in a society

    have a range

    which is

    less

    than

    the extent of

    the

    society as

    a whole,

    there

    should

    be multiple

    highest

    ranking

    economic

    centers

    instead

    of the

    primate pattern.

    In

    this

    case,

    I suggest,

    it

    is less

    likely that

    the

    highest-order

    place

    in the administrative

    hierarchy

    will

    be

    located in one of the commercial central places, for at least two reasons:

    (a)

    The location of any

    one of the

    multiple

    commercial

    central places,

    which

    might be optimal

    for

    servicing

    its region

    but not

    the

    whole society,

    might

    not

    be

    suitable

    for the location

    of central administrative

    transactions

    pertaining

    to

    the

    whole society. Suboptimal

    locations

    of highest

    ranking

    central

    places

    in

    the

    administrative system,

    as

    I

    mentioned

    above,

    increase the

    likelihood

    that

    noise

    could enter

    into communications

    with

    poorly serviced

    zones,

    de-

    creasing

    the

    effectiveness

    of the administration.

    (b)

    Merchants

    in existing high-order

    commercial

    central

    places

    might

    resist

    placement

    of

    high-order

    administrative

    functions

    in any

    existing center

    (except

    their

    own),

    because

    of the

    commercial advantages

    that

    would accrue

    to that

    center, especially

    insofar

    as such

    placement

    would

    increase

    the

    prestige

    of

    the

    one center

    and mass

    the

    purchasing

    power

    of

    high

    ranking

    elites

    there.

    I

    predict

    that in systems

    with

    multiple

    high-order

    commercial

    central

    places

    of

    nearly equivalent

    rank,

    the

    political

    capital

    will

    be

    located

    in

    a neutral

    position,

    away

    from

    existing

    commercial central

    places.

    This situation would also

    obtain

    in

    a region

    inhabited

    by

    a

    group

    of autonomous

    political

    units

    joined

    in a

    league

    or confederacy, perhaps

    for

    the purpose

    of

    taking

    advantage

    of

    their

    mutual

    military capabilities.

    in

    interregional

    warfare

    or control

    of interregional

    long

    distance exchange, but where all of the co-joining units are of nearly equivalent

    power.

    There are,

    in

    other

    words, situations

    in which

    one

    would expect

    the

    highest-order

    decision-making

    institution

    to be spatially

    disembedded

    from

    the remainder of the

    central-place

    hierarchy.

    There

    appear to

    be several

    differ-

    ent kinds of

    disembedded

    capitals.

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    11/17

    258

    BLANTON

    CAPITAL CENTERS The

    capital

    is a

    permanent but

    neutrally

    located

    special

    function

    community involved

    primarily

    in

    decision

    making at the

    regional level.

    Examples

    of

    this pattern

    include

    Washington DC (which was located

    away from

    the existing centers of Boston, New York, and Philadelphia, midway between

    the

    southern

    and northern states, at the

    insistence of

    the southerner, Thomas

    Jefferson),

    pre-Periclean Athens,

    Brazilia, Ottawa,

    New Delhi, and Canberra. I

    have

    argued that early

    Monte Alban, the ancient

    Zapotec capital in

    Oaxaca,

    Mexico, was

    a center of this type

    (Blanton 9).

    ROVING

    PALACES

    Highest-ranking elites move

    around periodically or at ran-

    dom

    from center to

    center, never staying long enough

    in one place to

    augment

    permanently the influence

    of any given

    center. Examples of this pattern

    include

    the

    roving palaces of

    ancient Egypt

    and certain periods and

    regions

    in

    pre-

    modern

    Europe.

    According to Russell (43), the failure

    to establish

    permanent

    places for ruler and court

    in Medieval

    Germany and Iberia precluded

    the rise of

    single, dominant central

    places.

    TEMPORARY

    CAPITALS

    Rulers build entirely new

    capitals

    when

    they

    come

    into

    office. Part of

    Coe's (11) argument that the

    ancient inland Cambodian

    capitals were not

    true

    cities was that each new ruler

    built a new

    facility,

    an

    impossible situation, Coe

    thought, for a

    commercial center. It is

    likely that he

    was

    dealing instead

    with

    a

    situation

    in

    which the

    capitals

    were

    disembedded

    from the

    remainder of the central place

    hierarchy.

    Unfortunately, the paucity of

    archaeological evidence

    makes it

    difficult to test this hypothesis.

    I

    feel it would be

    worthwhile to

    investigate certain of the dynamic

    properties

    of the

    two

    kinds of

    central place

    hierarchies just

    described. Specifically,

    it

    occurs to me

    that the first

    pattern, the primate pattern

    with a weakly

    developed

    hierarchy of commercial

    central places,

    might exhibit less long-term

    stability

    than the

    second

    pattern,

    in

    which the

    whole population is serviced

    by a

    more

    completely

    developed

    series of marketing central

    places. The class-like

    differ-

    ences that

    are likely

    to

    develop, given the

    primate pattern, between

    the well-

    serviced,

    relatively

    affluent

    groups

    in

    and near

    the main

    center

    versus

    those

    in

    poorly serviced, distant areas, could produce internal tensions that could erupt

    as warfare or

    revolution.

    Too,

    the

    primate

    pattern might

    be a more brittle

    one

    because

    populations

    distant

    from the main center

    might tend to break

    away

    politically

    and

    economically

    from

    the

    society as a whole, especially

    if

    allegiance

    to an

    adjacent

    system

    with

    a

    well-developed commercial

    central place hierarchy

    becomes

    a

    possibility.

    Political

    Control of

    Marketing Hierarchies

    Although

    classical central

    place theory predicts a lack of

    spatial

    isomorphism

    between administrative and commercial central place hierarchies (with the

    exception

    of

    the

    primate pattern described

    above),

    in

    reality

    there is often

    considerable

    spatial intertwining

    of the two

    types

    of

    central

    institutions.

    One

    reason for this

    undoubtedly has

    to do with the

    energy

    and

    time

    savings

    derived

    from the

    agglomeration

    of

    functions.

    Skinner writes

    concerning

    rural

    China:

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    12/17

    STUDIES OF CITIES

    259

    That the market town is a natural site for administration f its dependent area is

    obvious: Marketing periodically brings to town representatives of households

    throughout he administrative nit and village leaders can, on marketdays, readily

    consult their administrative uperiors 50, p. 382).

    Another factor to consider in explaining the overlap of political and commercial

    hierarchies is the extent to which the decision making central institution eyes the

    exchange system as a source of revenue and power. In this case,

    locating

    administrative and marketing activities together facilitates control and taxation.

    In spite of the obvious advantages of conformity between economic and de-

    cision hierarchies, however, there still exists the built-in incompatability be-

    tween the two. This is probably why Skinner found little overlap between

    administration and market places in rural China on the whole, especially in the

    lower levels of the central place hierarchy (48, p. 9).

    I

    suggest that the most fruitful method for explaining the cross-cultural and

    diachronic variability in relations between administrative and marketing

    hi-

    erarchies will be to investigate the following three variables:

    (a) The power of the state: This refers specifically to the extent to

    which the

    administrative institution is able to distort the economically desirable K=3 and

    K=4 patterns into the administratively more efficient K=7 pattern. According

    to

    Smith (52, p. 99) the K=7 pattern usually resembles the solar marketing

    pattern. Here,

    . .

    . poor market articulation occurs because

    the

    requirement

    of

    force overrides market efficiency. . A K=7 system almost always suggests

    imposition of the economic system by rulers . . . I predict that such administra-

    tively imposed patterns would always be temporary, because the more an

    administration meddles

    in

    markets, the less efficient marketing becomes.

    For

    example,

    the K=7

    pattern could easily lend itself to monopolistic pricing,

    since

    equivalent centers

    no

    longer compete. Producers, under these conditions, might

    choose

    to

    participate

    less

    in

    the market

    institution, lowering

    over-all

    productiv-

    ity, and thereby lowering state revenues from the market. This would coincide

    with the

    added costs incurred by the administration in its attempts to gain control

    over

    markets. These two factors operating together should force

    lessened

    ad-

    ministrative control of markets, probably first in lower ranking markets, which

    are

    the

    most

    numerous and therefore require the most personnel

    to administer.

    This

    process is nowhere better illustrated than in Skinner's description

    of the

    attempts

    of

    the communist

    regime

    in

    China

    to

    administer

    peasant marketing

    (50).

    The

    first such attempts resulted in considerable dislocations

    in the

    market

    and

    in

    reduced

    productivity.

    The

    response by

    the

    regime

    to

    the

    lowered

    produc-

    tivity

    was to

    attempt

    to

    obviate rural marketing by absorbing

    it .

    . .

    entirely

    into

    an expanded official structure, thereby shifting

    onto hundreds

    of

    thousands

    of

    local

    cooperative branches the functions of the standard

    market

    (50, p. 365).

    This

    tactic only exacerbated the problem, until finally the regime

    reversed

    its

    position: The rightist solution [to the marketing problem], which by August,

    1956,

    had

    carried the

    day, was

    to

    overcome

    the malfunctions

    in the

    existing

    system by relaxing

    controls

    and

    giving

    freer rein to

    the

    marketing

    mechanism.

    (b) The relative power of the state and participants in the

    market institutions:

    A

    politically powerful marketing institution might force the diminution

    of

    admin-

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    13/17

    260 BLANTON

    istrative

    distortions of the

    marketing hierarchy. This process is well illustrated

    in

    the history of Medieval Europe,

    where the emerging

    commercial middle class

    gradually

    swamped the power of the nobility. To quote

    Pirenne (40, p. 203), the

    legal codes of the commercially oriented cities . . . not only did away with

    personal

    servitude and r-estrictionson land, but also caused

    the disappearance of

    the

    seignioral rights and fiscal claims which interferred

    with the activity of

    commerce and

    industry. This

    resulted

    in

    the elimination of, among other

    things,

    market tolls, seigniorial monopolies on ovens and

    mills, and the right of

    shelter for the nobility.

    The possibility exists that there

    could develop in such

    cases a kind of market-

    state

    dynamic, such that,

    if

    for

    some reason the state begins to lose control over

    the market institution, an

    increase in market

    productivity would result, in-

    creasing in turn the power of

    the marketing institution,

    which could further

    exacerbate the

    power and revenue losses of the

    administrative institution-a

    deviation-amplifying,

    mutual-causal process, in the phraseology of Maruyama

    (33). Administrative expansion in

    control of markets,

    however, will normally be

    dampened as a result of revenue

    losses incurred in distortion of the marketing

    hierarchy, in combination with

    increased costs of

    administration.

    (c) The

    information processing capacity of

    administrative

    institutions:

    This

    refers to

    the extent to which a

    decision making institution can absorb an increase

    in

    the amount of

    information in the environment, for

    example,

    in

    the context

    of

    an

    expanding, evolving system.

    Any institution has a finite transactional capac-

    ity, limited by energy, personnel, and time, allowing it to respond only to a finite

    communications load.

    According to Meier:

    Communications

    oad is

    best measuredas

    the rate

    of

    requests

    for service

    or other

    forms of

    satisfying response,

    such as

    cogent explanations

    as to

    why

    the service

    cannotbe

    provided.

    It

    represents he initiation atefor social transactions ffected

    by

    the

    institution.The

    output,

    or

    transaction ompletion,rate s

    whatgenerates

    rewards

    for

    the institutionover

    the long run.When the outputrate fails to

    keep up

    with the

    initiationrate, some queues and

    backlogsdevelop. If all other

    factors remainequal,

    the

    resultant

    performance f the

    institutionbeginsto deviate more

    and

    morefrom

    the

    idealas load

    ncreases, untila peak n

    outputrate s reached.As certainresources

    and

    internal tocks-on-hand reexpended, the outputbecomes less with increasingoad.

    The

    output

    rate

    may drop

    precipitately resulting n breakdown]

    r

    it

    may seek

    a level

    which is

    'good enough to get by.' The

    capacity of the organization

    or

    completing

    transactionswill lie

    somewhere

    between the peak performance hat could

    not be

    maintained nd

    the level chosen for 'satisficing'. . . In this

    framework he capacity

    of an

    institution or

    completinga flow of transactions s

    equivalent

    to the channel

    capacity

    of

    a

    communications

    ystem

    for

    coding

    and

    decoding messages (34, pp.

    79-80).

    (See

    also

    J.

    G. Miller

    35

    and

    Wright 63.)

    Several different kinds

    of

    institutional

    responses

    to

    communications

    overload

    are possible, as Meier points out (including expansion in size if the institution

    can

    capture

    more

    energy

    to fund

    growth),

    but

    the

    kind

    of

    response

    most relevant

    to

    this

    discussion

    is for

    the institution

    to

    redefine

    its

    limits inward.

    An adminis-

    trative

    institution,

    in the

    context of stress due to communications

    overload

    (for

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    14/17

    STUDIES

    OF CITIES 261

    example in an

    evolving system), might

    respond by

    allowing

    certain

    previously

    administered transactions to operate

    autonomously.

    I

    suggest that in

    such cases

    one of the

    first areas

    in

    which control

    hierarchies would

    relinquish control

    would

    be in the context of exchange-related institutions. This is because economic

    institutions will tend, in

    the absence of

    administration, to exhibit

    self-regulation,

    or

    at least

    will

    tend

    to

    operate with a

    minimum of administrative

    regulation. This

    response

    would free energy and

    personnel for more

    urgent problems in the areas

    of offense

    and defense,

    long-distance trade, and

    adjudication.

    The arguments

    presented

    above, based especially on

    Skinner's analyses, strongly

    suggest that

    economic

    institutions

    actually do better with

    minimal administration

    because

    of

    the built-in

    incompatabilities of the

    marketing and

    administrative central place

    hierarchies.

    This kind of response to

    information

    overload could explain the

    transition from

    redistributive economies (the

    most highly

    administered ex-

    change

    systems)

    to

    markets, as well as being a

    possible explanation for

    why

    an

    administration might

    relinquish control

    of existing markets.

    CONCLUSIONS

    I

    have argued that

    traditional theories of cities

    utilized by

    anthropologists fail

    because

    they

    cannot

    adequately account

    for

    the cross-cultural

    variability

    in

    the

    nature

    of

    cities,

    and

    because they are

    inadequate for dealing with

    the dynamic

    properties of cities and

    the societies of

    which they are a part. I

    have suggested

    that

    one

    avenue anthropologists could

    take

    to

    resolve the

    shortage

    of

    adequate

    theory

    is

    to

    adopt

    a

    regional

    approach

    to

    studies

    of

    cities,

    based

    on

    the

    powerful

    central

    place theory

    of

    geography.

    This

    theory focuses attention

    on the

    dis-

    position

    of central

    institutions over the

    landscape. Those

    places

    that are the

    foci

    of

    central

    institution

    transactions

    are a society's

    system

    of

    cities

    and towns-its

    central-place hierarchy. This

    theory not

    only provides the means for

    explaining

    some

    of the

    cross-cultural

    variability

    in

    systems

    of

    cities

    and

    towns,

    but also

    provides

    a

    means for

    dealing with certain of the

    dynamic properties of societies.

    To

    accomplish

    this,

    I

    argued, the

    regionally oriented

    researcher should

    investi-

    gate the spatial relationships of the two basic kinds of central institutions, those

    that are economic and

    those that

    pertain to information processing

    and decision

    making.

    I

    outlined the

    basic kinds

    of

    articulation

    between

    these

    two

    genre

    of

    central

    institutions,

    described

    the

    patterns

    in

    the central

    place

    hierarchy

    which

    result

    from

    these

    relationships, and explored some of

    the implications

    of

    these

    varying patterns for

    understanding

    social change. The three patterns

    explored

    are the

    following:

    (a)

    The

    primate pattern

    obtains

    in

    a

    region

    in

    which the

    major

    commercial

    central

    place

    is also

    the

    political capital.

    This

    center

    will

    tend

    to

    dominate the

    region

    in

    such a way that the

    development of

    secondary centers,

    as

    predicted by

    Christaller's economic location principles, is retarded. This can result in a

    dendritic

    market pattern on

    the

    peripheries, such that regions distant from the

    main

    center are poorly

    serviced

    economically. This pattern is

    typically

    associ-

    ated with

    the dual

    economies

    described

    by Johnson

    (23),

    in

    which

    great

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    15/17

    262

    BLANTON

    wealth differentials develop

    between those populations close

    to or

    in

    the

    center,

    and those

    populations

    in

    distant, poorly serviced

    areas.

    Such societies, I

    argued,

    might exhibit relatively little long-term stability because these

    wealth

    differ-

    entials could lead to internal conflict, and because poorly serviced peripheral

    regions might tend to break away

    politically and economically from the society

    as a whole.

    (b) The second pattern I

    described is one in which there is more complete

    development of the commercial central place hierarchy, as predicted by Chris-

    taller. The primate pattern is absent, in part, because the political capital is

    typically disembedded from

    the marketing hierarchy, and so does not

    artificially distort that hierarchy away from what would be expected on the-

    oretical grounds alone (i.e.

    following Christaller's K=3 and K=4 locational

    principles).

    (c) Lastly,

    I

    discussed

    the

    nature

    of

    the lower ends

    of

    central place

    hi-

    erarchies. The nature and spatial

    distribution of low-order central places in a

    society,

    I

    argued, depends largely

    on the extent to which a decision making

    institution is able to distort the economically desirable K=3 and K=4 pat-

    terns

    into

    the administratively

    desirable K=7 pattern, in order to more closely

    regulate and tax rural production.

    Following the work of Skinner (50) as an

    example,

    it is

    clear that marketing

    efficiency depends on maintenance of the

    K=3

    or K=4

    patterns.

    Administrative meddling

    in

    the marketing hierarchy

    brings

    a

    reduction

    in

    marketing

    efficiency, and therefore, overall declines

    in

    productivity of participants in the marketing institution. As a result, I suggest,

    administrative

    distortions of

    commercial central place hierarchies

    should tend

    to

    be short-term, since an administration loses revenues at the same time that

    it is

    incurring the added costs of market administration.

    I

    hope this brief, and not nearly

    complete, exercise in central place theorizing

    will

    be an inducement to other

    anthropologists interested in cities to adopt a

    regional approach as one method

    for explaining the variability and dynamic

    features

    of

    systems

    of

    cities and towns.

    Relatively few anthropologists

    have

    employed

    such

    an

    approach.

    The

    prominent works are

    those

    I

    have

    already

    described at length, those of Skinner (48-50), Smith (52), and Crissman (12).

    To

    this list I can add the publications of Johnson (24-26), Wright (63), Adams (1),

    and

    Adams & Nissen (2), for ancient

    Greater Mesopotamia; Marcus (31),

    and

    Hammond

    (18)

    for

    the ancient

    lowland Maya area; the publications

    of

    par-

    ticipants in the Valley of Mexico

    Project (Blanton 8, Millon 36, Parsons 39,

    Sanders

    45,

    Wolf

    62);

    as well as

    Blanton (9)

    and

    Kowalewski (27), writing

    about

    the ancient Valley of Oaxaca. This small but growing movement,

    I

    feel,

    will

    prove

    to

    be

    a

    significant new

    addition

    to

    anthropological

    studies

    of cities.

    ACKNOWLE

    DG

    MENTS

    I

    am grateful for helpful comments

    received on an earlier version

    of this

    paper

    from Gary Feinman, Greg Johnson, Steve Kowalewski, Susan Lees, John

    Pfeiffer, John Speth, Donna Taylor,

    and

    Paul

    Wheatley. Responsibility

    for

    any

    errors

    is

    my

    own.

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    16/17

    STUDIES

    OF

    CITIES

    263

    Literature

    Cited

    1.

    Adams, R.

    McC.

    1965.

    Land

    Be-

    hind

    Baghdad:

    A

    Historv

    of Set-

    tlement on the Diyala Plains. Univ.

    Chicago Press

    2.

    Adams, R.

    McC.,

    Nissen,

    H.

    J.

    1972.

    The

    Uruk

    Countryside.

    Univ.

    Chicago

    Press

    3.

    Arensberg,

    C.

    M.

    1968.

    The

    urban

    in

    crosscultural

    perspective.

    In

    Ur-

    ban

    Anthropology:

    Research

    Per-

    spectives and

    Strategies,

    ed.

    E.

    Eddy,

    2:3-15.

    Proc.

    South. An-

    thropol. Soc.

    Athens:

    Univ.

    Geor-

    gia

    Press

    4.

    Berry, B. J.

    L.

    1961.

    City size dis-

    tribution

    and

    economic

    develop-

    ment. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change

    9:573-88

    5.

    Berry, B.

    J. L.

    1967.

    Geography

    of

    Market

    Centers and

    Retail

    Distribui-

    tion.

    Englewood

    Cliffs:

    Prentice-

    Hall

    6.

    Berry,

    B.

    J. L.,

    Garrison,

    W.

    L.

    1958.

    Recent

    developments in

    cen-

    tral-place

    theory. Proc.

    Reg. Sci.

    Assoc.

    9: 107-20

    7.

    Berry,

    B.

    J.

    L.,

    Pred, A.

    1961.

    Ceni-

    tral

    Place

    Studies: A

    Bibliographv

    of

    Theory and

    Applications.

    Philadelphia:Reg. Sci. Res. Inst.8.

    Blanton,

    R. E.

    1972.

    Prehispanic

    Settlement

    Patterns

    of the

    Ixta-

    palapa

    Peninsula

    Region, Mexico.

    University

    Park:

    Penn.

    State

    Univ.

    Dep.

    Anthropol.

    9.

    Blanton,

    R.

    E.

    1976.

    The

    origins of

    Monte

    Alban. In

    Cultural

    Chainge

    and

    Continuity,

    ed.

    C.

    Cleland.

    New

    York:

    Academic

    10.

    Christaller,

    W.

    1933.

    Die

    Zentralen

    Orte in

    Suddeutschland.

    Transl.

    C. W.

    Baskin, 1966.

    Central

    Places

    in

    Southern

    Germany.

    Englewood

    Cliffs:Prentice-Hall

    11.

    Coe, M. D.

    1961.

    Social

    typology

    and

    tropical

    forest

    civilizations.

    Comp. Stud. Soc.

    Hist.

    4:65-85

    12.

    Crissman,

    L.

    W.

    1973.

    Town

    and

    country: Central

    place

    theory

    and

    Chinese

    marketing,

    with

    particular

    reference to

    southwestern

    Chan-

    ghua

    Hsien,

    Taiiwan. PhD

    thesis.

    Cornell

    Univ.,

    Ithaca,

    NY

    13.

    Epstein, A. L.

    1967.

    Urbanization

    and

    social

    change

    in

    Africa.

    Curr.

    Anthropol.

    48:275-95

    14.

    Flannery,

    K.

    V. 1972.

    The

    cultural

    evolution of civilizations. Ann. Rev.

    Ecol.

    Syst.

    3:399-426

    15.

    Friedmann,J. 1961.

    Cities

    in

    social

    transformation.

    Comp.

    Stud.

    Soc.

    Hist.

    4:86-103

    16. Gunawardena,

    K. 1964. Service

    centers

    in southern Cevlon.

    PhD.

    thesis. Univ. Cambridge,England

    17. Haggett,

    P. 1965. Locational

    Analy-

    sis in Humnan

    Geographly.

    New

    York: St. Martin'sPress

    18. Hammond,

    N.

    1972.

    Locational

    models and the site of

    Lubaanturn:

    A classic Maya centre. In Models

    in

    Archaeology,

    ed.

    D.

    Clarke,

    757-800. London: Methuen

    19. Hauser, P. M. 1965.

    Urbanization,

    an overview.

    In

    The Study

    of Ur-

    banization,

    ed.

    P. M.

    Hauser,

    L.

    Schnore, p.

    12. New York:

    Wiley

    20. Hauser, P. M. 1965. The

    folk-urban

    ideal types: Observationson the ur-

    ban-folk

    and

    urban-rural

    di-

    chotomies

    as forms of Western eth-

    nocentrism. See Ref. 19,

    503-17

    21. Hodder, I.,

    Hassall

    M. 1971.

    The

    non-random spacing

    of Romano-

    British walled towns.

    Main

    6:391-407

    22. Jacobs, J. 1969. The

    Economv

    of

    Cities.

    New

    York: Random

    House

    23. Johnson,

    E. A. J. 1970. The Organi-

    zation of Space

    in

    Developing

    Countries. Cambridge:

    Harvard

    Univ. Press

    24.

    Johnson, G.

    A.

    1972.

    A

    test of the

    utility of central place

    theory

    in

    ar-

    chaeology.

    In

    Man, Settlement,

    and

    Urbanism,

    ed.

    P. J.

    Ucko,

    R. Tri-

    ngham, G.

    W.

    Dimbleby, 769-85.

    London: Duckworth

    25. Johnson, G.

    A. 1973.

    Local Ex-

    change

    and

    Early

    State

    Develop-

    ment

    in

    Southwestern

    Iran.

    An-

    thropol.

    Pap. 51.

    Ann

    Arbor: Univ.

    MichiganMus. Anthropol.

    26. Johnson, G.

    A.

    1975.

    Locational

    analysis

    and

    Uruk local exchange

    systems. In Ancient Civilization and

    Trade,

    ed. J. A.

    Sabloff,

    C. C.

    Lamberg-Karlovsky, 85-339.

    Albu-

    querque:Univ. New

    Mexico Press

    27.

    Kowalewski, S.

    1976.

    Prehistoric

    settlement patterns of

    the central

    part of the valley of Oaxaca,

    Mex-

    ico. PhD. thesis. Univ. Arizona,

    Tucson,

    Ariz.

    28.

    Lewis,

    0.

    1951.

    Life

    In

    a

    Mexican

    Village. Tepoztlin

    Restudied. Ur-

    bana: Univ.

    Illinois

    Press

    29. Lewis,

    0. 1965. The folk-urban

    ideal types:

    Further

    observations

    on

    the folk-urban continuum and ur-

    banization with

    special

    reference

    to

    Mexico

    City.

    See Ref.

    19,

    491-503

    30.

    Losch,

    A. 1940.

    Die riumliche Ord-

    nung der Wirtschaft.

    Transl.

    H.

  • 8/12/2019 2949313 mercado

    17/17

    264 BLANTON

    Woglom,

    W.

    F.

    Stolper,

    1954.

    The

    Economics

    of Location.

    New

    Ha-

    ven:

    Yale Univ.

    Press

    31.

    Marcus, J.

    1973.

    Territorial

    organi-

    zation of the Lowland Classic

    Maya.

    Science

    180:911-16

    32. Martindale,

    D. 1958.

    Prefatory

    re-

    marks:

    The

    theory

    of

    the city.

    In

    The

    City, M.

    Weber,

    9-62.

    Transl.

    D. Martindale,

    G. Neuwirth,

    New

    York: Free

    Press

    33.

    Maruyama,

    M. 1963.

    The

    second

    cybernetics:

    Deviation-amplifying

    mutual-causal

    processes.

    Am.

    Sci.

    51:164-79

    34. Meier, R.

    1962.

    A Communications

    Theory

    of Urban

    Growth.

    Cam-

    bridge:M. I. T. Press

    35.

    Miller, J.

    G.

    1965.

    Living systems:

    Basic concepts.

    Behav.

    Sci.

    10:193-257

    36.

    Millon,

    R.

    1973.

    Urbanization

    at

    Teotihuacin,

    Vol. I.

    The

    Map.

    Aus-

    tin:

    Univ.

    Texas

    Press

    37.

    Moore,

    K. 1975.

    The city

    as con-

    text:

    Context

    as process.

    Urban

    An-

    thropol.

    4:17-25

    38.

    Park,

    R. 1925.

    The

    city: Sug-

    gestions

    for

    the

    investigation

    of

    hu-

    man behavior

    in

    the

    urban

    environ-

    ment.

    In The City,

    ed.

    R. Park,

    E.

    Burgess, R. McKenzie, pp. 1-46.

    Univ. Chicago

    Press

    39.

    Parsons, J.

    R. 1972.

    Prehistoric

    Set-

    tlement

    Patterns

    in the

    Texcoco

    Re-

    gion,

    Mexico.

    Mem.

    3, Mus.

    An-

    thropol.,

    Univ. Michigan.

    447

    pp.

    40. Pirenne,

    H. 1925.

    Medieval Cities:

    Their

    Origins

    and the

    Revival

    of

    Trade, p.

    203.

    Princeton Univ.

    Press

    41. Redfield,

    R. 1941.

    The Folk Cul-

    tures

    of

    Yucatan. Univ.

    Chicago

    Press

    42.

    Redfield,

    R., Singer,

    M. 1954.

    The

    cultural role of cities. Econ. Dev.

    Cult. Change

    3:53-73

    43.

    Russell, J. C.

    1972.

    Medieval

    Re-

    gions

    and

    Their Cities,

    p.

    36.

    Bloomington:

    ndianaUniv. Press

    44.

    Sahlins,

    M. D. 1968. Tribesmen.

    Englewood

    Cliffs:

    Prentice-Hall

    45.

    Sanders,

    W.

    T. 1965. Cultural Eco-

    logy of

    the

    Teotihuacin

    Valley,

    Mexico. University

    Park:

    Penn.

    State

    Univ.

    Dep.

    Anthropol.

    46.

    Service,

    E.

    R. 1971.

    Primitive So-

    cial

    Organization.

    New York:

    Ran-

    dom House.

    2nd ed.

    47.

    Sjoberg,

    G.

    1960. The Preindustrial

    City,

    Past

    and Present. Glencoe:

    Free Press

    48. Skinner, G. W.

    1964.

    Marketing

    and social

    structure

    in rural China:

    Part I. J. Asian Stud. 24:3-43

    49. Ibid

    1965. Marketing and social

    structure

    in rural

    China: Part

    II,

    195-228

    50.

    Ibid.

    Marketingand social structure

    in ruralChina:Part

    III, 363-99

    51.

    Smith,

    C.

    A.

    1974.

    Economics of

    marketing

    systems: Models from

    economic

    geography.Ann. Rev.

    An-

    thropol.

    3:167-201

    52.

    Smith,

    C. A. 1975. Examining

    stratificationsystems

    through peas-

    ant

    marketing

    arrangements:An ap-

    plicationof some models from eco-

    nomic

    geography. Man 10:95-122

    53. Stafford,

    H. A. Jr. 1963. The func-

    tional

    bases of small towns. Econ.

    Geogr.

    39:165-75

    54.

    Taylor,

    D.

    1975.

    Some locational

    aspects

    of middle-range

    hierarchical

    societies.

    PhD. thesis. City Univ.

    New

    York, NY

    55.

    Vapnarsky,

    C. 1969. On rank-size

    distributionsof cities:

    an ecological

    approach.

    Econ. Dev. Cult. Change,

    17:584-95

    56.

    Wheatley, P. 1963.

    What

    the

    greatness of a city is said to be:

    Reflections

    on Sjoberg's

    Pre-

    industrial

    City.

    Pac. Viewpoint

    4:163-88

    57. Wheatley, P. 1971.

    Pivot of

    the

    Four

    Quarters, A Preliminary

    In-

    quiry

    into the Origins and Character

    of

    the

    Ancient Chinese City,

    Chicago:Aldine

    58.

    Wheatley,

    P. 1972. The concept

    of

    urbanism.

    See

    Ref. 24, 601-37

    59.

    Wirth,

    L.

    1925.

    A

    bibliography

    of

    the urban community.

    See Ref.

    38,

    p.

    172

    60. Wirth,L. 1938.Urbanismas a way

    of life.

    Am.

    J.

    Sociol.

    44:1-24

    61. Wolf,

    E.

    R. 1966.

    Peasants, p.

    11.

    Englewood

    Cliffs:

    Prentice-Hall.

    116

    pp.

    62.

    Wolf,

    E.

    R.,

    ed.

    1976.

    The

    Valley

    of

    Mexico:

    Studies

    in

    Ecology

    and

    So-

    ciety. Albuquerque:

    Univ. New

    Mexico

    Press

    63.

    Wright,

    H. T.

    1969.

    The

    Adminis-

    tration

    of

    Rural

    Production

    in

    an

    Early

    Mesopotamian

    Town.

    An-

    thropol.

    Pap.

    38.

    Ann Arbor: Univ.

    Michigan Mus. Anthropol.