21.- Wood, Charles H.

download 21.- Wood, Charles H.

of 22

Transcript of 21.- Wood, Charles H.

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    1/22

    Time, Cycles and Tempos inSocial-ecological Research and

    Environmental Policy

    Charles H. Wood

    ABSTRACT. The execution of successful social-ecological researchand the formulation of effective environmental policies cruciallydepend on a deep knowledge of the temporal complexity of theinteractions between social and biophysical systems. To promote akeener awareness of the relevance of time, cycles, and tempos, thisstudy assembles examples drawn from a range of disciplines to

    delineate the ways temporality enters into human behavior, resourcemanagement, and the conduct of social-ecological research. Anthro-pological and historical studies document the culturally embeddedtemporal subjectivities that shape the way humans exploit orconserve natural resources. Analyses of environmental policy showhow temporal considerations enter into intervention strategies viasuch concepts as discount rates, property rights and the precautionaryprinciple. The centrality of temporal assumptions is further evi-denced by the time-dependent foundations of disciplinary specializa-tions. The likelihood of temporal mismatches between the

    specializations that participate in interdisciplinary research andbetween the scientific findings and environmental policy can bemitigated by giving attention to temporal grain, temporal fallacy andtemporal extent. KEY WORDS environment; hierarchy; interdisci-plinary; precautionary principle; social-ecological system; temporalextent; temporal fallacy; temporal grain

    Time & Society copyright © 2008 SAGE (Los Angeles, London, New Delhi and Singapore)VOL. 17 No. 2/3 (2008), pp. 261–282 0961-463X DOI: 10.1177/0961463X08093425

    www.sagepublications.com

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    2/22

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    3/22

    sequent discussion that notes how temporal considerations enter into the formu-

    lation of environmental policy via such concepts as the discount rate, property

    rights and the precautionary principle. The third section delves more deeply into

    the centrality of temporal assumptions by showing that disciplinary specializa-

    tions in the social and natural sciences are largely predicated on a preferred levelof analysis and associated time-dependent theories, concepts and instruments.

    Cognizance of these fundamental differences is vital to interdisciplinary

    research agendas, as summarized in the conclusion.

    Subjective Time, Human Behavior and the Environment

    Anthropologists’ attention to culturally embedded notions of time has produced

    a wealth of data that amply document the variability in the perception and treat-

    ment of time among societies (e.g. Nilsson, 1920; Evans-Pritchard, 1940; Gell,

    1992). Typical of this approach are studies that show how temporal subjectivi-

    ties and durational expectations in non-western cultures are often tuned to the

    cycles of nature and to the rhythms of social practices and economic activities.

    An example in this classic tradition is Evans-Pritchard’s (1940) ethnography of 

    the Nuer of Africa, a society of pastoralists who calibrate the time of day and of 

    the passage of time mainly in relation to the round of tasks involved in tending

    to cattle. Thus conceived, time is treated as process-linked rather than somethingabstract and transcendent. Taking his cue from Durkeim’s Elementary Forms of 

    the Religious Life (1915/1964) , Evans-Pritchard – along with virtually all con-

    temporary anthropologists of time – rejected the notion of time as an immutable

    and external fact in favor of a perspective that treated time as a ‘social construc-

    tion’, something that human beings create in the course of their material

    existence (Gell, 1992: 4).

    The relevance of subjective time to the environment is illustrated by Oren

    Lyons’s (1980) study of the Iroquois who share a worldview that compels them

    to make decisions in a manner that institutionalizes the future into their presentchoices. Jeremy Rifkin (1987) cites an interview Lyons carried out with an

    Iroquois chief, who explained: ‘We are looking ahead . . . to make sure that

    every decision we make relates to the welfare and well-being of the seventh

    generation to come’ (p. 78). The Iroquois thus appear to have long embraced the

    principles of sustainable development as the form of development that does not

    ‘compromise the ability of future generations to meet their own needs’ (WCED,

    1987: 43).

    Other ethnographies show how backward-looking creation myths can simi-

    larly promote a conservation ethic (see Peterson, 2001). Among the Koyukonwho live in the north-western interior of Alaska, creation narratives look to the

    ‘distant time’ when animals were human, lived in human society and spoke

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 263

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    4/22

    human language (Peterson, 2001: 104). The oral history of tribal origins instills

    among the Koyukon a conservation view that endorses restraint, humility and

    respect for the world of nature.

    Group-held conceptions of time can just as easily undermine the resilience

    societies display as they contend with external threats and environmental chal-lenges. Among the Aztecs, it was a deep commitment to time as a cyclical

    phenomenon that disposed Moctezuma, at least in the beginning, to see the

    Spaniards not as a threat from the outside but as god-spirits who heralded the

    end of one cosmic period and the commencement of another (Paz, 1985).

    Emboldened by Moctezuma’s indecisiveness, Cortes marched his small band of 

    warriors into Tenochtitlán and changed the world forever (Chasteen, 2001).

    Sanguine interpretations of Iroquois and Koyukon culture may well reflect

    the much-criticized tendency to romanticize the ‘ecologically noble savage’,

    thus eliding the uncomfortable findings of studies that have documented manyinstances in which indigenous peoples are known to have over-exploited natural

    resources (Redford, 1991; Krech, 1999). In a similar manner, social and natural

    scientists alike are rightly wary of ‘just so’ stories wherein the existence of an

    observed phenomenon is explained by its adaptive function. ‘Just so’ reasoning

    was the premise of Rudyard Kipling’s whimsical children’s stories, published in

    1902, about the origins of curiosities like the leopard’s spots and the camel’s

    hump. As with Kipling’s stories, but in a more serious vein, Lyons’s (1980)

    account of the Iroquois, like the ecological interpretation of Koyukon culture,

    may be overly tendentious. Conclusions from a wealth of data are nonetheless

    consistent with the notion that the temporal orientations of indigenous societies

    often promote cultural traditions that preserve native species and natural

    resources in the course of protecting human subsistence (Peterson, 2001).

    Rifkin (1987) was quick to note the striking contrast between the expanded

    time horizon invoked by the Iroquois and the shortened lens of modern political

    leaders whose ‘concept of decision-making responsibility barely extends

    beyond the four-year period that marks off each new general election’ (p. 79).

    Because the consequences of decisions made today will be experienced bypresent generations and by generations to come, futures are being constructed

    and foreclosed with political tools that are unresponsive to citizens who live

    beyond the temporal boundaries of the deciding government’s term of office. A

    conspicuous example is the decision to construct a nuclear power station. The

    mere four- to five-year time horizon of a government’s accountability is insuffi-

    cient to cover the plant’s building phase, let alone its period of decommission-

    ing, and even less the time span of radioactive materials (Adam, 1998).

    Like the cultures of which they are a part, temporal orientations are subject to

    historical change, often in ways that reflect fundamental shifts in how peopleinteract with nature. A well-known treatment of the time–nature–history rela-

    tionship appears in E. P. Thompson’s (1967) influential essay on the demise of 

    264 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    5/22

    feudalism. In that text, Thompson documented how people’s temporal reckon-

    ing once based on the agricultural calendar was supplanted by notions of time

    dictated by industrial capitalism. Intimately tied to Newtonian physics and to

    assumptions about linear causality, irreversibility and objectivity, the new

    temporal foundation ‘constitutes the deep structure of the taken-for-grantedknowledge associated with the industrial way of life’ based on notions of cer-

    tainty and control (Adam, 1998: 97). Divorced from the periodicities of nature,

    our clocks and schedules allow us to impose science and technology on the

    tempos of the biological, physical and social worlds.1 As the steam whistle

    replaced the tolling of church bells that once signaled the hours of work and

    prayer, the associated values and ideologies, driven by the imperatives of capi-

    tal accumulation in competitive global markets, increasingly promote and

    reward short time horizons and the immediate exploitation of nature in ways

    profoundly antithetical to long-term conservation. If the implied dichotomybetween ‘traditional’ and ‘modern’ time orientations is often overstated as

    critics have argued (Adam, 1995; Bluedorn, 2002), the transition to industrial

    capitalism has clearly reorganized the cognitive and material bases of the inter-

    actions between humans and the natural environment.

    Indifference to the long term may have received an unintentional boost in

    recent years from the growing popularity of some evangelical Christian views

    that endorse the finite quantity of remaining time before the return of the

    Messiah. The attitude is especially manifest among those who endorse the

    ‘Rapture credo’ vividly expressed in the best-selling  Left Behind book series

    authored by Tim LaHaye. When droughts, floods and ecological collapse are

    treated as harbingers of an imminent, inevitable and even desirable apocalypse,

    conservationists like David Orr (2005) and E. O. Wilson (2006) note that people

    are not inclined to overly worry about the future state of the environment. In

    David Orr’s (2005) view, the apocalyptic tendencies of evangelical theology

    make believers complacent and therefore complicit to environmental degrada-

    tion. The argument is sufficiently troubling to conservationists that it is the basis

    of the first chapter in E. O. Wilson’s book, The Creation: An Appeal to Save Lifeon Earth (2006), in which Wilson, in an ‘Open Letter to a Southern Baptist

    Minister’, concludes that the widespread conviction that the Second Coming is

    imminent and that the Earth is therefore doomed is a gospel that plays down our

    responsibility to conserve nature.

    Evangelical Christians are not of one mind on the matter, as is clear in the

    exchanges published in the pages of Conservation Biology, a leading journal in

    the field of environmental studies (Cobb, 2005; Henderson, 2005; Orr, 2005;

    Stuart, 2005). Responding to Orr’s less than flattering picture of evangelical

    Christianity, one contributor (Van Dyke, 2005) noted that there are more than 40evangelical organizations that explicitly include environmental conservation in

    their mission statements. Competing perspectives in this discussion are unlikely

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 265

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    6/22

    to be reconciled any time soon. Still, the debate and the other examples noted in

    here underscore the broader idea that subjective perceptions of time have conse-

    quences for the environment and that temporal orientations are mutable and sub-

     ject to historical forces in ways that both reflect and produce fundamental shifts

    in how people interact with nature.

    Temporal Foundations of Environmental Policy

    Environmental policies that seek to alter the trade-off between current con-

    sumption and future welfare explicitly rely on the behavioral consequences of 

    subjective temporal orientation. Temporal dimensions enter into the formulation

    of environmental policy via concepts such as discount rates, property rights and

    the precautionary principle.

    Social and political discount rates

    Discounting is a key component of cost-benefit analysis, a procedure that

    requires that future benefits be expressed in monetary form. Discounting is

    based on the principle that a dollar today is worth more than a dollar in the

    future. Investors and policy makers therefore assess the current value of a future

    sum of money or a future benefit to society by depreciating its value backwardsin time. In the realm of environmental policy, both the costs and benefits of a

    project are discounted. The difference between the two yields the ‘net present

    value’ (NPV) of a particular initiative, a figure that provides the basis for policy

    decisions. If the NPV has a positive sign, then benefits exceed costs and adop-

    tion of the policy is encouraged. If the sign is negative, costs exceed benefits and

    the NPV counsels against adoption (Farber and Hemmersbaugh, 1993).

    Discounting is controversial because no agreement exists as to the correct dis-

    count rate. More generally, discounting can seem to give insufficient weight to

    future benefits. With the passage of sufficient time, the future is rendered worth-less regardless of the discount rate (Adam, 1998). Critics thus contend that dis-

    counting reduces even large benefits to present values that are insignificant

    (Farber and Hemmersbaugh, 1993). Others counter that when discounting is

     judiciously applied and thoughtfully interpreted, the method provides indispens-

    able information to make sound choices (Goulder and Stavins, 2002).

    The trade-off between the present and the future, enshrined in the discount

    rate, suggests a form of reasoning that has been applied to the political arena,

    albeit in less formal terms. In the political context it appears that the greater the

    elapsed time between today’s decision and its manifest consequences, the lessfuture consequences count in present considerations (Adam, 1998). In this sense

    we can speak of a ‘political discount rate’ to refer to the present political value

    266 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    7/22

    of the future benefits of a given action. In an institutional and historical context

    in which security in office is unpredictable, the rational ruler will forgo invest-

    ments whose benefits he or she may not survive long enough to reap. ‘The more

    doubtful the outcome, the higher the relative value of alternative activities that

    yield immediate dividends, even if the expected return of those activities is low’(Goldsmith, 2004). The principle has been used to explain the highly predatory

    style of political rule often seen in African countries (Goldsmith, 2004) and can

    be easily extended to address the politics of environmental regulation.

    Uncertain futures, property rights and land degradation

    Whether couched in social or political terms, discounting provides one basis for

    conceptualizing the relationship between present and future. Other approaches

    to understanding inter-temporal choices have been applied to a broad range of phenomena. In the case of land resources, the manner in which the future insin-

    uates itself into present is evident in the way property rights, land titles and

    tenure security influence the likelihood that people will take steps to conserve

    land.

    In the case of agricultural land, it is the rate of degradation relative to the pace

    of regeneration that decides the effectiveness of conservation strategies.

    Because the quantity of land available for agriculture took millions of years to

    form, it can, from the human temporal perspective, be treated as a fixed supply,

    a non-renewable resource. Even so, agricultural land has a regenerative capacity

    and can be made continuously productive with investment, maintenance and the

    replacement of nutrients. Effective land management occurs when the rate of 

    regeneration keeps pace with the degenerative consequences of agricultural use

    (Wachter, 1992). Whether land is a non-renewable (stock) or a renewable (flow)

    resource is therefore contingent not only on the technologies applied to the

    management of land but also on the time-frame invoked.

    The likelihood that land managers will engage in long-term investment, and the

    probability that they will defer the immediate exploitation of natural capital in theinterest of long-term conservation, is enhanced when people can be sure that at

    some point in the future they can reap the benefits of present investment and con-

    servation (Wachter, 1992). Confidence in the ability to claim ownership over

    future outputs is promoted via the official, but sometimes informal, establishment

    of clear and enforced property rights. In rural areas this usually takes the form of 

    land titles, the provision of which is assumed to create a predictable future and

    thereby improve the stewardship of land and natural resources (Alchian and

    Demsetz, 1973; Feder, 1987; Larson and Bromley, 1990; Beaumont and Walker,

    1994).The predictability of the future and the degree to which people have confi-

    dence in their hold over land are cognitive orientations that are influenced by

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 267

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    8/22

    economic and political contexts, as was readily seen in frontier regions of the

    Brazilian Amazon (Schmink and Wood, 1992). Poor migrants who initially

    trekked into the lowland tropics during the 1970s and 1980s were acutely aware

    of their tenuous hold over land and their vulnerability to more powerful ranchers

    intent on converting forest to pasture. Under the circumstances, smallholdersfound that their only option was to deforest with the explicit expectation of sell-

    ing their ‘improvements’ to the land as quickly as possible, then move on to

    repeat the cycle further down the road. The result was a process of rapid and

    extensive deforestation unrelated to the agricultural potential of the land. When

    settlement areas on the frontier became more consolidated and when the tran-

    sience that marked the early days gave way to more secure land tenure and to the

    possibility of longer time horizons, the stage was set for collective action on the

    part of individuals and communities to resist dispossession and to invest in land.

    Changing subjective assessments of the future thus played a significant role inpromoting social mobilization and encouraging the adoption of less predator

    forms of land use.2

    A variation in the analyses of the behavioral consequences of temporal orien-

    tations comes from Bryan Roberts’ (1995) use of Robert Merton’s (1984) con-

    cept of ‘socially expected durations’. Roberts invoked the concept to explain the

    fate of different immigrant groups to the United States (US). In a manner simi-

    lar to the studies that noted the land use consequences of short time horizons

    among migrants to the Brazilian Amazon, Roberts found that group differences

    in the probability of becoming a naturalized citizens, the likelihood of buying a

    home and the probability of investing in a business could be explained by

    whether immigrants thought of their presence in the US as transient or perma-

    nent.

    We can conclude from these observations that microeconomic explanations

    based on discount rates, as well as numerous other explanations of the human

    causes of environmental degradation, including predictions derived from the

    property rights paradigm, are special cases of the behavioral consequences of 

    subjective temporalities. The idea that culturally embedded temporal notionsand socially expected durations can exert a significant influence on behavior of 

    individuals and social groups further points to a connection, largely implicit,

    between subjective perceptions of time and leading issues within the social and

    environmental sciences. As the various examples suggest, group-held ideas of 

    time and the transitory or permanent character of people’s perception of their

    present situation can affect the likelihood of social movements (see Foweraker,

    1995), the development of ‘social capital’ as a development resource (Putnam,

    1993; Portes, 1998), the degradation of the natural environment (Wachter, 1992)

    and the feasibility of community-based conservation efforts (e.g. Agrawal,1997).

    268 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    9/22

    Future damages and present caution

    Assessments of the future damages caused by present action and attempts to

    mediate inter-temporal costs and benefits through environmental policies are

    especially difficult to formulate when the effects are drawn out over longperiods of time and when the processes involved are marked by contingencies,

    time lags and periods of invisibility. Global warming comes to mind as does

    damage to the ozone layer and the extra skin cancers created by the higher levels

    of ultraviolet radiation penetrating a normally protective ozone layer. Additional

    examples include the health consequences of genetically modified organisms,

    the manifestation of bovine spongiform encephalopathy (BSE) in cattle (‘mad

    cow’ disease) and Creutzfeldt-Jakob disease (CJD) in humans, and mesothe-

    lioma caused by the inhalation of asbestos dust.

    The uncertain outcome of present actions has prompted some to insist oncaution first, science second. Although there is no agreed definition of the idea,

    the concept is often labeled the ‘precautionary principle’. The principle is

    invoked when ‘there is a need to act to reduce potential hazard before there is

    strong proof of harm, taking into account the likely costs and benefits of action

    and inaction’ (Harremöes et al., 2002: 4). Ardent advocates of precaution

    contend, for example, that governments should immediately ban the planting of 

    genetically modified crops even though science cannot produce definitive evi-

    dence that they are a danger to the environment or to consumers. The precau-

    tionary principle shifts the burden of proof by ‘requiring those who would

    intervene in the environment to demonstrate that their interventions will not

    cause harm’ (Lee, 1993: 173). Skeptics counter that adopting the principle will

    stifle trade and limit innovation. ‘If someone had evaluated the risk of fire right

    after it was invented,’ remarked Julian Morris at a conference on the precau-

    tionary principle, ‘they may well have decided to eat their food raw’ (cited in

    Appell, 2001: 18).

    Introducing long-term considerations into present choices is particularly diffi-

    cult when a proposed action threatens the privileges or profits of powerful inter-ests, when the environmental or health consequences are far in the future, and

    when the real or perceived costs of action are large and immediate. Precaution-

    ary policies are further vulnerable to the very culture of the scientific enterprise

    that militates against anticipatory action. In the absence of strong evidence,

    experts habitually express scientific results with utmost prudence. Caution is

    formally enshrined in the fear of committing a Type I error – rejecting a null

    hypothesis that in fact is true. The colloquial expression for a scientist’s trepida-

    tion is a strong penchant to endorse the principle of ‘presumed innocent until

    proven guilty’.In most cases, avoiding Type I errors is desirable, but not in all. Firefighters

    who receive notice of a blaze in a wooden building and police who receive a tip

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 269

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    10/22

    about an abandoned package in a public place respond with dispatch, as though

    the fire were actually burning and a real bomb ticking. The high cost of not taking

    immediate action means ignoring the danger of committing a Type II error –

    accepting the null hypothesis when it is actually false. If the fire turns out to be a

    hoax and the bomb a fake, so be it – ‘better safe than sorry’, as the saying goes.A strict aversion to Type I errors endorses a logic that waits for clear evidence

    of harm before taking action – ‘presumed innocent’ trumps ‘better safe than

    sorry’. The problem is that decades may pass before reliable data become avail-

    able. By then the damages inflicted on the environment may be irreversible.

    Faced with this dilemma, Kai Lee (1993) has usefully suggested that we should

    be prepared to recognize those circumstances in which Type I errors are to be

    avoided and situations in which Type II errors are a problem: ‘Their differences

    in logic suggest that it might be possible to sort out situations and to design insti-

    tutions to apply the appropriate burden of proof’ (p. 75).

    The Treatment of Time in Social and Environmental Research

    Sensitivity to the inter-temporal implications of Type I and Type II errors

    clarifies key aspects of the relationship between the conduct of science and the

    enactment of environmental policies. However, limiting discussion to hypothe-

    sis testing focuses only on the mechanics of the scientific enterprise andtherefore overlooks the potential consequences associated with the temporal

    underpinnings of disciplinary specializations. At a more underlying level, it is

    evident that the very logic of the theoretical models that drive the scientific

    process can, by virtue of their temporal premises, incorporate or neglect critical

    considerations. An example is the equilibrium model at the core of neoclassical

    economics, a framework that occupies center stage in the field of environmental

    economics.

    Temporal foundations of models, theories and disciplines

    In the equilibrium model, time must pass for competitive markets to clear

    obstructions ‘in the long run’. But the model itself is timeless in that it does not

    pretend to represent changes in the relationships between variables over time.

    Such changes are treated as disturbances in the ceteris paribus assumptionssurrounding the model as an ‘ideally isolated system,’ not as features of reality tobe described by the model itself. (Gell, 1992: 176)

    Historical contingencies that produce results at variance with the predictions of the abstract model tend to be relegated to the category of transitory disturbances

    on the road to an as yet unrealized equilibrium state.

    270 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    11/22

    The theoretical (and surely political) utility of a ‘timeless’ horizon is not

    limited to neoclassical economists. Analysts in the Marxist-Althusserian tradi-

    tion, in their attempt to secure the materialist framework in the face of contra-

    dictory observations, are fond of asserting that, despite short-term anomalies,

    the economic is determinant in the last instance (see Roxborough, 1979).Ironically, the timeless long run in neoclassical equilibrium models becomes the

    timeless last instance in neo-Marxian historical materialism. Faced with evi-

    dence that contradicts theorized expectations, what remains standing is the con-

    ceptual framework rescued by the invocation of the last instance (or the long

    run) – a mythical future when all shall be revealed. In the meantime, all manner

    of environmental degradation may have occurred and countless species may

    have been lost forever.

    The broader point is that the theoretical models that comprise different

    specializations vary with respect to the manner and the degree to which they payovert attention to temporality (Wood, 2005). Some fields owe their very exist-

    ence to the discovery of a new temporal horizon as in the case of geology, the

    development of which was entirely contingent on the discovery of ‘deep time’

    (McPhee, 1980). Prior to Lyell’s Principles of Geology in 1830, the earth

    sciences were cramped by the temporal compression imposed by the biblical

    chronology. It was only with the postulation of deep time – which envisioned a

    nearly incomprehensible temporal immensity measured in thousands of millions

    of years – that geologists were conceptually positioned to interpret the slow and

    steady operation of erosion and other ordinary processes as the cause of such

    geologic marvels as the Grand Canyon (Gould, 1987).

    The temporal specificity of disciplinary specializations is further illustrated

    by the distinctions biologists make between molecules, cells and tissues, and the

    observation that each analytical focus gives rise, respectively, to the specialized

    fields of molecular biology, cytology and histology. Each field poses different

    questions, the answers to which rely on level and temporally specific theories

    and methods. In this way, the models and methods that distinguish one disci-

    pline from another implicitly channel its practitioners into largely pre-determined levels of analysis (Gibson et al., 2000) and, as a result, instill in them

    an associated temporal horizon.

    Because every specialization has a preferred object of inquiry that is asso-

    ciated with a particular level of analysis and temporal horizon, disciplines

    typically periodize events in very different terms. Meteorologists observe oscil-

    lations in temperature and precipitation that take place at virtually any scale, yet

    the distinctions they draw between ‘microclimate’, ‘weather’ and ‘climate’ con-

    note phenomena that are witnessed over increasingly larger areas and longer

    time spans (Urban et al., 1987). Historians speak of eras, epochs and stages.Economists concerned with prices and production talk of fluctuations that are of 

    varying length or, as in Kondratiev’s (1925) classic study, of cycles that endure

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 271

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    12/22

    half a century. In common parlance, people refer to the short, medium and long

    term, conveniently leaving aside the precise length of time each expression

    invokes.3 The spans of time that depict a given periodization scheme thus make

    sense only with respect to some prior conceptualization of the process at hand.

    The idea that treatments of time are entirely constructed by a theory, concep-tualization or instrumentation within a scientific discipline has profound impli-

    cations for interdisciplinary research. As anyone who has attempted to design an

    integrative study can readily attest, establishing effective trans-disciplinary

    communication between experts in different fields is burdened by theories that

    are incompatible, concepts that have different meanings and methods based on

    different techniques. Less palpable but potentially more pernicious divergences

    stem from the largely implicit temporal bases of competing approaches. A con-

    versation between, say, a wildlife ecologist, a forester and a political scientist is

    therefore likely to be derailed not only by their disparate vocabularies but alsothe fact that the languages spoken by the various participants, like their respec-

    tive orientations to the object of study, are implicitly grounded on conceptual

    clocks that tick at different paces. The frequent result is a temporal mismatch

    between the theories, methods and instruments used by various disciplines

    involved in an integrated study. Mismatches similarly occur between the tempo-

    ral boundaries of conclusions derived from scientific analyses, the formulation

    of intervention initiatives and the time horizons of the institutions charged to

    implement environmental policy (Cumming et al., 2006).

    Temporal hierarchies in ecological systems

    The conscious treatment of time and scale is present in many fields but is

    notably advanced in landscape ecology among researchers who developed ‘hier-

    archy theory’ to analyze complex systems (Allen and Starr, 1982; Ahl and

    Allen, 1996). Hierarchy theory is worth noting in the present context because the

    conceptual approach makes explicit a number of pertinent issues, especially the

    relationship between temporal frequencies and spatial scale.In hierarchy theory, a system is deemed ‘complex’ when it is composed of 

    observable and relatively stable sub-units that are unified by a super-ordinate

    relation.4 Different controls and processes tend to dominate in distinctive levels

    of time and space (Wu, 1999). Each level is governed by level-specific pro-

    cesses and temporal frequencies, the causal logic of which cannot be formulated

    in the languages appropriate to the lower or higher levels in the system. Hence,

    observations made at a single level – a strategy common to most research

    designs – capture only those patterns and processes pertinent to that tier in the

    system. Complexity arises when explanations simultaneously invoke multiplelevels of organization and address the cross-scale dynamics by which variables

    and processes at one level are influenced by those at another.

    272 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    13/22

    Examples of complex hierarchical systems include studies of the Arctic

    tundra in which the lowest level in the hierarchy, and the smallest spatial unit, is

    the individual plant. At a coarser grain, plants compose relatively homogeneous

    patches. Multiple patches, in turn, compose a landscape (Wu and David, 2002).

    The processes characteristic of each level (plant, patch, landscape) functionaccording to different types of causation, spatial extents and temporal frequen-

    cies. The processes that occur at higher levels in the system operate over larger

    areas and at slower temporal frequencies, defined as the amount of time it

    takes for a cycle to be completed and begin anew (Ahl and Allen, 1996). At

    lower levels in the system, the processes operate over small areas and at rapid

    temporal frequencies. The properties observed at a higher level in the hierarchy

    operate so slowly that they can be considered constant, at least for analyses

    cast at lower levels of the system. By the same token, the rapid frequency of 

    processes that occur at the lowest levels of the system represent little morethan background noise relative to higher tiers of interest. In this way, the

    framework recognizes levels of interacting forces so that ‘variables that

    appear to be drivers at one scale may seem constant at another’ (Turner et al.,

    1995: 29).

    Decades of research on regional ecosystems finds that it is the interaction of 

    slow and fast processes that establishes key features of ecosystem structure

    (Holling et al., 2002). Geophysical controls dominate at scales larger than 10

    kilometers. At smaller scales, biotic and abiotic processes control the structure,

    volume and pattern of vegetation (Holling et al., 2002). The arenas within which

    plant and animal-controlling interactions unfold are the same arenas in which

    human activities interact with the landscape (Holling et al., 2002). Terrestrial

    ecosystems are therefore linked at critical levels to social systems, which are

    themselves multileveled and complex.

    Temporal hierarchies in social systems

    Hierarchical reasoning is generally less developed in analyses of social systems,although historians such as Fernand Braudel (1949/1985) and Charles Tilly

    (1984) have made good use of the approach. In his magisterial The Mediter-

    ranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip the Second 

    (1949/1985), Braudel differentiated between la longue durée, conjunctures and

    événements. The first is an inquiry into almost changeless ecological history, ‘a

    history that goes on, tenaciously, as though it were somehow beyond time’s

    reach and ravage’ (Braudel, 1980: 12). Conjunctures concern the tidal move-

    ments of history that depict the rise and fall of civilizations and the gentler

    rhythms of changing social structures. The third level concerns the activities of individual people that are attuned to the ‘short and nervous’ vibrations of daily

    life. For Braudel, the third level of micro-history is only ‘a surface disturbance,

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 273

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    14/22

    the waves stirred up by the powerful movement of the tides that run at a deeper

    and slower pace’ (Braudel, 1980: 74).

    Braudel did not spell out a method for linking one temporal/organizational

    level to another (Tilly, 1984). A more successful attempt can be found in Tamara

    Hareven’s (1982) book, Family Time and Industrial Time, in which the authoruses life-course analysis to understand how the relatively slow cadence of capi-

    talism – manifest in the rise and fall of profits, employment and technology – con-

    ditions the faster rhythms of family cycles and individual behavior. A notable

    advantage of a multileveled framework – be it the Braudel/Hareven approach in

    social history or hierarchy theory in ecology – is to compel a sensitivity to the

    varying spatial and temporal levels that comprise the social and the biophysical

    systems.

    The conceptual and methodological tools for addressing multileveled tempo-

    ralities nonetheless remain largely undeveloped. This limitation is particularlydetrimental to environmental research that treats the social and biophysical

    domains as components of a single social-ecological system. The daunting com-

    plexity of the social-ecological approach makes the need for conceptual clarity

    imperative, especially as it concerns the interaction of the social and biophysical

    systems across and between different levels of space and time (Wood, 2005). In

    the face of such complexity, the concepts that geographers use to depict spatial

    properties suggest temporal analogs that can be usefully invoked to identify

    potential temporal inconsistencies when multiple specializations are brought

    together in integrative social-ecological research.

    Temporal analogs to spatial properties

    As used by geographers and landscape ecologists, grain (or resolution) refers to

    the finest level of spatial resolution possible within a given data set (Turner et

    al., 2001). Grain establishes the threshold between the smallest things captured

    and those that slip unrecorded through the net of observation (Ahl and Allen,

    1996). By the same token, ‘temporal grain’ is the shortest span of time that isrendered meaningful within a given theory, framework or instrumentation.

    The significance of temporal grain becomes evident in studies which find that

    conclusions based on data generated by instruments sensitive to phenomena that

    operate at slow frequencies may differ significantly from conclusions based on

    instruments sensitive to phenomena that operate at rapid frequencies. The

    problem is analogous to research by geographers on the ‘Modifiable Aerial Unit

    Problem’ which found that the conclusions reached at one spatial level change

    significantly when the same analysis is performed over different spatial parti-

    tions (Openshaw, 1984). Every change in spatial resolution brings forth anew problem and there is no basis for assuming that associations existing at one

    scale will also exist at another (McCarty et al., 1956). The modifiable unit

    274 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    15/22

    problem would apply, by analogy, to studies carried out at varying temporal

    grains.

    The idea that conclusions based on data with a large temporal grain may

    change when analysis is performed on data with a smaller temporal grain further

    suggests the notion of a ‘temporal fallacy’, a concept akin to the ecologicalfallacy first noted by Warren Robinson in 1950. In his study of counties in the

    US, Robinson found that the high correlation between the proportion of the

    population that was African-American and the proportion that was illiterate

    (aggregate-level association) did not mean that Blacks were more likely to be

    illiterate (individual-level association), only that illiterate members of both races

    tended to live in the same counties. The analogous temporal fallacy of imputing

    relationships based on coarse temporal grains to relationships at finer temporal

    grains is only beginning to be appreciated.

    The temporal equivalent of geographers’ notion of ‘spatial extent’, the size of the overall study area, is the ‘temporal extent’, the length of time encompassed

    by a given project. A study of the relationship between phytoplankton and zoo-

    plankton abundance in lakes demonstrated the effect of changing a study’s tem-

    poral extent (Carpenter and Kitchell, 1987). Analyses based on a three-day

    sampling frequency found a negative correlation between algal production and

    zooplankton biomass but the correlation was positive when a six-day sampling

    frequency was used. A broadened temporal extent can thus lead to different

    conclusions when processes or outcomes become manifest only after a longer

    period of time, as is often the case with biophysical phenomena.

    Lobbying for longer temporal extents

    Temporal mismatches occur when analyses of slow-paced biophysical pro-

    cesses are based on research designs that rely on time horizons too short to

    produce meaningful results (Tilman, 1989; Risser, 1991). An assessment of eco-

    logical research in the 1980s found that small spatial and short temporal extents

    characterized much of the literature in the field (Wu, 1999). About half of theexperiments published in Ecology were conducted on plots less than a meter in

    diameter (Kareiva and Andersen, 1986) and only 7 per cent of experiments were

    conducted on a timescale greater than five years (Tilman, 1989). The penchant

    for short-term and cross-sectional analyses has also been of concern in the social

    sciences, especially among macro-sociologists in the Marxian tradition who

    lament the temporal myopia common to contemporary social research (York 

    and Clark, 2006). Still, concern about short temporal horizons, when it is

    expressed at all, occurs mainly at the margin of core debates.

    More recent literature in ecology and in the earth sciences indicates a greaterprevalence of studies with wider spatial extents and longer temporal horizons

    (e.g. Redman and Kinzig, 2003; Trosper, 2003).The priority given to long-term

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 275

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    16/22

    social-ecological research is endorsed by prestigious institutions, including the

    National Science Foundation and its support of the Long-Term Ecological

    Research (LTER) Network (Redman et al., 2004). In the pages of Conservation

     Ecology, Gunderson and Folke (2003) similarly promote a ‘science of the long

    view’ which advocates research projects that encompass broad spatial areas andtemporal horizons ranging from centuries to millennia as a means to understand

    how coupled social-ecological systems operate. These initiatives strive to

    establish a temporal alignment between the pace of ecological change and the

    temporal extent of scientific observation and interpretation.

    An inspired if quirky plea for a keener appreciation of longer time horizons

    comes from contemporary visionaries who have seized upon the clock itself as a

    metaphor to reorient people’s temporal thinking to a ‘slower/better’ pace.

    Stewart Brand (1999), board member of The Long Now Foundation, known to

    many as the creator of the Whole Earth Catalog, contends that the goal is todesign a clock that ticks once a year for 10,000 years, gongs once a century and

    cuckoos once a millennium. A working eight-foot high prototype of the ‘Clock 

    of the Long Now’ is on display at the Science Museum of London.5 The device

    will be accompanied by a library that specializes in charting trends that may be

    too slow to notice but transform the environment in the long run. By encourag-

    ing long-range planning and thinking, the clock and the library project have

    caught the eye of leading ecologists (e.g. Holling, 2001) who find themselves

    frustrated by the same short time horizons that The Long Now Foundation

    strives to combat.

    Summary and Conclusion

    The goal of developing an integrative approach that treats society and nature as

    elements of a single complex system is a major challenge facing contemporary

    environmental research. The observations and analyses presented here suggest

    that the process of advancing an integrated social-ecological perspectivecrucially depends on a keen appreciation of the temporal complexities that shape

    the interactions between social and biophysical systems. This study assembled

    examples from a broad range of disciplines to illustrate the varied ways that

    temporal considerations enter into human behavior, the construction of environ-

    mental policy and the conduct of interdisciplinary research.

    The idea that culturally embedded temporal orientations influence the way

    people exploit, manage or conserve natural resources has been firmly docu-

    mented by anthropological research. Analyses have further shown that subjec-

    tive temporalities are influenced by historical forces in ways that both reflectand produce fundamental shifts in how people interact with nature. Attempts to

    influence the relationship between present action and future consequences enter

    276 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    17/22

    into environmental policies via such concepts as the social and political discount

    rate, property rights and the precautionary principle. Similarly, people’s percep-

    tion of their present and future situations play into leading issues in the social

    and environmental sciences, such as the likelihood of social movements, the

    development of social capital and the feasibility of community-based conserva-tion. More generally, it is evident that every disciplinary specialization in the

    social and natural sciences is largely predicated on a preferred level of analysis,

    an associated time horizon and a commitment to time and level-dependant con-

    cepts and methods. In this way, the models and instruments that distinguish one

    discipline from another tend to channel practitioners into largely predetermined

    levels of analysis. These, in turn, invoke a host of time-dependent methods that

    register events and relationships which only occur within delimited temporal

    frequencies. When the temporal foundations of disciplinary specializations go

    unrecognized, the oversight can lead to temporal mismatches between thetheories, concepts and instruments that contribute to an integrated study, and to

    mismatches between the findings of scientific work and the time horizons of 

    institutions that implement environmental policy. The likelihood of temporal

    inconsistencies can be mitigated by giving attention to three concepts developed

    here: temporal grain, temporal fallacy and temporal extent. These observations

    underscore the idea that the process of advancing an integrated social-ecological

    perspective crucially depends on a pointed recognition of the way that time,

    cycles and tempos shape the interactions between social and biophysical sys-

    tems.

    Notes

    This study is a revised and expanded version of a paper presented at a conference that cel-ebrated Stephen Bunker’s contribution to sociology called  Nature, Raw Materials and Political Economy, held in Madison, Wisconsin on 2 November 2002. I am grateful forhelpful comments provided by Emilio Bruna, Karen Kainer, Derek Lewis, Peggy Lovell,

    Elisa Maranzana, Marianne Schmink, Rick Stepp, Dan Zarin and Ana Siqueira, none of whom bears responsibility for this version.

    1. The punctual integration of social activities into stable and impersonal schedulesbecame a necessity with the advent of metropolitan life (Urry, 2000). The previousunimagined need for regimentation and co-ordination of activities prompted thestandardization of time, first initiated by railroad companies frustrated by the localtime zones that stood in the way of sensible timetables. Stations only a few miles apartset their clocks to different standards such that trains moving down the track wouldsometimes lurch backward into the past only to bound forward again upon arriving at

    the next platform (Levine, 1997). The four time zones we recognize in the US todaywere established in 1883 by the railroads and were put into law by the federal govern-ment in 1918.

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 277

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    18/22

    2. In a similar vein, John Hall (1978) found that ‘communal groups based on a dia-chronic scheduling of clock time . . . had difficulty marshaling members’ commitmentbeyond that required for performance of scheduled duties and for this reason groupsolidarity was problematic’ (p. 215). The communities most likely to survive werethose whose members shared an apocalyptic conception of history in which truebelievers construed their temporal existence as lying beyond the present in a timelesseternity. ‘The social temporality of action thus proved to have objective consequencesin objective time’ (Hall, 1984: 215).

    3. Although limited to students at the University of Missouri-Columbia, one study docu-mented the lengths of time that people associate with ‘short-term’, ‘mid-term’ and‘long-term’ time horizons (Bluedorn, 2002). Over half (55.5%) defined the short termas three months or less. As for the long term, close to half (45.1%) defined it as beingten or more years ahead.

    4. So burdened is the word ‘hierarchy’ by the common meaning of rigid, top-downauthority and control that ecologists have proposed the term ‘panarchy’ (from theGreek god, Pan, universal god of nature) to capture the adaptive and evolutionarynature of multileveled systems (Gunderson and Holling, 2002: 74).

    5. To see pictures and architectural drawings of the clock, go to http://www.longnow.org.

    References

    Adam, B. (1995) Timewatch: The Social Analysis of Time. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Adam, B. (1998) Timescapes of Modernity: The Environment and Invisible Hazards.London and New York: Routledge.

    Agrawal, A. (1997) Community in Conservation: Beyond Enchantment and Disenchant-ment (Discussion Paper). Gainesville, FL: Conservation and Development Forum(CDF).

    Ahl, V. and Allen, T. F. H. (1996) Hierarchy Theory: A Vision, Vocabulary and Epistem-ology. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H. (1973) ‘The Property Rights Paradigm’,  Journal of  Economic History 33: 16–27.

    Allen, T. F. H. and Starr, T. B. (1982)  Hierarchy: Perspectives for Ecological Com-

     plexity. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Appell, D. (2001) ‘The New Uncertainty Principle’, Scientific American (January):

    18–19. Available at: http://www.sciam.com/article.cfm?articleID=000C3111-2859-1C71-84A9809EC588EF21&catID=2.

    Beaumont, P. M. and Walker, R. T. (1994) ‘Land Degradation and Property Regimes’, Ecological Economics 18: 55–66.

    Bluedorn, A. C. (2002) The Human Organization of Time: Temporal Realities and  Experience. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Brainard, J. (2002) ‘U.S. Agencies Look to Interdisciplinary Science’, The Chronicle of  Higher Education 6/14. Available at: http://chronicle.com/weekly/v48/i40/40a02001.

    htm.Brand, S. (1999) The Clock of the Long Now: Time and Responsibility. New York: Basic

    Books.

    278 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    19/22

    Braudel, F. (1949/1985)  La Méditerranée et le Monde Méditerranéen à l’époque dePhilippe II [The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip theSecond] (6th edn). Paris: Armand Colin.

    Braudel, F. (1980) On History. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Carpenter, S. R. and Kitchell, J. F. (1987) ‘Plankton Community Structure and Limnetic

    Primary Production’, American Naturalist 124: 159–72.Chasteen, J. C. (2001) Born in Blood and Fire: A Concise History of Latin America. New

    York: W. W. Norton.Cobb, J. B. (2005) ‘The Responsibility of Progressive Protestants’, Conservation Biology

    19(2): 294.Cumming, G. S., Cumming, D. M. and Redman, C. L. (2006) ‘Scale Mismatches in Social-

    ecological Systems: Causes, Consequences and Solutions’ Ecology and Society 11: 14.Durkheim, E. (1915/1964) The Elementary Forms of the Religious Life. London: George

    Allen and Unwin.Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (1940) The Nuer: A Description of the Modes of Livelihood and 

    Political Institutions of a Nolitic People. London: Oxford University Press.Farber, D. A. and Hemmersbaugh, P. A. (1993) ‘The Shadow of the Future: Discount

    Rates, Later Generations, and the Environment’, Vanderbilt Law Review 46: 267–304.

    Feder, G. (1987) ‘Land Ownership Security and Farm Productivity: Evidence fromThailand’, Journal of Development Studies 24: 16–30.

    Foweraker, J. (1995) Theorizing Social Movements. Boulder, CO: Pluto Press.Gell, A. (1992) The Anthropology of Time: Cultural Constructions of Temporal Maps

    and Images. Providence, RI: Berg Publishers Limited.Gellert, P. (2005) ‘For a Sociology of “socionature”: Ontology and the Commodity-

    based Approach’, in P. S. Ciccantell, D. A. Smith and G. Seidman (eds) Nature, Raw Materials, and Political Economy (Vol. 10), pp. 65–91. New York: Elsevier.

    Gibson, C. C., Ostrom, E. and Ahn, T-K. (2000) ‘The Concept of Scale and the HumanDimensions of Global Change: A Survey’, Ecological Economics 32: 217–39.

    Goldsmith, A. A. (2004) ‘Predatory Versus Developmental Rule in Africa’,  Democra-tization 11(3): 89–110.

    Gould, S. J. (1987) Time’s Arrow, Time’s Cycle: Myth and Metaphor in the Discovery of Geological Time. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Goulder, L. H. and Stavins, R. N. (2002) ‘Discounting: An Eye on the Future’,  Nature419(17, October): 673–74.

    Gunderson, L. and Folke, C. (2003) ‘Toward a “Science of the Long View”’, Conserva-tion Ecology 7(1): 15. Available at: http://www.consecol.org/vol7/iss1/art15/.

    Gunderson, L. H. and Holling C. S. (eds) (2002) Panarchy: Understanding Trans- formations in Human and Natural Systems. Washington DC: Island Press.

    Hall, J. R. (1978) The Ways Out: Utopian Communal Groups in an Age of Babylon.London: Verso.

    Hall, J. R. (1984) ‘Temporality, Social Action, and the Problem of Quantification inHistorical Analysis’, Historical Methods 17(4): 206–18.

    Hareven, T. K. (1982) Family Time and Industrial Time. London: Cambridge UniversityPress.

    Harremöes, P., Gee, D., MacGarvin, M., Stirling, A., Keys, J., Wynne, B. and GuedesVaz, S. (2000) The Precautionary Principle in the 20th Century: Late Lessons from Early Warnings. Copenhagen: European Environment Agency.

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 279

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    20/22

    Henderson, D. (2005) ‘Evangelicals are Conservationists’, Conservation Biology 19(6):1687–88.

    Holling, C. S. (2001) ‘Understanding the Complexity of Economic, Ecological, andSocial Systems’, Ecosystems 4: 300–505.

    Holling, C. S., Gunderson, L. H. and Ludwig, D. (2002) ‘In Quest of a Theory of Adap-tive Change’, in L. H. Gunderson and C. S. Holling (eds) Panarchy: UnderstandingTransformations in Human and Natural Systems, pp. 3–22. London: Island Press.

    Holling, C. S. Gunderson, L. H. and Peterson, G. D. (2002) ‘Sustainability and Pan-archies’, in L. H. Gunderson and C. S. Holling (eds) Panarchy: Understanding Trans- formations in Human and Natural Systems, pp. 63–102. London: Island Press.

    Kareiva, P. and Andersen, M. (1986) ‘Spatial Aspects of Species Interactions: TheWeddings of Models and Experiments’, in A. Hastings (ed.) Community Ecology,pp. 35–50. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Kondratiev, N. (1925) ‘The Major Economic Cycles’, Voprosy Konjunktury (1): 28–79.[English translation in (1935) Review of Economic Statistics (18): 105–15.]

    Krech III, S. (1999) The Ecological Indian: Myth and History. New York: W. W. Norton.Larson, B. A. and Bromley, D. W. (1990) ‘Property Rights, Externalities and Resource

    Degradation’, Journal of Developing Economics 33: 235–62.Lee, K. N. (1993) Compass and Gyroscope: Integrating Science and Politics for the

     Environment. Washington DC: Island Press.Levine, R. (1997) A Geography of Time. New York: Basic Books.Lyons, O. (1980) ‘An Iroquois Perspective’, in C. Yecsey and R. W. Venables (eds)

     American Indian Environments: Ecological Issues in Native American History,pp. 171–4. New York: Syracuse University Press.

    McCarty, H. H., Hook, J. C. and Knos, D. S. (1956) The Measurement of Association in

     Industrial Geography. Ames, IA: University of Iowa.McPhee, J. (1980) Basin and Range. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Merton, R. (1984) ‘Socially Expected Durations: A Case Study of Concept Formation in

    Sociology’, in W. W. Powell and R. Robbins (eds) Conflict and Consensus: In Honor of Lewis A. Coser , pp. 362–83. New York: Free Press.

    Newell, B., Crumley, C. L., Hassan, N., Lambin, E. F., Pahl-Wostl, C., Underdal, A. andWasson, R. (2005) ‘A Conceptual Template for Integrative Human-environmentalResearch’, Global Environmental Change 15: 299–307.

    Nilsson, M. P. (1920) Primitive Time-reckoning. Lund: Gleerup.Openshaw, S. (1984) ‘The Modifiable Aerial Unit Problem’, Concepts and Techniques in

     Modern Geography, 38. Norwich: GeoBooks.Orr, D. (2005) ‘Armageddon Versus Extinction’, Conservation Biology 19(2): 290–92.Paz, O. (1985) The Labyrinth of Solitude. New York: Grove Weidenfeld.Peterson, A. L. (2001) Being Human: Ethics, Environment, and Our Place in the World.

    Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Portes, A. (1998) ‘Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology’,

     Annual Review of Sociology 24(1): 1–24.Putnam, R. (1993)  Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.

    Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Redford, K. H. (1991) ‘The Ecologically Noble Savage’, Cultural Survival Quarterly

    15(1): 46–8.Redman, C. L. and Kinzig, A. P. (2003) ‘Resilience of Past Landscapes: Resilience

    Theory, Society and the Longue Duré ’, Conservation Ecology 7(1): 14. Available at:

    280 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    21/22

    http://www.consecol.org/vol17/iss1/art14.Redman, C. L., Morgan Grove, J. and Kuby, L. H. (2004) ‘Integrating Social Science into

    the Long-term Ecological Research (LTER) Network: Social Dimensions of Eco-logical Change and Ecological Dimensions of Social Change’, Ecosystems 7: 161–71.

    Rhoten, D. (2004) ‘Interdisciplinary Research: Trend or Transition?’,  Items: SocialScience Research Council (SSRC) 5(1–2): 6–11.

    Rifkin, J. (1987) Time Wars. New York: Simon and Schuster.Risser P. G. (1991) Long-term Ecological Research: An International Perspective. New

    York: Wiley.Roberts, B. (1995) ‘Socially Expected Durations and the Economic Adjustment of 

    Immigrants’, in A. Portes (ed.) The Economic Sociology of Immigration, pp. 42–86.New York: Russell Sage.

    Robinson, W. (1950) ‘Ecological Correlations and the Behavior of Individuals’, Ameri-can Sociological Review 15: 351–7.

    Roxborough, I. (1979) Theories of Underdevelopment. London: Macmillan Press.Schmink, M. and Wood, C. H. (1992) Contested Frontiers in Amazonia. New York:

    Columbia University Press.Stuart, S. N. (2005) ‘Conservation Theology for Conservation Biologists: A Reply to

    David Orr’, Conservation Biology 19(6): 1689–92.Thompson, E. P. (1967) ‘Time, Work-discipline and Industrial Capitalism’, Past and 

    Present 38: 56–96.Tilly, C. (1984) Big Structures, Large Processes, Huge Comparisons. New York: Russell

    Sage Foundation.Tilman, D. (1989) ‘Ecological Experimentation: Strengths and Conceptual Problems’, in

    G. E. Likens (ed.) Long-Term Studies in Ecology: Approaches and Alternatives, pp.

    136–57. New York: Springer-Verlag.Trosper, R. L. (2003) ‘Resilience in Pre-contact Pacific Northwest Social Ecological

    Systems’, Conservation Ecology 7(3): 6. Available at: http://www.consecol.org/ vol17/iss3/art6.

    Turner II, B. L., Skole, D., Sanderson, S., Fischer, G., Fresco, L. and Leemans, R. (1995) Land Use and Land-Cover Change: Science/Research Plan. Geneva: The Inter-national Geosphere-Biosphere Programme (IGBP) and the Human Dimensions of Global Environmental Change Programme (HDP) of the International Social ScienceCouncil (ISSC).

    Turner, M. G., Gardner, R. H. and O’Neill, R. V. (2001)  Landscape Ecology in Theory

    and Practice. New York: Springer-Verlag.Urban, D. L., O’Neill, R. V. and Shugart Jr, H. H. (1987) ‘Landscape Ecology: A

    Hierarchical Perspective Can Help Scientists Understand Spatial Patterns’,  Bio-Science 37(2): 119–27.

    Urry, J. (2000) Sociology Beyond Societies: Mobilities for the Twenty-first Century.London: Routledge.

    Van Dyke, F. (2005) ‘Between Heaven and Earth: Evangelical Engagement inConservation’, Conservation Biology 19(6): 1693.

    Wachter, D. (1992) Farmland Degradation in Developing Countries: The Role of Property Rights and an Assessment of Land Titling as a Policy Intervention (Land

    Tenure Center Paper 145). Madison: University of Wisconsin-Madison.WCED (The World Commission on Environment and Development) (1987) Our 

    Common Future. New York: Oxford University Press.

    WOOD: TIME, C YC LE S AN D T EM PO S 281

     at CIESAS - Parent on November 12, 2015tas.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

    http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/http://tas.sagepub.com/

  • 8/16/2019 21.- Wood, Charles H.

    22/22

    Wilson, E. O. (2006) The Creation: An Appeal to Save Life on Earth. New York: W. W.Norton.

    Wood, C. H. (2005) ‘Keeping Time: Temporal Hierarchies in Socio-ecological Systems’,in P. S. Ciccantell, D. A. Smith and G. Seidman (eds)  Nature, Raw Materials, and Political Economy (Vol. 10), pp. 93–112. New York: Elsevier.

    Wu, J. (1999) ‘Hierarchy and Scaling: Extrapolating Along a Scaling Ladder’, Canadian Journal of Remote Sensing 25(4): 367–80.

    Wu, J. and David, J. L. (2002) ‘A Spatially Explicit Hierarchical Approach to ModelingComplex Ecological Systems: Theory and Applications’,  Ecological Modelling153(7): 7–26.

    York, R. and Clark, B. (2006) ‘Marxism, Positivism, and Scientific Sociology: SocialGravity and Historicity’, Sociological Quarterly 47: 425–50.

    CHARLES H. WOOD is a member and former Director of the Center forLatin American Studies at the University of Florida in Gainesville, Florida.His research focuses on the causes and consequences of deforestation in theBrazilian Amazon. ADDRESS: Center for Latin American Studies,University of Florida, 319 Grinter Hall, Gainesville, FL 32611–5530, USA.[email: [email protected]]

    282 TIME & SOCIETY 17(2/3)