207.full

download 207.full

of 11

description

207

Transcript of 207.full

  • Previous School Results and SocialBackground: Compensation and ImperfectInformation in Educational Transitions

    Fabrizio Bernardi1,* and Hector Cebolla-Boado2

    Abstract: In this article, we analyse whether previous school results have a social background-specific

    impact on a students decision to continue in schooling. We refer to the model proposed by Breen and

    Goldthorpe (1997) and scrutinize the theoretical underpinnings of the interaction between previous

    school performance and educational choices. We provide two sets of predictions. First, a compensatory

    effect might occur if inequality is greater among the worst-performing students than among others. In

    this case, students from socio-economically advantaged backgrounds with poor school results would still

    move to higher educational levels, whereas students from socio-economically disadvantaged back-

    grounds with poor school results would drop out. Second, inequality might be higher among average

    performers. Both good and poor school results send stronger messages and clearer information than

    scores in the middle of the distribution. If individuals from different socio-economic backgrounds

    handle imperfect information differently, then the impact of social background could be larger on

    average grades than on good or poor ones. To test these hypotheses, we used the French Panel dEle`ves

    du Second Degre and focused on social background differences in the decision to opt for the academic

    or the vocational track after the completion of compulsory education. Our findings support the

    hypothesis of a compensatory effect. In the conclusion, we discuss further general implications of our

    results for research on educational inequality.

    Introduction

    A key tenet in the research on educational inequality is

    that grades, as well as any alternative proxy of previous

    school performance, are used by families to infer the

    probability of success when facing critical branching

    points in the education system (Boudon, 1974). Little

    attention has, however, been paid to differences in the

    impact of academic performance on future educational

    choices across social backgrounds. It is true, on the one

    hand, that some studies have discussed the empirical

    relevance of an interaction between social background

    and academic performance, either as a built-in compo-

    nent of the specific decomposition method employed, or

    as robustness checks. Yet, on the other hand, the

    theoretical reasons as to why previous school results

    might impact differently depending on social back-

    ground have not been fully scrutinized. The main

    contribution of the present article is to fill this gap in

    the literature and to provide behavioural evidence on

    how families of diverse social standings react differently

    to similar childrens performance in school. As we argue,

    our findings also hold important implications for the

    model of educational transitions proposed by Breen and

    Goldthorpe (1997).The main question that we address in this article is

    whether previous school results have a social background

    specific impact on a students decision to continue

    in schooling. We provide two sets of predictions. A

    compensatory effect occurs if the transition probabilities

    for upper-class students are less dependent on previous

    performance than those of students of lower socio-

    economic standing. In that case, students of higher

    socio-economic standing with poor school results still

    proceed to higher educational levels or onto more

    prestigious educational tracks, whereas lower-class

    1SPS, EUI, Via dei Roccettini 9, San Domenico di Fiesole, 50014 Florence, Italy; 2UNED, Sociology department II,

    Calle Obispo Trejo s/n, 28040 Madrid, Spain. *Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

    European Sociological Review VOLUME 30 NUMBER 2 2014 207217 207DOI:10.1093/esr/jct029, available online at www.esr.oxfordjournals.org

    Online publication 11 October 2013

    The Author 2013. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.For permissions, please e-mail: [email protected]. Submitted: March 2013; revised: July 2013; accepted: August 2013.

  • students with poor school results are more prone todrop out or to opt for less-demanding educationaltracks. Social background inequality in educationaltransitions would then be higher among poorly per-forming students. A compensatory effect might comeabout because upper-class students have a strongerincentive to pursue ambitious school careers to avoidsocial demotion, largely independent of the low estimatesof the likelihood of their success (Lucas, 2009).Moreover, upper-class families have the necessary eco-nomic, social, and cultural resources to compensate forprevious poor school results.

    Alternatively, inequality might be higher among aver-age performers. The results on the extremes of theachievement distribution might send stronger and clearermessages than scores in the middle of the distribution.When students attain average results, their families mightbe less able to infer from their childs current perform-ance their chances of succeeding at the next stage, whichcan amplify the impact of social origin.

    To test these predictions, we used the French PaneldEle`ves du Second Degre, a longitudinal cohort studythat followed students joining compulsory secondaryschool in 1995. We focused on social class differences inthe decision to opt for the academic or vocational trackafter the completion of compulsory education.Additionally, we examined whether and how thesedifferences are conditioned by previous performance.

    The remainder of the article is structured as follows:In the next section, we present the theory andhypotheses that drive our work. A short description ofthe French school system follows. The fourth section isdevoted to the presentation of our dataset, followed by adiscussion of the empirical findings. The concludingsection provides a summary of our results and adiscussion of their implications for the Breen andGoldthorpe (1997) model and for social stratificationresearch.

    Relative Risk Aversion, SubjectiveProbability of Success, andResources

    The Breen and Goldthorpe model (1997) (henceforth,BG model) proposes three mechanisms through whichclass differences in educational outcomes might origin-ate. These mechanisms are Relative Risk Aversion (RRA),differences in abilities and expectations of success, anddifferences in resources. We elaborate on each of thesemechanisms to understand whether and why the impactof previous results on decisions to continue in schoolmight vary depending on social background.

    Relative Risk Aversion

    A central assumption in the BG model is that students

    and their families aim to achieve an educational level

    that minimizes the risk of downward social mobility. A

    corollary of this assumption is that students of higher

    socio-economic standing will continue in education

    when their probability of accessing the higher social

    classes, either after completion of the next educational

    level or after failing to do so, is higher than the

    probability of accessing the higher social classes after

    dropping directly out of education. Formally:

    i 1 i > 1where i is the expected probability of success incompleting the next educational level; is the probabil-ity of accessing the higher social classes if the next

    educational level is completed; (1i) is the probabilityof failing to complete the next educational level; is theprobability of accessing the service class despite not

    having completed the next educational level; and is theprobability of accessing the higher social classes having

    dropped out of education.Based on (1), Lucas (2009) demonstrates that the RRA

    implies that students of higher socio-economic standing

    might discontinue education only under specific condi-

    tions, namely, when is smaller than .1 This indicatesthat the students might drop out only if they think that

    their chances of occupational success are higher if they

    leave education than if they stay in school and fail. Even

    in that case, the students would still stay in education if

    i and were sufficiently high. In any case, upper-classstudents of higher socio-economic standing will leave

    school only when they perceive that their chances of

    occupational success, and of avoiding downward mobil-

    ity, are higher by leaving than by staying in school

    (regardless of whether they fail or complete the next

    educational level). This specific situation is labelled by

    Lucas (2009) as the Gates Gambit, as the story of the

    famous college dropout, Bill Gates, exemplifies. Despite a

    high probability of success in education (i), the expectedoccupation returns without education () might behigher than the estimated future returns, both in the

    event of failure () or success () in completinguniversity education.

    Lucas (2009) formal analysis provided us with the

    insight that for the large majority of students of higher

    socio-economic standing, their decision to continue or

    not in schooling is largely independent of the probability

    of success at the next educational level. Except under the

    very specific conditions epitomized by the Gates Gambit,

    the aversion to downward mobility will always make it

    more convenient for students of higher socio-economic

    208 BERNARDI AND CEBOLLA-BOADO

  • standing to stay in school, regardless of their previous

    performance.

    The Differences in Abilities and the

    Probability of Success

    As previously mentioned, the subjective probability offuture success in education, i, is one of the keyparameters in the BG model. In general terms, the higheri, the higher the probability of continuing in education.Moreover, the subjective probability of future success isinterpreted as a function of manifested abilities in a

    previous examination or the final grades at the previous

    educational level (Breen and Goldthorpe, 1997).Formally,

    i g ai 2where ai refers to previous school results.

    A rather undertheorized assumption of the BG model

    is that the function g is the same for all social classes. Inother words, when given similar school results, families

    of different social classes would infer a similar subjective

    probability of success at the next educational level.However, if one follows Breen (1999), the subjective

    probability of success at the next educational level can beconceived of as a function of two factors: the individual

    effort a student has made so far, and an ascriptive factorrelated to the individuals innate ability. Thus, a family

    interprets previous school results as a combination of

    effort and ability. Formally,

    i g ai gai Ii ei 3where Ii stands for individual ability and ei represents

    effort. Framed in this way, class-specific differences inschool continuation rates might also stem from different

    values attributed to and . A poor performance mightbe disregarded as an indicator of likely subsequent failurethe smaller is, or if one believes that the poorperformance was caused by limited effort, which can becorrected in the future. Alternatively, if poor perform-

    ance is interpreted as a reflection of limited individual

    abilitythat is, if more weight is given to Ii (large )then there is less room for improvement at the next

    educational level. Recent experimental work in socialpsychology shows that academic success among high-

    status groups and failure among low-status groups areattributed to ability, whereas academic failure among

    high-status and success among low-status groups tend to

    be attributed to effort (Iatridis and Fousiani, 2009). In anutshell, if the view that poor school performance of

    upper-class students is interpreted as the result of a lackof effort, its negative implication on school continuation

    decisions can be expected to be smaller.

    Another mechanism that could have an impact is the

    information that school results convey to families. Both

    good and poor school results send clear messages to

    families concerning the likelihood of their children

    succeeding at higher stages of the educational system,

    while scores in the middle of the distribution might be

    more difficult to interpret. When faced with middling

    results, families of lower socio-economic standing might

    interpret this differently to those of higher standing. In a

    scenario of incomplete information, lower-class families

    might overestimate the level of selectivity of the next

    educational level, undercutting their childs potential

    ambition to pursue further education. Formally,

    i g ai,k 4where k is the perceived threshold in academic perform-

    ance that has to be met to complete the next educational

    level. The subjective probability of future success i willthen depend on the comparison between previous school

    performance and k. Some uncertainty about the exact

    value of k can, however, be supposed. Students with very

    high or low previous performance are less likely to be

    influenced by this uncertainty, the former group being

    convinced of their ability to surpass the threshold as

    opposed to what happens within the latter group. We

    can also factor in the idea that upper-class families are

    likely to possess a better knowledge about k, given their

    own school experience, their higher level of involvement

    in their childrens schooling, and their more frequent

    interactions with teachers (Lareau, 1987). The crucial

    point, then, is whether lower-class families overestimate

    or underestimate k. If self-justification strategies are

    assumed, one can expect that parents who have not

    completed a given level of education will tend to

    overestimate k as a way to justify their low educational

    achievement.2 To sum up, if high- and low-performing

    students are not affected by the uncertainty in k, while

    lower-class families tend to overestimate k, then larger

    class inequality can be expected among students with

    average school performances.

    Resources

    Differences in resources do not play a key role in the BG

    and are mainly conceived as economic resources to meet

    the costs of education. Cultural and social resources,

    however, in addition to economic ones, might play a

    crucial role in compensating the effect of previous failure

    or mediocre performance at school. For example,

    because of their superior financial and cultural resources,

    upper-class families could provide extra support to their

    childrens schooling. These families can, for instance, pay

    for private tuition or help with homework assistance.

    PREVIOUS SCHOOL RESULTS AND SOCIAL BACKGROUND 209

  • Additionally, their knowledge of the education system

    and their social contacts can also help to identify the

    ideal school for their offspring (for example, less selective

    institutions with fewer students and special

    programmes).Differences in economic, cultural, and social resources

    across social classes would then complement the RRA

    mechanism and the micro-psychological mechanism for

    rationalization of a previous failure discussed in the

    previous section. To summarize, parents of higher socio-

    economic standing have great interest in avoiding

    downward social mobility and tend to interpret a

    previous failure as the result of a lack of effort. They

    thus believe that the lack of effort can be compensated

    for, and also have the resources to pursue such

    compensation.

    Summary of Hypotheses

    Empirical tests of the BG model have modelled the

    effects of motivational factors related to the RRA

    mechanism and the effects of observed school perform-

    ance in an additive manner (Need and de Jong, 2001;

    Van de Werfhorst and Hofstede, 2007; Gabay-Egozi,

    Shavit and Yaish, 2010). However, our previous dis-

    cussion of the BG model suggests different mechanisms

    that could possibly invalidate the assumption that school

    performance and social background effect related to

    status maintenance affect transitions in an additive

    manner. We call these mechanisms compensatory

    effects and incomplete information. These mechanisms

    imply an interaction between the parameters modelling

    performance and the social background in making actual

    choices. In other words, when facing similar school

    results, people of different classes might behave differ-

    ently and, accordingly, make different school continu-

    ation choices.A compensatory effect occurs if the upper-class students

    move onto the next educational level (or onto a more

    demanding academic track), disregarding low levels of

    previous performance. This effect is predicted by the

    RRA mechanism. In almost all situations, the fear of

    downward mobility for upper-class students will make it

    more attractive to continue in school, regardless of their

    previous performance and their subjectively estimated

    probability of failure. In contrast to upper-class students,

    for those of lower socio-economic standing, the BG

    model implies that past performance and its impact on

    the subjective estimation of the probability of success is a

    key parameter in their decision to continue in schooling

    or not. Moreover, those of higher standing tend to

    interpret school performance in terms of effort instead of

    innate ability, thus making school continuation more

    likely for this group, despite previous poor school

    results. Finally, advantaged students have the social,

    cultural, and economic resources to pursue compensa-

    tion strategies. Figure 1 provides a graphic illustration of

    the compensatory effect. The Y-axis refers to the

    probability of staying in school, while the X-one refers

    to previous performance at school. Figure 1 shows that

    the probability for the upper-class group is rather

    inelastic to previous performance. This graphically

    summarizes our first hypothesis, namely, the compensa-

    tory effect, according to which the largest inequality in

    the probability of school continuation between classes

    should be observed among the low-performing students.Alternatively, inequality might be higher in the middle

    ranks of the range of grades. The specific cause of this is

    that whereas good and bad grades send clear messages to

    families regarding estimated chances in subsequent stages

    of the educational system, scores in the middle of the

    distribution are more difficult to interpret. If facing

    imperfect information, families of lower standing could

    over-estimate k and the level of selectivity of the next

    educational level. Figure 2 illustrates this second hy-

    pothesis. klower and kupper refer to these perceived

    thresholds for those of lower and higher socio-economic

    standing, respectively. The probability of the children of

    lower-standing families making the transition remains

    low until the grades surpass the threshold klower. In

    contrast, upper-class families set the threshold at a lower

    level, and their probability of making the transition

    begins to rise accordingly for a lower value of school

    performance. As a consequence, a larger inequality

    should be expected for average academic performance.

    This summarizes our incomplete information hypothesis.

    The French Educational System

    In France, compulsory education covers elementary

    (ecole elementaire) and lower secondary school (colle`ge)

    up to age 16. Throughout this period, the system is

    comprehensively organized. Post-compulsory upper sec-

    ondary education is subsequently divided into three

    tracks. The lycee general et technologique (general and

    technological upper secondary school) provides general

    and abstract training and represents the most straight-

    forward path to university. The lycee professionnel

    provides the Brevet detudes professionnelles (BEP) after

    2 years. Students on this track can proceed to the

    adaptation course (1 year) that bridges to the profes-

    sional and technical lycee, although this alternative is

    scarcely used. The other vocational credential is the

    Certificat daptitude professionnelle (CAP), which prepares

    the student for a specific occupation and is a direct path

    210 BERNARDI AND CEBOLLA-BOADO

  • to the labour market. This track does not allow the

    possibility of a Baccalaureat (BAC) degree.The selection of students at the end of lower

    secondary education onto the academic track (General

    or Technological Lycees) or the vocational one (BEP and

    CAP) is the critical junction of the French school system.

    Previous studies have indeed shown that the outcome of

    this educational transition largely conditions the later

    opportunities to access university, and that large differ-

    ences exist between the social classes of origin in the

    distribution of students between the academic and

    vocational tracks (Merle, 2002).The tracking of students onto the academic and

    vocational tracks is decided during the so-called proce`s

    dorientation, which takes place at the end the final year

    of colle`ge. After consultation with the families, a class

    council formed by teachers and inspectors makes

    decisions based on the students previous academic

    achievement and the explicit wishes of the families. The

    students academic achievement is evaluated through anational examination called Brevet des colle`ges as well astheir school results in the last year of colle`ge. The aim ofthe Brevet is to certify the level of academic achievementat the end of colle`ge, but its results do not formallycondition access to post-compulsory upper education.The proce`s dorientation was intended to reduce classbias in the distribution of students across differenttracks (Duru-Bellat and Van Zanten, 1999). However, anumber of studies have shown that the families explicitpreferences are given greater weighting and that thisamplifies social background inequality (Roux andDavaillon, 2001; Merle, 2002).

    Data and Variables

    The Panel dEle`ves du Second Degre (19952001) sampleda cohort of 17,830 students who started lower secondaryschool in 1995. The questionnaire de recrutement wascompleted in 1995 using administrative files. It includesbasic demographic information, such as sex, place anddate of birth, and nationality. A number of follow-upquestionnaires collected yearly information on academicprogress and school careerssuivi de la scolarite delele`ve. At the end of lower secondary schooling (3e`me),the heads of the schools completed another question-naire with detailed information concerning grades andthe result of the selective process that links lower andupper secondary schooling (procedure dorientation). Afollow-up questionnaire a year later allowed the head ofschools to check whether students ultimately droppedout or accepted the placement proposed at the end ofcompulsory schooling.

    We have restricted the analysis to students born inFrance (N 17,161). The bottom line of Table 1 reportsthe loss of cases from the original to the analyticalsample. The sizeable reduction in the number of cases inthe analytic sample (N 12,670) is due to the largenumber of observations with missing information on thegrades at the end of lower secondary schooling (Brevetscores). However, it is reassuring that the distribution ofthe primary independent variables (gender and socialclass of origin) in Table 1 is very similar in the analyticsample and in the original sample. Moreover, wereplicated all of the analyses, including an additionalcategory for those cases with missing values on Brevet.Our primary finding also turns out to be highly robustin this larger sample (N 15,741; see online Table A1).Thus, we are confident that our conclusions, based onthe analytic sample, are reliable.

    Our dependent variable is the track that the studentfollowed in upper secondary school. As we have arguedin the previous section, Table 1 shows that 40 per cent

    Lower class

    Upper class

    Previous grades kupper klower

    Probability of making the transition

    Figure 2 Incomplete information: inequality is greater foraverage grades

    Previous grades

    Probability of making the transition

    Lower class

    Upper class

    Figure 1 Compensatory class effect: inequality is greateramong those with poor grades

    PREVIOUS SCHOOL RESULTS AND SOCIAL BACKGROUND 211

  • of the students who did not drop out went intovocational training; in contrast, 60 per cent of thestudents opted for the academic track. Our dependentvariable takes the value of 1 if the student proceedstowards the academic track (Seconde Generale etTechnologique) and 0 if the student chooses any of thevocational tracks (professional lycee, first-year BEP, orCAP).

    As for our independent variables, we use the averagegrades obtained in the Brevet des Colle`ges forMathematics and French as the key indicators ofprevious school performance. The mean of Brevetscores can range from 0 to 20. In our sample, theminimum value is 4, the maximum value is 17, andthe average value is 11. In addition to the continuousvalue for the individual average in the Brevet scores, wehave defined three dummy variables that refer to thedistribution of the Brevet scores in tertiles. Thus, anindividual receives a score of 1 on the dummy firsttertile if his/her average in Brevet score in French andMath falls within the first tertile of the Brevet scoredistribution.3 Social class of origin refers to the occupa-tion of the head of the household when the student was12 years old, and it is coded using the Erikson and

    Goldthorpe class scheme with six categories. These arethe upper class (that includes professionals and man-agers), routine non-manual employees of higher grade,petty-bourgeoisie (small proprietors with and withoutemployees), farmers, routine employees of lower grade,and skilled and unskilled manual workers. In comment-ing on the results, we focus on the comparison betweenthe top and the bottom categories, i.e., the upper classand the skilled and unskilled manual workers, thattogether include 50 per cent of the population.

    We estimated a number of linear probability models(LPMs) with robust standard errors and logit models.The coefficients of the LPM are almost identical to theaverage marginal effects of the logit model. The advan-tage of the LPM over the logit model is not only that theinterpretation of marginal effect of the interactions thatare at the core of our analysis is much more straight-forward (Norton, Wang and Ai, 2004) but also that theyhelp to compare nested non-linear models (Mood,2010).

    We have also conducted a number of robustnesschecks that include the following: a different definitionof the dependent variable, considering the preferencesexpressed by the families at the beginning of the

    Table 1 Descriptive statistics: original sample (students born in France only), sample at the end of lowersecondary education (ninth grade), and analytic sample with valid information on Brevet

    Originalsample

    End of 3e`me End of 3e`me

    dropout excludedAnalyticsample

    Dependent variableAcademic track 54.1 55.9 61.1Vocational track 42.7 44.1 38.9Drop-out 3.2

    Independent variablesGender (female) 48.3 48.9 49.2 51.1

    Social class of originUpper class 14.4 14.9 15.0 16.1Routine employees, higher grade 17.3 17.8 18.0 19.2Petty-bourgeoisie 9.0 9.2 9.1 9.1Farmer 3.0 3.1 3.1 3.3Routine employees, lower grade 17.9 17.7 17.4 17.0Skilled and unskilled workers 34.5 34.2 34.5 33.1Inactivity 2.9 2.5 2.3 1.9Missing social class 1.0 0.3 0.6 0.6Brevet score (average) 11.0

    Average Brevet within the1st tertile of the Brevet distribution 8.02nd tertile of the Brevet distribution 10.93rd tertile of the Brevet distribution 14.1

    Number of observations 17,161 16,265 15,741 12,670

    Source: Panel dEle`ves du Second Degre (19952001).

    212 BERNARDI AND CEBOLLA-BOADO

  • orientation process instead of the final outcome; a

    different treatment of the missing values in the Brevet

    scores; a different conceptualization of social background

    that also considers the highest level of education among

    parents; the inclusion of those who have dropped out of

    the education system; the replication of the models using

    dummies for quartiles of the brevet distribution instead

    of tertiles; and the replication of the results using the

    average marginal effects (AME) of a logit model. The

    results of these parallel analyses are available in the

    supplementary online appendix, and they suggest that

    the findings presented in the next section are robust.

    Results

    In Table 2, we present the results of our LPM models.

    The first model includes only social class of origin and

    sex. The second model adds school performance as

    measured by the average Brevet score. The third model

    breaks down the grades into three dummies that

    Table 2 Transition to the academic track in France; linear probability model

    Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

    Gender (Female) 0.11** 0.04** 0.05** 0.04** 0.05**Social class of origin

    Upper class (reference)Routine employees, higher grade 0.17** 0.10** 0.11** 0.64** 0.15**Petty-bourgeoisie 0.27** 0.13** 0.15** 0.82** 0.20**Farmer 0.30** 0.22** 0.24** 0.93** 0.33**Routine employees, lower grade 0.37** 0.20** 0.22** 0.86** 0.29**Skilled and unskilled workers 0.47** 0.27** 0.30** 1.05** 0.40**No activity 0.60** 0.33** 0.37** 0.99** 0.56**

    Previous school resultsBrevet score 0.09** 0.05**

    Position in the Brevet distribution1st tertile 0.39** 0.28**2nd tertile (reference)3rd tertile 0.23** 0.08**

    InteractionsRoutine employees (high)Brevet 0.04**Petty-bourgeoisieBrevet 0.06**FarmerBrevet 0.07**Routine employees (low)Brevet 0.06**Skilled/unskilled workerBrevet 0.06**No activityBrevet 0.03**Routine employees (high) 1st tertile 0.15**Petty-bourgeoisie 1st tertile 0.13**Farmer 1st tertile 0.13*Routine employees (low) 1st tertile 0.12**Skilled/unskilled worker 1st tertile 0.08*No activity 1st tertile 0.08Routine employees (high) 3rd tertile 0.11**Petty-bourgeoisie 3rd tertile 0.13**Farmer 3rd tertile 0.24**Routine employees (low) 3rd tertile 0.19**Skilled/unskilled worker 3rd tertile 0.26**No activity 3rd tertile 0.30**

    Constant 0.84** 0.29** 0.81** 0.24** 0.88**N 12,670 12,670 12,670 12,670 12,670BIC 15,970 11,737 11,920 11,531 11,838

    *P < 0.05; **P < 0.01.

    Note: The models include a residual category of respondents with missing social class, not shown here.

    Source: Panel dEle`ves du Second Degre (19952001).

    PREVIOUS SCHOOL RESULTS AND SOCIAL BACKGROUND 213

  • correspond to tertiles in the distribution of grades (the

    middle one being the reference category). In Models 4and 5, the class of origin interacts with the average Brevetscore and with the tertile dummies.

    Model 2 indicates that approximately one-half of theobserved class inequality in Model 1 is due to thedifference in school results. For instance, the coefficient

    for the skilled and unskilled workers declines from 0.47to 0.27 (a reduction of 43 per cent) once the Brevet iscontrolled for.4 The only exceptions are farmers, for

    whom the reduction is somewhat smaller (from 0.30 to0.22, i.e., a reduction of 27 percentage points).

    Model 3 specifies school results as dummy variables

    that refer to the tertile distribution. The estimates forsocial class are very close to the estimates of Model 2.Next, in Model 4, we add the interaction effects between

    the Brevet score and the dummies for social class. Theseinteraction effects are positive and statistically significant.This result indicates that inequality, with respect to the

    service class, is largest among the worst achievers andbecomes progressively smaller as the values of the meanBrevet increase. This finding is in line with the hypoth-

    esis of a compensatory class effect discussed in thesecond section. However, the specification of the meanBrevet as a continuous variable in Model 4 does not

    allow testing for non-linearity in the class-specific impactof previous school results. For this reason, Model 5breaks down the grade distribution into tertiles, and it

    checks for non-linearity in the class-specific influence ofgrades on the type of transition made in uppersecondary school.

    With respect to the service class, the effects of thesocial class dummies in Model 5 express the disadvantageamong those with middling academic performance (that

    is, among those with a mean Brevet in the second tertile).Thus, for a male student from an upper-class family witha Brevet score within the range of the second tertile, the

    probability of choosing the academic track is 88 per cent(i.e., the constant term). For a male student from aworking-class background in the second tertile, the same

    probability is 48 per cent (8840). Following on, theinteraction effects between the social-class dummies andthe dummies for the tertile distribution of Brevet are

    negative in the case of the first tertile and positive in thecase of the third tertile. These results suggest that theclass inequality observed for the second tertile increases

    among the worst-performing students and decreasesamong the best-performing. The same pattern is observedfor other social classes. Thus, no support is found for the

    incomplete information hypothesis that would suggest alarger inequality in the middle of the grade distribution.

    If that were the case, one would also observe positiveinteraction effects for the first tertile.

    Finally, very similar conclusions are drawn if onefocuses on the predicted probabilities for differentcombinations of the class of origin and school resultsusing a logit model (Table 3). For all social classes, thelargest gap compared with service-class students isobserved among the worst-performing students (i.e.,those in the first tertile). The gap progressively reducesfor the students in the second tertile, and it almostdisappears among the best-performing students. Thepattern is particularly accentuated for students comingfrom white-collar or self-employed families.

    Conclusions

    We are now in a position to answer our initial researchquestion: do grades affect educational transitions differ-ently depending on social background? The answer is aclear yes. The results presented in the previous sectionsuggest that when compared with students of othersocial origins, upper-class students in France are lessaffected by previous school performance in choosing theacademic track or vocational track. In particular, upper-class students with below-average grades have a higherprobability of taking the academic track than studentswith similar grades from other social classes. As aconsequence, the largest class inequality is concentratedamong students with previously poor academic perform-ance. Among students of higher socio-economic standingwith below-average results, almost two in three students(60 per cent) move onto the academic track, whereas thesame is true of only one in five students (20 per cent)whose parents are routine employees of low grade or onein seven (15 per cent) students whose parents aremanual workers (Table 3). The difference between socialclasses is much smaller among high-performing students.Thus, we find evidence of a compensatory class effect,while not finding support for the incomplete informa-tion hypothesis, which suggests that inequality should belarger in the middle of the distribution of school results.

    The observed compensatory class effect is in line withthe prediction of the BG model. As highlighted by Lucas(2009), the RRA mechanism implies that for most of thestudents of higher socio-economic standing, the subject-ive probability of success proves irrelevant for theirschool continuation decision, while it is a key parameterin the choice of middle- and lower-class students.

    In addition to the motivational factor explained by theRRA mechanism, the two other mechanisms that arepart of the BG model might also contribute to theemergence of a compensatory class effect. First, socialclasses apparently differ in the way they interpret schoolperformance and infer expected probability of success,attributing different weighting to effort and ability as

    214 BERNARDI AND CEBOLLA-BOADO

  • causes of school results. Recent experimental evidence

    suggests that failure of upper-class students tends to be

    interpreted as a consequence of poor effort, whereas the

    failure of working-class students is perceived as an

    indicator of low ability (Iatridis and Fousiani, 2009). The

    crux of the argument is that whereas it is possible to

    change and increase the level of effort, an increase in

    performance is more complicated (if at all possible) in

    the case of ability. Second, upper-class families have the

    economic, social, and cultural resources to correct for

    previous academic failure and improve the efforts of

    their children.To conclude, we have three final remarks on how

    common the French compensatory class effect might be,

    its applicability to other research problems, and its

    implications for the empirical test of the BG model and

    the somewhat related area of research on primary and

    secondary effects.First, we suspect that the compensatory class effect

    found at the end of lower secondary school in France is

    rather pervasive and similarly applicable to other edu-

    cational transitions in other countries. Indeed, there is

    sparse evidence that appears to support this claim. For

    instance, a larger social background inequality in the

    decision to continue in schooling among low-performing

    students is observed in disparate and polar contexts,

    such as the Soviet Unions Leningrad in the late 60s

    (Yanowitch, 1977: p. 65) and the United States in the

    late 70s (Carneiro and Heckman, 2003; Figure 2.7: p.

    108). However, the last word on this issue can only be

    offered when systematic replications have been per-

    formed in different countries. In this respect, we would

    expect that the compensatory effect is larger for those

    educational transitions whose outcomes entail higher risk

    of social downward mobility. Therefore, the compensa-

    tory effect is possibly more relevant at earlier educational

    junctions, when compared with choices about tertiary

    education. Moreover, we would expect that it is smaller

    for those educational transitions that are more strictly

    regulated and formally dependent on previous educa-

    tional performance. To put it another way, the com-

    pensatory effect will be larger in those educational

    systems and for those educational transitions that allow

    more space for manoeuvre to families. This latter

    expectation goes, however, with the caveat that even

    where progress in education is most formally regulated,

    the crucial idea underlying the compensatory effect is

    that those of higher socio-economic standing will find

    other channels to compensate a previous failure, and

    effectively maintain their advantage (Lucas, 2001).5 For

    instance, they might disproportionately take advantage of

    second-opportunity education or recur to schooling

    abroad.Second, we believe that the compensatory effect does

    not apply solely to the interplay between previous grades

    and school continuation decisions. It can naturally be

    generalized to other situations, such as the consequences

    of retention in those educational systems where retaking

    is common, or to placement in a less prestigious

    educational setting in a tracked system. There is evidence

    demonstrating that the negative consequences of reten-

    tion are smaller (Gambetta, 1987: pp. 121122) and that

    movements from less to more prestigious tracks are

    more common for students from more advantaged

    backgrounds (Jacob and Tieben, 2009; Tables 3 and 4).

    The compensatory effect can also manifest itself outside

    the educational system. In its most general formulation,

    the effect would state that whenever a problematic event

    occurs, its negative implications will be much more

    limited for those of the upper class. Poor grades are the

    specific case studied in this article, but the compensatory

    effect could also be relevant for other events known to

    have negative consequences for the educational and

    occupational outcome of an individual, such as juvenile

    arrest, early pregnancy, or parental divorce. The com-

    pensatory class effect, thus, depicts a general mechanism

    Table 3 Predicted probability of probabilities of the transition to the academic track in France, by previousschool results and class of origin logit model

    Brevet score in the . . .First tertile Second tertile Third tertile

    Upper class 0.63 [0.590.67] 0.91 [0.900.93] 0.98 [0.980.99]Routine employees, higher grade 0.34 [0.320.37] 0.76 [0.730.78] 0.94 [0.940.95]Petty-bourgeoisie 0.29 [0.260.32] 0.71 [0.670.74] 0.93 [0.920.94]Farmer 0.19 [0.150.22] 0.58 [0.520.64] 0.88 [0.850.91]Routine employees, lower grade 0.21 [0.190.23] 0.61 [0.590.64] 0.90 [0.880.91]Skilled and unskilled workers 0.15 [0.140.16] 0.51 [0.490.53] 0.85 [0.830.87]

    Confidence intervals in squared brackets.

    Source: Panel dEle`ves du Second Degre (19952001).

    PREVIOUS SCHOOL RESULTS AND SOCIAL BACKGROUND 215

  • that potentially underlies the making of social inequality

    in many dimensions over life course.6

    Finally, the existence of an interaction between social

    background and school performance or, less technically,

    the fact that social classes respond differently to previous

    school performance in their school continuation decision

    has important implications for empirical tests of the BG

    model and the related area of research on primary and

    secondary effects. Various studies have confirmed the

    behavioural predictions of this rational choice model of

    education; however, the (relatively) few studies that have

    directly investigated motivational mechanisms find less

    consistent results, particularly with regard to the social

    demotion avoidance mechanism (Need and de Jong,

    2001; Stocke, 2007; van de Werfhorst and Hofstede, 2007;

    Gabay-Egozi, Shavit and Yaish, 2010). However, these

    articles have modelled the effects of motivational factors

    related to the RRA mechanism and subjective probability

    of success (or observed school performance) in an

    additive manner. Because the elasticity of grades varies

    by social class and because service-class students in

    particular are largely unaffected by previous performance

    in their school continuation decision (as actually pre-

    dicted by the RRA mechanism), these tests might be

    somewhat off target. The same applies to those recent

    studies that have investigated the primary and secondary

    effects as additive effects and, once controlled for

    previous school performance, interpret the effect of

    social background as secondary effects (Cebolla-Boado,

    2011; Schindler and Lorz, 2012; Barg, 2013). If, as our

    findings appear to suggest, secondary effects are primarily

    concentrated among students with below-average per-

    formance, then an additive specification might produce

    biased estimates. We hope that our research might make

    other researchers more aware of the fact that social classes

    do not apparently respond in the same way to previous

    school performance in their school continuation decision.

    Notes

    1 There is no space here to develop the formal

    demonstration, but see Lucas (2009: pp. 482483).

    2 Research on risk perception indeed suggests that

    people tend to exaggerate risks that are new or

    unfamiliar (Slovic, 2000). That would be the case

    for the risk of failure at the next educational level

    for those parents who have not attended it.

    3 The cutoff points for the first tertile are 1 and 9.7,

    for the second tertile 9.7 and 12, and for the third

    tertile 12 and 19.5. These cutoff points are based on

    the sample distribution of the average scores on

    Brevet. The three tertiles, however, almost perfectly

    overlap with three broad categories that have a

    clearer meaningful interpretation. A score 12 is considered satisfactory or good. We have

    replicated the analysis also using these more sub-

    stantive criteria for the definition of the categories

    and the results (available on request) do not change.

    4 A similar result for the cohort of students who

    started lower secondary education in 1995 is also

    reported by Ichou and Vallet (2013). Using different

    decomposition techniques, they find that about one-

    half of the observed inequality in the transition to

    post-compulsory education between upper- and

    working-class pupils is due to differences in previ-

    ous academic performance.

    5 On a theoretical level, the compensatory class effect

    discussed in this article can thus be fruitfully framed

    at the interconnection between the BG and effec-

    tively maintained inequality (EMI) models. Lucas

    (2009: p. 506) makes the case that the two theories

    are complementary. We also believe that focusing

    on how social classes react to a previous educational

    failure provides an advantageous perspective to

    integrate the two theories and to understand class-

    based strategies to maintain and reproduce inequal-

    ity. Draconian word limits prevent us from further

    elaborating on this point.

    6 However, a negative event does not randomly occur.

    This posits a serious problem of endogeneity for the

    study of the compensatory effect as defined in this

    article. See Morgan (2012) for a discussion and

    Bernardi (2012) for an attempt to address empir-

    ically this problem.

    Supplementary Data

    Supplementary data are available at ESR online.

    References

    Barg, K. (2013). The influence of students social

    background and parental involvement on teachers

    school track choices: reasons and consequences.

    European Sociological Review, 3, 565579.

    216 BERNARDI AND CEBOLLA-BOADO

  • Bernardi, F. (2012). Unequal transitions: selection biasand the compensatory effect of social background ineducational careers. Research in Social Stratificationand Mobility, 30, 159174.

    Boudon, R. (1974). Education, Opportunity, and SocialInequality. New York: Wiley.

    Breen, R. (1999). Beliefs, rational choice and Bayesianlearning. Rationality and Society, 11, 463480.

    Breen, R. and Goldthorpe, J. (1997). Explaining educa-tional differentials: towards a formal rational actiontheory. Rationality and Society, 9, 275305.

    Carneiro, P. and Heckman, J. (2003). Human capitalpolicy. In Heckman, J., Krueger, A. and Friedman, B.(Eds.), Inequality in America: What Role for HumanCapital Policies? Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 77239.

    Cebolla Boado, H. (2011). Primary and secondary effectsin the explanation of immigrants educational dis-advantage. British Journal of Sociology of Education, 2,407430.

    Duru-Bellat, M. and Van Zanten, A. (1999). Sociologie delEcole. Paris: Armand Colin.

    Gabay-Egozi, L., Shavit, Y. and Yaish, M. (2010). Cur-ricular choice: a test of a rational choice model ofeducation. European Sociological Review, 26, 447463.

    Gambetta, D. (1987). Were they Pushed or Did TheyJumped? Individual Decision Mechanisms inEducation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Iatridis, T. and Fousiani, K. (2009). Effects of status andoutcome on attributions and just-world beliefs: howthe social distribution of success and failure may berationalized. Journal of Experimental SocialPsychology, 45, 415420.

    Ichou, M. and Vallet, L. A. (2013). Academic achievement,tracking decisions and their relative contribution toeducational inequalities: change over four decades inFrance. In Jackson, M. (Ed.), Determined to Succeed?Performance Versus Choice in Educational Attainment.Stanford: Stanford University Press, pp. 116148.

    Jacob, M. and Tieben, N. (2009). Social selectivity oftrack mobility in secondary schools. A comparison ofintra-secondary transitions in Germany and theNetherlands. European Societies, 5, 743773.

    Lareau, A. (1987). Social class differences in family-school relationships: the importance of culturalcapital. Sociology of Education, 60, 7385.

    Lucas, S. (2001). Effectively maintained inequality:education transitions, track mobility, and socialbackground effects. American Journal of Sociology,106, 16421690.

    Lucas, S. (2009). Stratification theory, socioeconomicbackground, and educational attainment a formalanalysis. Rationality and Society, 21, 459511.

    Merle, P. (2002). Democratisation ou accroissement desinegalites scolaires? Lexemple de levolution de laduree des etudes en France (1988-1998). Population,57, 633660.

    Mood, C. (2010). Logistic regression: why we cannot dowhat we think we can do, and what we can do about.European Sociological Review, 26, 6782.

    Morgan, S. (2012). Models of college entry in the UnitedStates and the challenges of estimating primary andsecondary effects. Sociological Methods and Research,41, 1746.

    Need, A. and de Jong, U. (2001). Educational differen-tials in the Netherlands: testing rational actiontheory. Rationality and Society, 13, 7198.

    Norton, E., Wang, H. and Ai, C. (2004). Computinginteractions effects and standard errors in logit andprobit models. Stata Journal, 4, 154167.

    Roux, S. and Davaillon, A. (2001). Le processusdorientation en fin de troisie`me. Education andFormations, 60, 4153.

    Schindler, S. and Lorz, M. (2012). Mechanisms of socialinequality development: primary and secondaryeffects in the transition to tertiary education between1976 and 2005. European Sociological Review, 28,647660.

    Slovic, P. (2000). The Perception of Risk. London:Earthscan Publications Ltd.

    Stocke, V. (2007). Explaining educational decision andeffects of familiess social class position: an empiricaltest of the Breen-Goldthorpe model of educationalattainment. European Sociological Review, 23,505519.

    Van de Werfhorst, H. and Hofstede, S. (2007). Culturalcapital or relative risk aversion? Two mechanisms foreducational inequality compared. The British Journalof Sociology, 58, 391415.

    Yanowitch, M. (1977). Social and Economic Inequality inthe Soviet Union: Six Studies. White Plains: Sharpe.

    PREVIOUS SCHOOL RESULTS AND SOCIAL BACKGROUND 217