2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

download 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

of 35

Transcript of 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    1/35

    COOPERATIVE BANKS VS FINANCIAL CRISIS:

    AN APPLICATION OF THE STV VS. SHV DEBATE

    ABSTRACT

    The Great Financial Crisis of 2007-09 makes an interesting case study to test the shareholder vs.

    stakeholder debate in banking and finance. The hegemony of shareholder value maximization in the

    financial community showed its weaknesses being a factor in destroying the common good of

    financial stability. While shareholder value maximizing (SHV) organizations appear to have greatly

    contributed to the financial crisis, stakeholder value maximizing (STV) ones seem to have

    continued assuring credit, mortgages, financial services and financial sustainability to communities.

    In this paper we use probit and tobit models to test whether the probability of a country being in

    crisis in 2007-09 and the associated costs related the extent of the presence of Cooperative Banks

    taken as a proxy of STV organizations in the country. We start with the model of Caprio et al.

    (2010) introducing a new variable that is the percentage of the total assets of Cooperative Banks on

    the total assets of the national banking system. The database that we constructed from Bankscope

    features 83 countries containing data for 20,000 banks among Commercial Banks, Cooperative

    Banks, Bank Holding Companies, Investment Banks, Savings Banks. We find that the higher the

    percentage of Cooperative Banks total assets, the lower the probability of crisis. Through the tobit

    estimates, we also show that the costs of the crisis negatively relate to the extent of Cooperative

    Banks assets. Thus, Cooperative Banks appear to have reduced both the probability of suffering the

    crisis and, in the event, its consequences. This is in line with the virtues of biodiversity in banking.

    JEL Classification: G0; G01; G14; G15; G18; G21; G20; G24; G28; G30; G32.

    Keywords: Governance; Financial Crisis; Banking Crisis; Government Intervention; Regulation; Economic Institutions

    and Organizations; Financial Constitutional Economics, Shadow Banking System.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    2/35

    1. INTRODUCTION

    The Great Financial Crisis of 2007-09, the subprime mortgage crisis, materialized under the

    hegemony of the shareholder value maximization (SHV) model through financial institutions and

    organizations! (Deakin & Floor, 2010; Ingley et al. 2011; Hellwig, 2009). Different kinds of

    financial intermediaries, Banks, Insurance Companies, Mortgages Institutions", have pursued a

    corporate governance model based on SHV generating strong connections between credit and

    financial markets# increating systemic risks forcing the policy makers to apply the Too big too

    fail paradigm (Bullard et al., 2009 ) and financing the shadow banking system ( Gennaioli et al

    2012). The hegemony of the SHV model was part and contributed to produce several modifications

    in the banking business: i) a change in the credit management model from Originate-to-Hold (OTH)

    to Originate-to-Distribute (OTD; Berndt & Gupta, 2009; Bord & Santos, 2012); ii) a change in

    credit management model from relationship banking to transaction banking (Berger e Udell 2002) ;

    iii) improving the importance of the bank-lending channel for the transmission of monetary policy

    (Cavalcanti, 2009; Bernanke, 2007; Disyatat, 2011 ); iv) a change in the evaluation of credit risks

    1In this paper we use the term institution referring to norms, behaviors, best practices and ethical codes working asrules of the game (North, 1990), while the term organization refers to the players of the game constitutionally

    founded on these institutions and using them in the game. For example, corporate governance models are institutions

    while financial intermediaries are organizations. The distinction between financial institutions and organizations lets us

    investigate the reasons of inefficiency and mal-function in the financial constitution of the economic order.2We must consider that the set of financial organizations and institutions features a high degree of heterogeneity.

    Financial organizations include Banks, Insurance Companies, Government Banks, and also Financial Markets.

    Financial institutions count different economic orders based on financial constitution, for example differentiated on thebasis of their legal origin as in the Legal Origin Theory, and within a single economic order it features different kinds of

    financial and banking laws defining obligations, degrees of freedom and geographical and social mandates of financial

    organizations. But, despite the heterogeneity of financial organizations and financial institutions, the unique model of

    corporate governance based on SHV theory exercised by global financial governance established its hegemony(Gramsci, 1936). Through this Hegemony global financial governance has changed the meaning of the financial

    constitution of the economic order and the management of the financial organizations contributing to the crisis. Only

    few kinds of financial institutions and organizations resisted this hegemony, such as cooperation and Cooperative

    Banks, Savings Banks, Credit Unions, Micro-credit Intermediaries. These financial institutions and organizations are

    the pillars of the embedded stakeholder value (STV) maximization.3A great part of the economic literature (Kindleberger, 1978; Minsky, 1982; Galbraith, 2009) studies the causal relation

    between the growth of the credit borrowed from financial intermediaries to financial intermediaries and financial

    markets and the manifestation of a financial crisis. When the financial system uses credit to generate credit without

    connection to the real economy, households, public administrations, socially oriented organizations and firms, theprobability of a financial crisis grows approaching the value of 1. The SHV theory has offered the accounting meta-

    narrative to strengthen the establishment of credit from financial intermediaries to financial intermediaries and financial

    markets.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    3/35

    from relationship lending to credit scoring with a reduction of informational capital (Petersen,

    2004; Diamond, 1984 and 1989; Boot and Thakor, 1994) ; v) a change in the accumulation

    procedure of reputational capital from long-run multi-relationships with economic counterparts in

    the community to credit rating agencies especially for SMEs (Mariano, 2012; Moro & Fink, 2013),

    and vi) a change in the dynamic of perspective from a long-run perspective to shortermism%(World

    Bank, 2008) through commercial papers and short term debt (Rappaport, 2005, Diamond & Rajan

    2001, 2005 and 2009).

    The debate between Stakeholder and Shareholder has been reported also in banking (Freeman ,

    2010; Coyne, 2011). Stakeholder oriented banks apply originate to hold credit management model

    (STH-OTH) developing multiple long-run relationships with households and firms (Slovin et al.

    1993, Cornell & Shapiro, 1998), performing an ethical banking governance (Wijnberg, 2010),

    producing hard and soft information (Stein, 2002), endogenously evaluating the reputational

    capital&of the borrower.

    On the other side we have Shareholder oriented banks applying the originate to distribute credit

    management model (STV-OTD) related with credit scoring, hard information and securitization

    (Rajan et al. 2008;, Efraim, & Dlugosz. 2008) and shadow banking system generating financial

    instability and financial crisis ( Zamagni, 2006 and 2009). SHV-OTD due to their profit orientation

    have undervalued the systemic risk related to the securitization of mortgages ( Raghuram G. Rajan,

    2005; and Anil K. Kashyap, Raghuram G. Rajan, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2008).

    All these modifications were justified by the SHV-OTD model offering the meta-narrative (Eiter,

    1997) for these more speculative and sometimes even irrational behaviors increasing systemic

    risk and producing the Great Financial crisis.

    4The short-term temptation is an old question in the economic debate (Hayes and Abernathy,1980; Laverty, 1996).

    5We can observe a change from endogenous reputational capital to exogenous reputational capital. In the first case the

    reputational capital arises for the fact that organizations respect institutions in the long run and they are re-paid by their

    counterparts by gains in reputational capital. In the second case reputational capital is accumulated through externalcertification offered by a third subject in respect to parties that assign rankings offered to counterparts. An example of

    endogenous reputational capital is offered by the relationship banking. An example of exogenous reputational capital is

    offered by credit rating lending.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    4/35

    Maximizing the value of shares in the short-run (Gaspar et al., 2005) has created a new paradigm in

    financial contracting based on shortermism (Rappaport, 2005) that reduced the propensity of

    financial organizations to build the future through investment'.

    Financial intermediaries have phased out constitutional financial institutions infringing their public

    mandate to offer solution to classical market failures and have started to concentrate their effort in

    the corporate value function strictly based on the actualization of SHV maximization generating a

    more unstable banking model ( Shleifer& Vishny, 2010) .

    The strict relationship between financial crisis and the SHV-OTD paradigm has been largely

    showed in the economic literature and in the chronicles of the Great Financial Crisis (Purnanandam,

    2009).

    In this paper we concentrate our analysis on the relationship between stakeholder value

    maximization (STV) financial intermediaries and the Great Financial Crisis of 2007-09. In

    particular, we ask whether the presence of Cooperative Banks played a role in reducing the

    probability of suffering the Great Financial Crisis of 2007-09.

    We start our analysis from the paper of Caprio et al. (2010), where the authors investigate the

    relationship among financial and banking regulation and the probability to be in crisis in 2007-09.

    We focus on some of the Caprio et al.s variables introducing a variable that captures the percentage

    of total assets of Cooperative Banks in the national banking system.

    Our research question is related to the debate on STV vs. SHV in banking and finance. Cooperative

    Banks have an STV oriented management and control and this enforces their ability to work for the

    community(.

    6The relation between saving and investment is one of the main ideas at the foundations of macroeconomics. Indeed,

    since Keynes (1936), economists have based their macroeconomic analysis on this relation defined as an identity. But

    financial contracting has introduced a third element in this equation. Saving and Investment differ from the value of the

    saving that is borrowed in the financial markets in non-investment assets such as securitization. This new element, thatis produced as financial innovation, breaks the identity of saving and investment and produces distortions and risks that

    regulators and intermediaries are not able to tackle and that, when increasing their assets, can create a financial crisis.7In particular, we can refer to Cooperative Banks as Embedded STV organizations since in these organizations the STVtheory is not exogenously affirmed in their statutory mandate, and in their corporate governance model. In these case

    STV theory is embedded in the constitutional mandate and functioning of Cooperative Banks. Other kinds of Banks,

    such as Commercial Banks, can use corporate social responsibility codes but in this case they approach STV from a

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    5/35

    Cooperative Banks have statutory obligations that impose a one head one vote rule for voting in

    the assembly and a social mandate in the exercise of banking business.

    The STV orientation of Cooperative Banks) is juxtaposed to the SHV orientation of Investment

    Banks*, Commercial Banks and Bank Holding Companies.

    Our research question relates to evaluating the STV orientation in banking and finance.

    The economic behavior of STV oriented financial institutions and organizations has been more

    virtuous than that of SHV oriented financial institutions and organizations (Beltratti & Stulz, 2011).

    In fact, embedded STV organizations are less prone to securitize, to adopt the OTD model, to

    financing speculation, and asset-price-bubbles. STV banking and finance focuses on relationship

    banking, and OTH enforcing the relationship with communities (Groeveneld & Vries, 2009). STV

    oriented financial organizations develop a more sustainable model (Coco & Ferri, 2010). Due to this

    theoretical base we have investigated whether more STV oriented countries from the point of

    view of their financial constitution were less prone to the Great Financial Crisis (Allen & Gale,

    2000).

    The Great Financial Crisis at an operational level has been created by the OTD model,

    securitization and the strengthening of the finance-credit nexus through the hegemony of the SHV

    theory. This hegemony has been implemented by Commercial Banks, Investment Banks, Bank

    Holding Companies, while Cooperative Banks generally have a differentiated corporate governance

    model based on OTH, relationship banking and more socially oriented business. We have shown

    that the more the banking system was STV oriented in the period 1998-2006 the lower was the

    probability to suffer the Great Financial Crisis of 2007-09. This seems to show that the banking

    SHV orientation. In this case STV maximization is not embedded in the institutional building of financial organization

    but its just a tool in a SHV based financial organization.8We have used Cooperative Banks as a proxy for all the STV oriented banking and financial institutions and

    organizations. During the years the number of STV oriented institutions and organizations in banking and finance has

    been increasing. We must consider not only Cooperative Banks but also Savings Banks, Government Banks, and Micro-finance and Micro-credit organizations, and never forget to mention the economic organizations devoted to the

    reduction of financial exclusion.9We know that many of these banks have the skills to pursue socially oriented objectives. Some of them have adoptedrules based on corporate social responsibility and ethical codes devoted to humanitarian ends. But this kind of

    normative legislation, as a simple fact, is not sufficient to code these banks as STV oriented. Economists, managerial

    scientists and business ethicists address the nexus between corporate social responsibility and STV management.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    6/35

    model of Cooperative Banks is sustainable and actively participates to financial stability (OHara,

    1981; Esty, 1997; Fraser & Zardkoohi, 1996).

    We have used data based on the paper of Caprio et al. (2010) and data from Bankscope for the total

    assets of Cooperative Banks, Commercial Banks, Investment Banks, Bank Holding and Savings

    Banks from 1998 to 2006.

    The paper is divided as follows. In the second section we present a brief literature review where we

    tackle the question of the importance of cooperation in economic games, in which we connect

    cooperation with managerial models in banking and finance stressing the macro financial influence

    of the banking governance. In the third section we focus on methodology illustrating the strategy

    that we have taken to model the econometric technique that we have implemented. Here, we also

    illustrate the database and show the results obtained. The fourth section contains our conclusions.

    2. LITERATURE REVIEW

    In this section we present a brief literature review relative to the topics directly connected with our

    research question: the relation between Cooperative Banks and Financial Crisis as a case in the STV

    vs. SHV debate. While the Great Financial Crisis has been created by the hegemony of SHV

    financial organizations, Cooperative Banks are considered to be a proxy of STV oriented financial

    organizations (Freeman, 1984). The first thing to recall is the fundamental importance of

    cooperation in economics. In particular, economists such as North have developed a theory of

    institutional building based on cooperative behavior. In Norths theory cooperative behavior is a

    tool to solve market failures produced by asymmetric information and shortermism. In the theory of

    North cooperative behavior has the ability to impede free riding and by this way to develop a

    mechanism to build the common good of confidence. Cooperative behavior has the ability to solve

    market failures and, at the same time, to develop institutions based on long-run perspective.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    7/35

    The efficiency of cooperation has been showed in the repeated game theory both theoretically and

    empirically (Axelrod, 1984; 1986; 1987; 1997). The use of cooperation!+ in banking and finance

    has important effects on financial stability (Beck et al., 2009). The transformation of individual

    risks into systemic risk is more difficult in the case of cooperative banks in which their statute and

    economic organization strictly connect to their social mandate (Fonteyne, 2007). In this sense we

    have referred to cooperative banks as embedded STV governance!!organizations.

    Defining the Cooperative Banks Governance as Embedded Stakeholder Governance, gives us the

    possibility to consider the connections between Cooperative Banks and Financial Crisis interlinking

    the theory of economic cooperation, the economics of banking and finance, and the governance

    modeling in managerial science.

    STV banks suffered less the Great Financial Crisis. In particular, some studies show that

    cooperative banks may develop a more sustainable lending model (Coco & Ferri, 2010).

    Cooperative banks!" have a model of ownership that is egalitarian based on one head one vote

    (ICA, 1995; European Commission, 2001). At the same time they have the ability to develop more

    socially oriented business (EACB, 2004). Their legal statutory mandate, their ethical codes and the

    STV oriented governance produce positive effect on economic development, economic growth,

    reducing financial exclusion!#, improving the value of entrepreneurial human capital with long run

    banking relationships and horizons (Rajan, 1994), and being active part of the soft power locally

    10We know that we cooperative banks are only one kind of economic organizations working on the side of cooperativebehavior in banking and finance. Other organizations can implement cooperative behavior even if they are not

    cooperative in their statutory mandate.11We have developed the definition of Embedded STV Governance from the definition of embedded liberalism that

    we have discovered occasionally and fortunately (Ruggie, 1982). In effect as in the definition of embedded liberalismwe have considered what are the institutions and the organization for which STV theory is not an approach, or an ends,

    or an orientation, but it is a constitutional mandate inspiring the exercise of governance. In this sense we can distinguish

    Embedded STV Governance from Governance STV Oriented where STV is an approach that can be affirmed in the

    SHV organizations.12We can accept the proposition of Nobel Prize Yunus (Yunus, 2010) in which he considers the possibility that

    cooperative banks can be under a free riding attack. In the sense that it is possible that people in cooperative banksrealize unethical oriented behavior de facto misapplying the constitutional mandate of cooperative banks. But this case

    is strongly related with the corruption of the social environment that depreciates the value of human capital. In this case

    we have free riding oriented cooperative banks in which the statutory mandate of cooperative banks can be perverted.13The reduction of financial exclusion is one of the pillars in the ethical foundation of cooperative banks recalling to

    our mind the Latin adage Homo sine pecunia est imago mortis. The goal of reducing financial exclusion is pursued

    especially due to Cooperative Banks local ethos (De Bruyn & Ferri, 2005).

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    8/35

    defined in exercising governance (Brazda & Schediwy, 2001). Cooperative Banks become active

    part of economic change. Cooperative banks, as mutual banks are less prone to take risk (Chaddad

    & Cook, 2004; Gurtner, Jaeger & Ory, 2002; Fama & Jensen, 1983, Cannari & Signorini, 1997).

    The embedded STV governance of Cooperative Banks affects positively the common goods of

    financial stability (Cihk & Hesse, 2007), and economic development and growth even at a local

    level (Cosci & Mattesini, 1997; Usai & Vannini, 2005). Cooperative Banks produce financial

    sustainability. This ability of Cooperative Banks to produce financial stability is showed both

    theoretically and empirically. Theoretically it has been showed that cooperation has the ability to

    solve market failures and this per se produces economic equilibrium overcoming the

    microeconomic foundation of market failures caused by asymmetric information (Hansmann,

    1996). Empirically, it has been demonstrated that Cooperative Banks are less prone to take risks, are

    characterized by long-term horizon. Cooperative Banks have the ability to collect both explicit and

    implicit information. In particular, on the theoretical point of view Cooperative Banks have the

    possibility to solve the agency problem through the collection of explicit and implicit information

    building confidence (Kay, 2006). Cooperative Banks have the economic and constitutional mandate

    that cast them economically and socially in the role of producing economic sustainability as well as

    participating actively to the financial stability building (Ayadi et al., 2010).

    Another important implication of the STV oriented banking and financial organizations is

    implementing the OTH model in credit management. Originate to hold is a model of credit

    management that is based on the practices to generate credit, holding it until maturity. Credit

    holding and relationship banking are strictly related.But in the mutation of financial globalization

    during the late 1990s and the early years of the new decade OTH has been substituted by OTD

    through securitization. The passage from OTH to OTD has been a passage from monitoring based

    on implicit information to monitoring based on explicit information collected by credit scoring. This

    passage from OTH to OTD has been justified in the interest of SHV maximization. The hegemony

    of SHV maximization theory has offered the meta-narrative for the exercising of a financial market

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    9/35

    oriented banking governance that through securitizations, financial innovations and risks sharing

    has produced the Great Financial Crisis. Many economists and policy makers are calling for a return

    to more traditional banking (De Grauwe, 2008; Group of Thirty, 2009; de Laroisire, 2009).

    The change from OTH to OTD has created a multiplication of un-hedged risks and the

    libertarization!%

    of financial markets based on non-regulated financial markets has generated the

    worst financial Crisis since that of 1929.

    Particularly, we can say that the Great Financial Crisis has been aggravated by an approach in

    which the traditional relationship banking model based on OTH has been discontinued. On the

    contrary, embedded STV Governance in Cooperative Banks produces administrative methodologies

    based on relationship banking (Kay, 1991). Relationship banking is the traditional way of doing

    banking that is a long track in the history of capitalism!&.

    Cooperative Banks generally apply relationship banking. Relationship banking is a model in which

    banks hold long-run relationships with firms, households, and constituencies. These long-run

    relationships put the bank in the position to have more information about the borrower (Ghatak,

    2000). Having more information is a strategy to reduce the risk generating long-run relationships

    that reinforce the role of the bank in the community and gives confidence to the community. The

    relationship banking model has the ability to develop relational capital, confidence and, by this way,

    it is a model to produce common immaterial goods that can sustain economic growth (Alexopoulos

    and Goglio, 2012).

    14In this case we want to distinguish between liberalization and libertarization. In classical liberalism (e.g. Smith, Mills)

    there is the idea that markets should have some public control exercising a defense to small enterprises operating to

    solve market failures, while in classical libertarianism the idea of the State as an active economic subject removing

    market failures conditions is completely absent.15

    Indeed, we can say that the economics of banking, insurance and financial services is pre-capitalist. In particular, thehistory of banking shows us that relationship banking is the rule in the development of financial economics during the

    ages. The positive effect of relationship banking on the efficiency of banks is showed in the reduction of the cost of

    factoring, in reducing the risk of failures of counterparts, and in reinforcing the stability of the bank and the presence ofthe bank in the community. So we can say that relationship banking is the classical model of banking exercising

    positive effects in management, in the promotion of the banking business and in the social acceptance and reputation of

    the banks as economic organizations.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    10/35

    3. METHODOLOGY

    To estimate whether the increasing importance of Cooperative Banks total assets did affect the

    probability to suffer the Great Financial Crisis, we have used a probit model putting the value of 0

    when the country was not in crisis in 2007-09 and a value of 1 otherwise. We have data on 83

    countries in their mean value from 1998 to 2006. Our model is based on a cross section analysis.

    We have collected these data by using the database of Caprio et al. (2010), that of La Porta et al.

    (1998) and adding new information drawn from Bankscope.

    In our cross country analysis we have taken into consideration the mean value of each independent

    variable form 1998 to 2006. This could be criticized in the sense that mean values are unable to

    capture the dynamics of the change of each variable. If this kind of critique can in a certain sense

    produce a sort the skepticism on the methodology used in this paper we can say, on the other side,

    that the representative characteristics of the mean as statistical entity are perfectly working. This

    lets us infer about some generality of our proposition. Indeed, if we lose some information about the

    dynamics of the financial phenomena, on the other side we have the ability to produce a more

    general rule due to the statistical properties of the mean value. In particular, taking the mean over an

    extended nine-year period reduces the extent of errors in measurement of the exogenous variables.

    Although our analysis is based on the paper of Caprio et al. (2010), we have used different variables

    from that paper. In line with the model of Caprio et al. (2010) our dependent variable (Table 1) is:

    CRISIS= dummy equal to 1 if the country is classified as either borderline crisis or systemic crisis

    by Laeven and Valencia (2010) and 0 otherwise. The average value of this variable is 0.23

    with a standard deviation of 0.42.

    We employ a wide set of independent variables (Table 2) to take into account the various

    characteristics of the national financial systems, such as, for example, the banking efficiency,

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    11/35

    stability, profitability, the market structure and the regulation!'

    . In particular, we use the following

    banking indicators:

    CONCENTRATION = annual mean of the asset value of the three largest banks as a share of assets

    of all banks, from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck et al., 2000). The average of this variable is

    67.4% with a standard deviation of 18.9%.

    CREDIT/DEPOSIT= annual mean of the ratio of loans to deposits from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck

    et al., 2000)!(. While a high loan/deposit ratio indicates high intermediation efficiency, a

    ratio significantly above one also suggests that private sector lending is funded with non-

    deposit sources, which could result in funding instability (see Beck et al., 2000; Merrouche

    and Nier, 2010)!). The average of credit deposit ratio is 102.2%, with a standard deviation

    of 38.6%.

    ROA= annual mean of return on assets (net income to total assets) from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck

    et al., 2000). The average ROA is 1% with a standard deviation of 1.1%.

    RESTRICTION = mean value of the Overall Restrictions index reported in the three surveys by

    Barth et al. (2004). This index measures the degree to which banks face regulatory

    restrictions on their activities in: (a) securities markets, (b) insurance, (c) real-estate, and

    (d) owning shares in non-financial firms. The index can take values from 0 to 4 for each of

    these four sub-categories, where 4 indicates the most restrictive regulations on this sub-

    category of bank business. Thus, the index of overall restrictions can potentially range

    from 0 to 16. Its average value is 7.4 with a standard deviation of 1.7.

    16Our database provides aggregate (that is country-level) information on all countrys banks and not just on larger

    banks.17This variable only includes customer deposits and does not include interbank deposits.18The ratio of credit to deposit measures how much non-deposit funding is used to increase domestic credit. These

    alternative sources of funding include short-term debt (e.g. commercial paper and asset-backed commercial paper) andlong-term debt (e.g. bonds). Though desirable, a breakdown of funding into short-term and long-term instruments is not

    available even from International Monetary Fund, such as International Financial Statistics, or from international bank-

    level databases, such as Bankscope (see Huang & Ratnovski, 2009).

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    12/35

    BANK Z-SCORE = annual mean of bank z-score from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck et al., 2000).

    The z-score is the ratio of return on assets plus capital-asset-ratio to the 5-years standard

    deviation of return on assets. A higher z-score indicates that the bank is more stable,

    therefore, this index can be seen as the inverse of the probability of insolvency. Its average

    is 11.3 with a standard deviation of 6.6.

    CAPITAL= mean value of the Capital Regulation index reported in the three surveys by Barth et

    al. (2004). This index includes information on (1) the extent of regulatory requirements

    regarding the amount of capital banks must hold and (2) the stringency of regulations on

    the extent to which the source of funds that count as regulatory capital can include assets

    other than cash or government securities, borrowed funds, and on whether the

    regulatory/supervisory authorities verify the sources of capital. Large values indicate more

    stringent capital regulations. The index can be considered as a proxy of Basel Pillar 1. The

    average value of CAPITAL REGULATION is 6.2 with a standard deviation of 1.5.

    SUPERVISION = mean value of the Official Supervisory index reported in the three surveys by

    Barth et al. (2004). This index measures the degree to which the countrys commercial

    bank supervisory agency has the authority to take specific actions. It is determined by the

    information provided on the following features of official supervision: (1) does the

    supervisory agency have the right to meet with external auditors about banks? (2) are

    auditors required to communicate directly to the supervisory agency about elicit activities,

    fraud, or insider abuse? (3) can supervisors take legal action against external auditors for

    negligence? (4) can the supervisory authority force a bank to change its internal

    organizational structure? (5) are off-balance sheet items disclosed to supervisors? (6) can

    the supervisory agency order the bank's directors or management to constitute provisions to

    cover actual or potential losses? (7) can the supervisory agency suspend the directors'

    decision to distribute: a) dividends? b) bonuses? c) management fees? (8) can the

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    13/35

    supervisory agency supersede the rights of bank shareholders-and declare a bank

    insolvent? (9) can the supervisory agency suspend some or all ownership rights? (10) can

    the supervisory agency: a) supersede shareholder rights? b) remove and replace

    management? c) remove and replace directors? The official supervisory index has a

    minimum value of 0 and a maximum value of 14, where larger numbers indicate a greater

    power. It can be seen as a measure of Basel Pillar 2. The average value of this index is 10.9

    with a standard deviation of 2.3.

    INT_DEBT_ISS_GROSS_GDP = annual mean of the gross flow of international bond issues as

    percentage of GDP, from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck et al., 2000). This variable measures

    the degree to which a countrys financial system is interlinked with international financial

    markets. Its average value is 21.9% with a standard deviation of 25.8%.

    We augmented this model with a new variable named COOPERATIVE_BANKS defined as:

    COOPERATIVE_BANKS= percentage annual mean of total assets of Cooperative Banks on the

    sum of total assets of Cooperative Banks, Commercial Banks, Investment Banks, Bank

    Holding Companies, Investment Banks. The mean of this variable is 0.1636 with a

    standard deviation of 0.1633.

    So our model (Table 3 reports pairwise correlations; Table 4 shows descriptive statistics of the

    variables) is defined in this way:

    Pr(CRISISi)= !+1COOPERATIVE_BANKSi+2CONCENTRATIONi+3CREDIT/DEPOSITi

    +4ROAi +5RESTRICTIONi+5PRIVATE MONITORINGi+5BANK Z-SCOREi+6

    SUPERVISIONi+ INT_DEBT_ISS_GROSS_GDPi+ "i,

    3.1DATA AND THEORETICAL MODEL

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    14/35

    The data have been taken from 3 sources: from the database of the paper of Caprio et al. (2010),

    from the Bankscope database and from the paper of La Porta et al. (1998). In particular, we have

    taken from the paper of Caprio et al. (2010) the variables related to the international financial

    regulations and banking activities. We have taken this model as our reference point since it is

    devoted to the analysis of the relationships among financial regulations, banking business and the

    financial crisis. This model offers a sound basis for our research question relative to the evaluation

    of the impact of Cooperative Banks on Financial Crisis based on both the theoretical framework as

    well as on the contemporary development of the international political economy. We have taken

    data from La Porta et al. (1998) relative to Legal Origin, using dummy variables for French Legal

    Origin countries, German Legal Origin countries, UK Legal Origin countries and Socialist Legal

    Origin countries that we have used to instrument the probit model verifying the exogeneity of the

    Cooperative Banks variable. From the Bankscope Database we have taken data relative to the total

    assets of Cooperative Banks, Commercial Banks, Investment Banks, Bank Holding Companies and

    Saving Banks!*

    .

    Following the white rabbit of the relationship among Cooperative Banks and Financial Crisis, we

    have modified the model of Caprio et al. (2010) in two ways: introducing a new variable and

    dropping others. Specifically, we introduced a new original variable, i.e. Cooperative Banks that we

    have computed based the Bankscope database. The other variables taken from Caprio et al. (2010)

    are: Return on Assets (ROA), Bank Z-Scores, Supervision and INT_DEBT_ISS_GROSS_GDP,

    measuring the annual mean of the gross flow of international bond issues as percentage of GDP. We

    have done these modifications to better answer our research question. In particular, we have

    dropped NET_INTEREST_MARGIN from Caprio et al. (2010) since there is in a certain sense an

    effect of substitution between NET_INTEREST_MARGIN and COOPERATIVE BANKS due to

    19We know that the Bankscope database classifies different kinds of financial organizations, for example Government

    Banks, Mortgage Banks, Insurance Companies and similar. But we have concentrated our attention on the traditional

    banking sector putting it in relation with the Great Financial Crisis. Indeed, we have considered only private bankingorganizations excluding Government Banks, and on the other side we have considered pure banking organizations

    excluding for this reason Insurance Companies. We are aware that the set of private banking organizations is a subset of

    the set of banking organizations while the set of banking organizations is a subset of the set of financial organizations.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    15/35

    the fact that Cooperative Banks have generally high level of NET_INTEREST_MARGIN in their

    balance sheet as direct manifestation of the embedded STV maximization. So, for this reason, we

    have considered the contemporaneous presence of these two variables as redundant. At the same

    time we have introduced new variables ROA, BANK Z-SCORE, SUPERVISION and

    INT_DEBT_ISS_GROSS_GDP in the original model of Caprio et al. using them to explain the

    relationships between Cooperative Banks and Financial Crisis through variables explain banking

    returns and financial regulation on 83 countries.

    Pr(CRISISi)= !+1COOPERATIVE_BANKSi+2CREDIT/DEPOSIT i+3

    CONCENTRATIONi+4RESTRICTIONi +5PRIVATE MONITORINGi+5ROAi+5BANK

    Z-SCORE i+6SUPERVISIONi+ INT_DEBT_ISS_GROSS_GDPi+ "i,

    Our theoretical model has the right variables developed in the economics of banking for the

    evaluation of the banking performance and we have the ability to test it econometrically thanks to

    the data collected we have the possibility to test it econometrically.

    3.2RESULTS

    We have found a statistical significance of the importance of Cooperative Banks in being negatively

    associated with the Financial Crisis of 2007-09.

    To address the problem of exogeneity, we use the instrumental variable probit, instrumenting for the

    legal origins of the country. Performing the Wald test of exogeneity we have found that the variable

    of our interest was not endogenous (Table 7). We have than checked for the marginal effects

    quantifying the marginal derivative of the variables and we have confirmed the importance of the

    size of the negative association between cooperative banks and the probability of financial crisis.

    We have obtained equations that can explain in a dynamic context how the change in the percentage

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    16/35

    of Cooperative Banks total assets share can change the probability to suffer the Great Financial

    Crisis of 2007-09.

    Now we can consider the single regressors in this equation.

    The regressor COOPERATIVE BANKS is negatively associated with the dependent variable

    CRISIS. The regressor COOPERATIVE BANKS has a coefficient closed to 4.5, with a p-value

    equal to 0.018 (Table 5). Marginal effects show a negative relation between the variable

    COOPERATIVE and the CRISIS (Table 6). This leads us to affirm that the presence of Cooperative

    Banks reduced the probability to suffer for the Great Financial Crisis.

    Our analysis shows that there is also a negative relation between the regressor BANK

    CONCENTRATION and the dependent variable CRISIS. The BANK CONCENTRATION has a

    coefficient value equal to 3 and a p-value of 0.089 (Table 5) that becomes 0.052 checking for the

    marginal effects (Table 6).

    The value of the CREDIT DEPOSIT RATIO regressor is positively associated with the independent

    variable CRISIS and its p-value show a statistical significance either in the probit model (0.011 as

    in Table 5) or checking for the marginal effects (0.001 as in Table 6). The CREDIT DEPOSIT

    RATIO measures the mean of the ratio of loans to deposits. This variable in the data has a mean of

    1.022 a minimum value of .036 and a maximum value of 2.49. This means that on average national

    banking systems tend to have a level of credit that overcomes that of deposits and this fact can

    destabilize the economy. In particular, we can say that for 33 countries on 83"+

    the level of the ratio

    20 The countries are: Australia (1.36), Austria (1.26), Bolivia (1.13), Burundi (1.13), Chile (1.31), Colombia (1.41),

    Costa Rica (1.65), Denmark (2.48), El Salvador (1.06), Estonia (1.51), Finland (1.29), Germany (1.26), Iceland (2.49),

    Ireland (1.49), Italy (1.52), Kazakhstan (1.30), Korea Rep. Of (1.29), Latvia (1.42), Malaysia (1.05), Mali (1.08),

    Netherlands (1.48), New Zealand (1.37), Norway (1.46), Oman (1.25), Panama (1.13), Portugal (1.48), South Africa

    (1.25), Spain (1.33), Sweden (1.92), Switzerland (1.22), Thailand (1.03), Tunisia (1.24), United Kingdom (1.26). Wecan observe that even if the subprime crisis has been produced in the United States, United States doesnt figure in this

    list. In effect if we look at the data we can see that the level of Credit Deposit Ratio in the USA in the period between

    1998-2006 was, on average, lower than 1 and in particular equal to 0.79. This means that the banking system in theUSA was informed to the prudential principle of having a value of Credit Deposit Ratio lower than 1. This let us infer

    that the financial crisis was not created in the banking system but in the non-regulated connections between banking

    system and financial markets.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    17/35

    is greater than 1 and in two cases the value is greater than 2"!

    . We can say that the level of CREDIT

    DEPOSIT RATIO when is greater than 1 can produce financial sustainability risks and this can

    argue the strong and negative relation between this regressor and the dependent variable.

    Our probit model shows that there is a negative relation between the RESTRICTION regressor and

    the dependent variable CRISIS. This variable is statistically significant (0.008 in probit and 0.006 in

    probit marginal effects as showed in Tables 5 and 6). This relation can be better explained

    considering the fact that liberalization produces more competition, competition reduces profits, and

    this leads banks to manage more risky portfolio increasing the risk of failure (Hellmann et al.,

    2000). Banking restrictions reduce competition, lowering the propensity of banks to manage risky

    portfolio bringing down the probability to suffer for the Financial Crisis.

    The Z-SCORE regressor is negatively associated with the dependent variable CRISIS. Its

    coefficient is small and its p value is equal to 0.045 (Table 5). The negative relation between Z-

    SCORE and CRISIS is explained by the economic meaning of the Z-SCORE regressor, that is

    representative of banking stability.

    The ROA regressor is positively associated with the probability to suffer for the Great Financial

    Crisis measured by the dependent variable CRISIS. This positive relation is statistically significant

    with a p-value equal to 0.022 and a coefficient equal to 6.5 (Table 5). This means that an increase in

    the return on asset increase the probability to be in Crisis. The reason can be related with the strong

    connection between banks and financial markets. Using ROA to evaluate the banking performance

    is one of the strategies that can be practiced to realize a shareholder oriented banking governance.

    The CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN regressor is positively associated with the dependent variable CRISIS.

    The coefficient of this variable is near to 0 and the variable has a p value equal to 0.050 (Table 5).

    Marginal effects show a detriment in the statistical significance (p value = 0.057 as shown in Table

    21The value is greater than 2 for Denmark (2.48) and Iceland (2.49). Many economists have showed that the collapse of

    the Icelandic banking system actively contributed to let the financial crisis going global. Icelandic bankingorganizations have developed a global attitude but their ability to manage for systemic risks wasnt sufficient to secure

    the Icelandic economy. The Icelandic banking system international activism was not supported by an adequate Central

    Bank monetary policy leading to the crisis (Buiter & Sibert, 2008).

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    18/35

    6). The fact that there is a positive relation between the CAPITAL restrictions and the probability of

    a Financial Crisis can be explained by a qualitative approach on the basis of an efficient evaluation

    of the capital restriction banking legislation.

    There is a positive relation between the SUPERVISION regressor and the dependent variable

    CRISIS. This means that the more a country has a system of supervision the higher the probability

    to suffer for the financial crisis. We can say that this variable is statistically significant at the level

    of 5% with a coefficient closed to 0 (Table 5). The negative effect of RESTRICTION and the

    positive one of SUPERVISION suggest that, at least in our specification, regulatory restrictions

    were particularly important to secure financial stability.

    The INTERNATIONAL regressor is positively related with the probability to suffer for the Great

    Financial Crisis, measured by the dependent variable CRISIS. The value of the coefficient is 6.315

    and the level of the p value is equal to 0.000 (Table 5). This positive relation between the increasing

    financial international interconnectedness and the probability to suffer for the Great Financial crisis

    shows us that the Great Financial Crisis is global in its causation, materializing also through

    contagion.

    We have checked not only for Crisis but also for the Ordered Crisis and Cost of the Crisis both

    variables present in the paper of Caprio et al. (2010). We have found that in both cases the negative

    relation between Cooperative Banks and Financial Crisis though with different significance level

    still remains (as showed in Tables 8, 9 and 10).

    Firstly, the ordered probit results confirm the signs, the coefficient magnitude and the level of

    statistical significance of the variables in the model as showed in Table 8. Also here, the marginal

    effects show similar signs, coefficients and statistical significance of the variables as showed in

    Table 9.

    Finally, we have checked for the variable Cost of the Crisis measured as the cost of government

    interventions to salvage banks taken as a ratio to GDP using the tobit model. In this case all the

    regressors preserve their statistical relation with the independent variable, with small changes in the

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    19/35

    coefficient magnitude, and all the variable are statistical significant at least at a level of 5%, with

    the exception of CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN that has a p value equals to 0.181. This check lets us infer

    about a certain kind of robustness of the econometric estimation of our theoretical model.

    4 CONCLUSIONS

    4.1The importance of Cooperation for economic growth, and financial sustainability

    Our results find a negative relation between Cooperative Banks presence and the occurrence of the

    Financial Crisis. Our work sheds light on a part of the classical economic theory that economists

    and policy makers have ignored in the libertarian post-modern age of financial globalization.

    Cooperation has a positive impact on the efficiency of the economic game (North, 1990).

    Various economists have shown the importance of cooperative behavior in the institutional building

    process able to reduce market failures. Cooperative Banks may produce sustainability (Coco &

    Ferri, 2010), enforcing an STV maximizing approach, serving communities and constituencies

    (Freeman, 2010), having an egalitarian corporate governance model able to develop more socially

    oriented investment. Cooperative Banks preserve a level of competitive operational efficiency with

    respect to Commercial Banks (Cebenoyan et al, 1993; Valnek, 1999; Altunbas et al., 2001; Ayadi et

    al., 2009). Cooperative Banks can develop the firm-bank nexus, reducing the use of securitization.

    Cooperative Banks prevent local capital drain and actively promote local economic growth and

    development (Hakenes & Schnabel, 2006; Hakenes, Schmidt & Xie, 2009). Cooperative Banks may

    develop a more sustainable oriented banking system.

    4.2Relationship banking

    An important strength of Cooperative Banks is their ability to develop relationships with firms and

    customers"" (Boot, 2000; Elyasiani & Goldberg, 2004). In this sense Cooperative Banks are very

    22The relationship banking model affects directly the way in which Cooperative Banks produce value added. While inSHV model valued added is incorporated in profits, in Cooperative Banks, as a proxy for STV banks, the value added is

    incorporated in products and services offered to customers (Drake & Llwellyn, 2001). The value added process is based

    on relationship and the quality of relationship affect directly the production of value added.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    20/35

    fundamental. Several economists in this post-crisis period argue that it is very important to preserve

    relations as a basis to develop human capital and common confidence"#. Some economists speak

    about the capital of relationships, or, in other terms, the economics of relationships, using this

    expression referring to the complex of relationships that are created among economic agents

    (Zamagni, 2004). These relationships generate information, both explicit and implicit, promoting

    the exchange of immaterial goods among economic agents"%(Stiglitz, 1990; Varian, 1990; Besley &

    Coate, 1995). Evaluating the relational capital seems to be fundamental to solve market failures and

    create confidence in the market. The nexus among human capital, relational capital and the banking

    market seems to be a key for the description of macroeconomic and microeconomic phenomena.

    This gives some suggestions for policy makers. Financial political economies based on relationship

    banking have three effects: increase the value of human capital; increase the value of relational

    capital; producing sustainability.

    4.3 Heterogeneity and hegemony in the financial constitution of the economic order

    The hegemony of SHV maximization has produced an age of increasing financial risks, of rising

    global uncertainties and, at the end, the Great Financial Crisis. The Hegemony of the SHV

    maximization is the managerial representation of a widespread post-1989 idea: the idea of the end

    of history (Fukuyama, 1993), the idea of the unipolar world, the idea of the definitive victory of

    capitalism. The Great Financial Crisis has showed that the idea of a unipolar world is not

    sustainable, that the economic order needs heterogeneity of institutions and organizations (Kirman,

    2006), and that at the end globalization can be more sustainable in the heterogeneity of economic

    orders representative of ethno-anthropological differentiation. Our results show that countries with a

    more heterogeneous financial constitution less likely suffered the Great Financial Crisis.

    23 We can say that relational goods are able to increase the value of human capital. In effect human capital can

    depreciate if it is not applied in the exercise of relational goods, since the fundamental characteristic of human capital is

    that to produce a knowledge economics optimized under a relational constraint.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    21/35

    Heterogeneity of institutions and organizations can create the right incentives to overcome classical

    distortions of information developed in modern economics, thus securing better allocations.

    4.4 Law and banking: a new perspective

    In the last few years we have witnessed a development in the field of law and economics, especially

    law and finance (La Porta et al., 1998). We can say that the nexus between the financial system and

    the banking system has been studied in depth in the last fifteen years. It is important to understand

    that the banking system and the financial system are in the relation of a part to the whole, in the

    sense that the banking system is completely contained inside the financial system, but at the same

    time it is important that the nexus between the banking system and the financial system still remains

    under regulatory control. This control is important since it seems that overly increasing the volume

    of credit to the financial sector produces financial crises. For this reason it seems important to

    develop a law and banking perspective inside the law and finance field in law and economics to

    preserve banks from taking excessive financial risks that end up destroying saving as public good.

    Within economics, the field of financial economics has been developed more than banking

    economics. Financial economics includes the economics of financial institutions and organizations

    and, due to the rising relative importance of the financial markets, it is possible recognize a

    financial constitution of the economic order that possesses some degree of heterogeneity even in the

    financial globalization. Banking economics is a subfield of financial economics but it is the

    diamond of the financial constitution of the economic order. The supremacy of the banking

    economics is in the pragmatic of capitalism. Economists should weigh the need to defend the

    economics of banking with appropriate laws. In this effort, they should not forget the importance to

    safeguard cooperative financial institutions and organizations, so to support financial stability

    within sustainable economies.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    22/35

    BIBLIOGRAPHY

    Alexopoulos Y., Goglio S. (2012; eds.), Financial Co-operatives and Local Development, London:

    Routledge.

    Allen F., Gale D. (2000), Comparing Financial Systems, Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Altunba!Y., Evans L., Molyneux P. (2001), Bank Ownership and Efficiency, Journal of Money,

    Credit & Banking 33(4): 926-54.

    Axelrod R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books.

    Axelrod R. (1986), An evolutionary approach to norms. American Political Science Review 80:

    1095-111.

    Axelrod R. (1987), The evolution of strategies in the iterated Prisoners' Dilemma., in L. Davis,

    ed., Genetic Algorithms and Simulated Annealing, Los Altos, CA: Morgan Kaufmann.

    Axelrod R. (1997), The Complexity of Cooperation, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Ayadi R., Arbak E., Carb Valverde S., Rodriguez Fernandez F., Schmidt R.H. (2009), Investigating

    Diversity in the Banking Sector in Europe: The Performance and Role of Savings Banks, Brussels:

    Centre for European Policy Studies.

    Ayadi R., Arbak E., De Groen W.P., Llewellyn D.T. (2010), Investigating Diversity in the Banking

    Sector in Europe: Key Developments, Performance and Role of Cooperative Banks, Brussels: Centre

    for European Policy Studies.

    Barth J., Caprio G. Jr., Levine R. (2004), Bank Regulation and Supervision: What Works Best?,

    Journal of Financial Intermediation 13: 20548.

    Beck T., Demirg-Kunt A., Levine R. (2000), A New Database on Financial Development and

    Structure, World Bank Economic Review 14: 597-605.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    23/35

    Beck T., Hesse H., Kick T., von Westernhagen N. (2009), Bank Ownership and Stability: Evidence

    from Germany, Bundesbank Working Paper Series.

    Beltratti A., Stulz R.M. (2012), Why Did Some Banks Perform Better During the Credit Crisis? A

    Cross-Country Study of the Impact of Governance and Regulation, Journal of Financial Economics,

    forthcoming.

    Benmelech E., Dlugosz J. 1. The Alchemy of CDO Credit Ratings NBER Working Paper No. 14878

    Issued in April 2009 NBER Program(s): CF 2.

    Berger A.N.,Udell G.F 2002, Small business credit availability And relationship lending: the

    importance Of bank organisational structure, in The Economic Journal, 112 : F32-F53

    Bernanke Ben S., The Financial Accelerator and the Credit Channel At the The Credit Channel of

    Monetary Policy in the Twenty-first Century Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta,

    Georgia June15,2007 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20070615a.htm#f5

    Berndt A., Gupta A. (2009), Moral hazard and adverse selection in the originate-to-distribute model

    of bank credit, Journal of Monetary Economics 56: 725-43.

    Besley T., Coate S. (1995), Group Lending, Repayment Incentives and Social Collateral, Journal of

    Development Economics 46(1): 1-18.

    Boot, A.W.A. (2000), Relationship Banking: What Do We Know?, Journal of Financial

    Intermediation 9(1): 7-25.

    Boot, A.W.A., and A.V. Thakor (2000), Can relationship banking survive competition?, Journal of

    Finance LV, 679-713.

    Bord, Vitaly and Santos, Joo A. C., (September 19, 2012), The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute

    Model and the Role of Banks in Financial Intermediation Economic Policy Review, Vol. 18, No. 2,

    21-34, July 2012.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    24/35

    Brazda J., Schediwy R. (2001), Preconditions for Successful Co-operative Ventures in the Light of

    Historical Evidence, Review of International Cooperation 94(1): 35-42.

    Buiter W. H., Sibert A.C. (2008), The Icelandic Banking Crisis and What to Do About It: The

    Lender of Last Resort Theory of Optimal Currency Areas, CEPR Policy Insight No. 26, October.

    Bullard J., Christopher J. Neely, and David C. Wheelock, (2009) Systemic Risk and the Financial

    Crisis: A Primer, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Part 1 4

    Cannari L., Signorini L.F. (1997), Rischiosit e razionamento del credito: unanalisi dellefficienza

    allocativa delle BCC e dei divari Nord-Sud, in Cesarini F., Ferri G., Giardino M. (eds.) Credito e

    sviluppo, Bologna: il Mulino.

    Caprio G. Jr, DApice V., Ferri G., Puopolo G.W. (2010), Macrofinancial determinants of the Great

    Financial Crisis, Temi di Economia e Finanza working paper ABI Italian Banking Association.

    Cavalcanti A.F.H. (2010), Credit market imperfections and the power of the financial accelerator: A

    theoretical and empirical investigation, Journal of Macroeconomics 32: 118-44.

    Cebenoyan A.S., Cooperman E.S., Register C.A., Hudgins S.C. (1993), The relative efficiency of

    stock versus mutual S&Ls: A stochastic cost frontier approach, Journal of Financial Services

    Research 7(2): 151-70.

    Cihk M., Hesse H. (2007), Cooperative Banks and Financial Stability, IMF WP/07/02.

    Cornell B. and Shapiro Alan C., Corporate Stakeholders and Corporate Finance, Financial

    Management, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Spring, 1987), pp. 5-14

    Cosci, S., Mattesini, F. (1997), Credito e sviluppo nelle province italiane, in Cesarini F., Ferri G.,

    Giardino M. (eds.) Credito e sviluppo, Bologna: il Mulino.

    Coyne J. (2011), Constitution and Crisis, Journal of Economics Behaviour and Organization 80:

    35157.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    25/35

    De Bruyn R., Ferri G. (2005), Le ragioni delle banche Popolari: motivi teorici ed evidenze

    empiriche, Working Paper n 1. Disefin Universit di Genova.

    De Grauwe P. (2008), The Banking Crisis: Causes, consequences and remedies, CEPS Policy Brief,

    No. 178, Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels, November.

    de Larosire J. (2009), The High-Level Group on Financial Supervision in the EU, Brussels. Report

    for the European Commission.

    Deakin S., Floor T. (2010), Corporate Governance and Financial Crisis in the long run, Centre for

    Business Research, University of Cambridge, Working Paper No. 417.

    Diamond D, Rajan R (2009) The credit crisis. NBER, WP 1473, February

    Diamond, D.W. (1984), Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring, Review of Economic

    Studies 51, 393-414

    Diamond, D.W. (1989), Reputation acquisition in debt markets, Journal of Political Economy 97,

    828-862.

    Diamond, Douglas W., and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2001. Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation and

    Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking. Journal of Political Economy, 109(2): 287-327.

    Diamond, Douglas W., and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2005. Liquidity Shortages and Banking Crises.

    Journal of Finance, 60(2): 615-647.

    DISYATAT, P. (2011), The Bank Lending Channel Revisited. Journal of Money, Credit and

    Banking, 43: 711734. doi: 10.1111/j.1538-4616.2011.00394.x

    Drake L., Llewellyn D.T. (2001), The Economics of Mutuality: A Perspective on UK Building

    Societies, in J. Birchall (ed.), The New Mutualism in Public Policy, London: Routledge.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    26/35

    Eiter F. (1997), Storytelling and Ethics in Financial Economics, Critical Perspectives on Accounting

    8: 60532.

    Elyasiani E., Goldberg L.G. (2004), Relationship Lending: A Survey of the Literature, Journal of

    Economics & Business 56(4): 315-30.

    Esty B.C. (1997), A Case Study of Organizational Form and Risk Shifting in the Savings and Loan

    Industry, Journal of Financial Economics 44(1): 57-76.

    European Association of Cooperative Banks (2004), Cooperative Banks in Europe: Values and

    Practices to Promote Development, Available at http://www.eurocoopbanks.coop/

    European Commission (2001), Co-operatives in enterprise Europe, Draft consultation paper,

    Brussels.

    Fama E.F., Jensen M.C. (1983), Agency Problems and Residual Claims, Journal of Law and

    Economics 26(2): 327-49.

    Fonteyne W. (2007), Cooperative Banks in Europe- Policy Issues, IMF WP/07/159.

    Fraser D.R., Zardkoohi A. (1996), Ownership Structure, Deregulation, and Risk in the Savings and

    Loan Industry, Journal of Business Research 37(1): 63-9.

    Freeman R.E. (1984), Strategic Management, Cambridge University Press.

    Fukuyama F. (1993), The end of the history and the last man, Free Press (February 28, 2006)

    reprinted.

    Galbraith J.K. (2009), The Great Crash, Mariner Books; Reprint edition.

    Gaspar J.M., Massa M., Matos P. (2005), Shareholder investment horizons and the market for

    corporate control, Journal of Financial Economics 76: 13565.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    27/35

    Gennaioli, Nicola, Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W., A Model of Shadow Banking (April 16,

    2012). Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

    Ghatak M. (2000), Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer

    Selection Effect, Economic Journal 110: 601-31.

    Gramsci A. (2010), Prisons notebook, New York: Columbia University Press.

    Groeneveld J.M., De Vries Y.B. (2009), European co-operative banks: First lessons from the

    subprime crisis, Working Paper Economic Research Department Rabobank Nederland.

    Gurtner E., Jaeger M., Ory J.N. (2002), Le Statut de Cooprative est-il Source dEfficacit dans le

    Secteur Bancaire?, Revue dEconomie Financire 67: 133-64.

    Hakenes H., Schmidt R.H., Xie R. (2009), Public Banks and Regional Development, Journal of

    Financial Services Research.

    Hakenes H., Schnabel I. (2006), The Threat of Capital Drain: A Rationale for Public Banks?,

    Working Paper Series Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods, No. 11.

    Hansmann H. (1996), The ownership of enterprise, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Hellmann T.F., Murdock K.C., Stiglitz J.E. (2000), Liberalization, Moral Hazard in Banking, and

    Prudential Regulation: Are Capital Requirements Enough?, The American Economic Review 90(1):

    147-60.

    Huang R., Ratnovski L. (2009), Why are Canadian Banks More Resilient?, IMF WP/09/152.

    Ingley C., Mueller J., Cocks G. The financial crisis, investor activists and corporate strategy: will

    this mean shareholders in the boardroom? Journal of Management & Governance, November

    2011, Volume 15, Issue 4, pp 557-587.

    International Co-Operative Alliance ICA (1995), Statement of Identity, ICA News Issue 5&6.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    28/35

    Kashyap, Anil K., Raghuram G. Rajan, and Jeremy C. Stein. 2008. Rethinking Capital

    Regulation. Paper presented at the Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System Federal

    Reserve Bank of Kansas Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY

    Kay J. (1991), The Economics of Mutuality, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 62(3):

    309-18.

    Kay J. (2006), The mutual interest in building trust still remains, Financial Times, April 26.

    Kindleberger C.P. (1978), Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, London:

    Palgrave Macmillan.

    Kirman A. (2006), Heterogeneity in Economics, Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination

    1: 89117.

    La Porta R., Lopez-de-Silanes F., Shleifer A., Vishny R.W. (1998), Law and Finance, Journal of

    Political Economy 106: 1113-55.

    Laeven L., Valencia F. (2010), Resolution of Banking Crises: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly, IMF

    WP/10/146.

    Laverty K.J. (1996) Economic "Short-Termism": The Debate, the Unresolved Issues, and the

    Implications for Management Practice and Research, The Academy of Management Review 21(3):

    825-60.

    Mariano B. (2012), Market Powers and Reputational Concerns in the Rating Agencies, Journal of

    Banking & Finance 36: 1616-26.

    Martin F. Hellwig, Systemic Risk in the Financial Sector: An Analysis of the Subprime-Mortgage

    Financial Crisis, De Economist, June 2009, Volume 157, Issue 2, pp 129-207.

    Merrouche O., Nier E. (2010), What Caused the Global Financial Crisis? Evidence on the Drivers of

    Financial Imbalances 19992007, IMF WP/10/265.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    29/35

    Minsky H. (1982), The Financial Instability Hypothesis: Capitalistic Processes and the Behavior of

    the Economy, in C. Kindleberger, J.-P. Laffargue, Financial Crises: Theory, History and Policy, New

    York: Cambridge University Press.

    Moro A., Fink M., (2013) Loan managers trust and credit access for SMEs, Journal of Banking &

    Finance Volume 37, Issue 3, March 2013, Pages 927936

    OHara M. (1981), Property Rights and the Financial Firm, Journal of Law & Economics 24(2): 317-

    32.

    Petersen M.A., 2004, Information: Hard and Soft, mimeo

    Rajan R.G. (1994), Why Bank Credit Policies Fluctuate: A Theory and Some Evidence, The

    Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2): 399-441.

    Rajan, Raghuram G. 2005. Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier. Paper presented

    at The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas Symposium, Jackson

    Hole, WY.

    Rajan, Uday, Seru, Amit and Vig, Vikrant, The Failure of Models that Predict Failure: Distance,

    Incentives and Defaults (August 1, 2010). Chicago GSB Research Paper No. 08-19; EFA 2009

    Bergen Meetings Paper; Ross School of Business Paper No. 1122. Available at SSRN:

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=1296982 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1296982

    Rappaport A. (2005), The Economics of Short-Term Performance Obsession, Financial Analysts

    Journal 61(3): 6579.

    Ruggie J.G. (1982),International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the

    Postwar Economic Order, International Organization 36(2).

    Shleifer A. Vishny Robert W. Unstable banking (September 2010), Journal of Financial Economics,

    Volume 97, Issue 3, , Pages 306318

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    30/35

    Slovin M.B.,Sushka M.E.,Polonchek J.A.,1993, The value of bank durability: Borrowers as bank

    stakeholders, in The Journal of Finance, 48, pp. 289-302.

    Slovin, Myron B. , Sushka Marie E. and Polonchek John A., The Value of Bank Durability:

    Borrowers as Bank Stakeholders The Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 1 (Mar., 1993), pp. 247-266

    Stein J.C., 2002, Information Production and Capital Allocation: Decentralized versus Hierarchical

    Firms, in Journal of Finance, 57: 1891-1922.

    Stiglitz, J.E. (1990), Peer Monitoring and Credit Markets, World Bank Economic Review 4(3): 351-

    66.

    Usai S., Vannini M. (2005), Banking Structure and Regional Economic Growth: Lessons from Italy,

    Annals of Regional Science 39(4): 691-714.

    Valnek T. (1999), The comparative performance of mutual building societies and stock retail banks,

    Journal of Banking & Finance 23(6): 925-38.

    Varian H.R. (1990), Monitoring Agents with Other Agents, Journal of Institutional & Theoretical

    Economics 146(1): 153-74.

    Wijnberg Nachoem M. , Normative Stakeholder Theory and Aristotle: The Link Between Ethics and

    Politics, Journal of Business Ethics June 2000, Volume 25, Issue 4, pp 329-342

    World Bank (2008) Lessons from World Bank research on financial crises. World Bank,

    Washington, DC

    Zamagni S (2006) The ethical anchoring of corporate social responsibility. In: Zsolnai L (ed)

    Yearbook of business ethics. Peter Lang, Oxford, UK

    Zamagni S. (2004), Happiness and -Individualism: A Very Difficult Union, in L. Bruni, P. Porta

    (eds.), Happiness and Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    31/35

    Zamagni S., The lesson and warning of a crisis foretold: a political economy approach, International

    Review of Economics, September 2009, Volume 56, Issue 3, pp 315-334

    TABLE 1. DEPENDENT VARIABLES

    Probit Model: CRISIS Dummy equal to 1 if the country is classified as either borderline crisis or systemic crisis by Laeven and Valencia

    (2010) and 0 otherwise

    Dependent variable

    ordered probit model

    ORDERED CRISIS

    Dummy equal to 1 is the country is classified as borderline crisis, equal to 2 if the country is classified as systemiccrisis and 0 otherwise (source: Laeven and Valencia , 2010)

    Dependent variable tobit

    model: CRISIS_COST

    Variable as provided by Laeven and Valencia (2010) that measures the cost of public support to the financial system in

    term of GDP

    TABLE 2. INDEPENDENT VARIABLES

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    32/35

    COOPERATIVE BANKS Mean value of the percentage, from 1998 to 2006, of total assets of Cooperative Banks on the sum of total assets ofCooperative Banks, Commercial Banks, Bank Holding, Investment Banks, Savings Banks, (source: Bankscope

    Database)

    CREDIT DEPOSIT

    RATIO

    Mean of the ration of loans to deposits from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck Demigurc-Kunt and Levine, 2000)

    BANK

    CONCENTRATION

    Mean of assets of three largest banks as a share of assets of all commercial banks from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck,

    Demigurc-Kunt and Levine, 2000)

    PRIVATE

    RESTRICTION

    Mean value of the "overall restrictions" index reported in the three surveys (source: Barth, Caprio and Levine , 2004)

    Z SCORE Mean value of bank z score from 1998 to 2006 (source: beck, Demigurc-Kunt and Levine , 2000)

    ROA Mean of average return on assets (net income/total equity)=, from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck, Demigurc-Kunt and

    Levine, 2000)

    CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN Mean value of the "Capital Regulation" index reported in the three surveys (source: Barth, Caprio and Levine 2004).

    CAPRIO SUPER MEAN Mean value of the "Official Supervisory" index reported in the three surveys (source: Barth, Caprio and Levine, 2004)

    INTERNATIONAL Mean of the gross of international bond issues, relative to GDP from 1998 to 2006 (source: Beck, Demigurc-Kunt and

    Levine, 2000)

    TABLE 3. CORRELATIONS

    CRISIS COOP CONCENTRATION

    CREDITDEPOSIT

    RESTRICTION

    BANK ZSCORE

    ROA CAPITMEAN

    SUPERMEAN

    INTERNATIONAL

    CRISIS 10.000

    COOPERATI

    VE BANKS

    -0.2485 10.000

    BANK

    CONCENTR

    ATION

    0.0419 -0.3489 10.000

    CREDIT

    DEPOSITRATIO

    0.3520 -0.2228 0.2682 10.000

    PRIVATE

    RESTRICTION

    -0.4445 0.2687 -0.1515 -0.1273 10.000

    BANK ZSCORE 0.0569 -0.2212 0.2321 0.1511 -0.1024 10.000

    BANK ROA 0.0813 0.1037 0.3226 -0.0132 0.0624 0.2321 10.000

    CAPRIOCAPIT MEAN

    0.1667 0.0621 0.0071 -0.0374 0.0250 -0.0815 0.0379 10.000

    CAPRIO

    SUPER

    MEAN

    -0.0664 0.0799 -0.0624 -0.2512 0.2888 -0.0045 0.2572 0.1326 10.000

    INTERNATIO

    NAL

    0.6074 -0.1951 -0.0267 0.1772 -0.5633 0.0746 0.0001 -0.0192 -0.2418 10.000

    TABLE 4. STATISTICSOF VARIABLES

    Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

    CRISIS 83 .2289157 .4226889 0 1

    COOPERATIVE BANKS 83 .1636145 .1633758 0 .77

    BANK CONCENTRATION 83 .6739759 .1896398 .25 1

    CREDIT DEPOSIT RATIO 83 1.022.289 .3861736 .36 2.49

    CAPRIO RESTRICTION 83 7.427.831 1.741.259 3.33 12

    BANK Z SCORE 81 1.125.506 6.626.298 4.2 39.17

    BANK ROA 83 .0108434 .0111754 -.02 .04

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    33/35

    CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN 83 615.253 1.492.439 3 10

    CAPRIO SUPER MEAN 82 1.093.902 2.310.924 5 14.25

    INTERNATIONAL 73 .2141096 .2563192 0 1.46

    TABLE 5. PROBIT REGRESSION

    PROBIT REGRESSION

    Number of obs = 71

    Wald chi2(9) = 39.07

    Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

    Pseudo R2 = 0.5981

    CRISIS COEF. R. STD. ERR. Z P>|Z| [95% !

    !!

    !

    Conf.Interva

    COOPERATIVE BANKS -4.499.449 1.909.812 -2.36 0.018 -.8160095 -7562862BANK CONCENTRATION -2.981.543 1.718.613 -1.73 0.083 -6.349.963 .3868772

    BANK CREDIT/DEPOSIT 2.042.641 .7992698 2.56 0.011 .4761009 3.609.181

    CAPRIO RESTRICTION MEAN -.4681251 .1774953 -2.64 0.008 -.8160095 -.1202407

    BANK Z SCORE -.0621564 .0309377 -2.01 0.045 -.1227933 -.0015196

    BANK ROA 6.522.032 2.849.678 2.29 0.022 9.367.655 121.073

    CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN .299565 .1525842 1.96 0.050 .0005054 .5986246

    CAPRIO SUPER MEAN .2725048 .1291008 2.11 0.035 .0194719 .5255378

    INTERNATIONAL 6.315.616 1.594.051 3.96 0.000 3.191.334 9.439.898

    CONSTANT -3.537.184 2.190.953 -1.61 0.106 -7.831.372 .757004

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    34/35

    TABLE 6. MARGINAL EFFECTS OF PROBIT REGRESSION

    ,-./01. 20/13405 .66.789

    :;? @ A;BC98

    ?DE/.993;4 @ F/G>/3939HI E/.|Z| [95% !!!

    !Conf.Interval]

    COOPERATIVE BANKS LM&&%(!*% M"#"#!)% L"M#* +M+!( L!M+!+M+&& LM+**#)#)

    BANK CONCENTRATION LM#'(&)") M!)*!&)( L!M*% +M+&" LM(#)#"( M++#!'!&

    BANK CREDIT / DEPOSIT M"&!)"*" M+()(* #M"+ +M++! M+*(#*#" M%+'"'&"

    CAPRIO RESTRICTION ME LM+&((!## M+"+*')' L"M(& +M++' LM+*))!!! LM+!''!&&

    BANK Z SCORE LM++(''# M++#(+*( L"M+( +M+#* LM+!%*##) LM+++#*""

    BANK ROA )M+%+M(&) #M"(%M!"( "M%' +M+!% !M'"#M&)' !M%%&M(*#

    CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN M+#'*#"" M+!*%!!' !M*+ +M+&( LM++!!!#) M+(%*()"

    CAPRIO SUPER MEAN M+##&*'! M+!&'&&! "M!& +M+#" M++"*!"' M+'%"(*&

    INTERNATIONAL M(()'"(' M!("!&"& %M&" +M+++ M%%!"!%* !!!M'+%

    TABLE 7. WALD TEST OF EXOGENEITY

    TEST FOR EXOGENEITY

    Instruments: BANK CONCENTRATION BANK CREDIT / DEPOSIT RATIO

    CAPRIO RESTRICTION MEAN

    BANK Z SCORE BANK ROA CAPRIO CAPIT MEAN CAPRIO

    SUPER MEAN INTERNATIONAL

    Wald test of exogeneity chi2(1) = 0.20 Prob > chi2 = 0.6560

  • 8/10/2019 2012 Angelo Leogrande Cooperative Banks vs Financial Crisis

    35/35

    TABLE 8. PROBIT REGRESSION ORDERED CRISIS

    F/;B38 /.1/.993;4 JC2B./ ;6 ;B9 K (!

    N05< 7O3"G*H K #*M+( F/;B P 7O3" K +M++++

    Q;1 E9.CSJ>?JTA,TUSJ L"M*)!M&%# !M(!)M'!# L!M(# +M+)# L'M#%*M*'# M#)')(("

    >A?YUT Y?FSXUT A,TUS "M+%"M'%! M(**"'*) "M&' +M+!! M%('!++* #M'+*M!)!

    >,FAUS A?XTAU>TUSJ LM%')!"&! M!((%* L"M'% +M++) LM)!'++*& LM!"+"%+(

    V,JW Z X>SA? LM+'"!&'% M+#+*#(( L"M+! +M+%& LM!""(*## LM++!&!*'

    V,JW AS, 'M&""M+#" "M)%*M'() "M"* +M+"" *M#'(M'&& !"!M+(#

    >,FAUS >,FUT :?,J M"**&'& M!&"&)%" !M*' +M+&+ M+++&+&% M&*)'"%'

    >,FAUS X[F?A :?,J M"("&+%) M!"*!++) "M!! +M+#& M+!*%(!* M&"&()

    UJT?AJ,TUSJ,Q 'M#!&M'!' !M&*%M+&! #M*' +M+++ #M!*!M##% *M%#*M)*)

    >SJXT,JT L#M(M!)% "M!*+M* L!M'! +M!+' L(M)#!M#(" M(&(++%'

    TABLE 9. MARGINAL EFFECTS PROBIT REGRESSION ORDERED CRISIS

    !"#$"$# &"'('( &!$)* "* (+# $""!" , -./,/ 0123 &456*'5789:;SSF?A,TU=? V,JWX LM&&%(!*% M"#"#!)% L"M#* +M+!( L!M+!+M+&& LM+**#)#)

    V,JW >SJ>?JTA,TUSJ LM#'(&)") M!)*!&)( L!M*% +M+&" LM(#)#"( M++#!'!&

    >A?YUT Y?FSXUT A,TUS M"&!)"*" M+()(* #M"+ +M++! M+*(#*#" M%+'"'&"

    >,FAUS A?XTAU>TUSJ LM+&((!## M+"+*')' L"M(& +M++' LM+*))!!! LM+!''!&&

    V,JW Z X>SA? LM++(''# M++#(+*( L"M+( +M+#* LM+!%*##) LM+++#*""

    V,JW AS, )M+%+M(&) #M"(%M!"( "M%' +M+!% !M'"#M&)' !M%%&M(*#

    >,FAUS >,FUT :?,J M+#'*#"" M+!*%!!' !M*+ +M+&( LM++!!!#) M+(%*()"

    >,FAUS X[F?A :?,J M+##&*'! M+!&'&&! "M!& +M+#" M++"*!"' M+'%"(*&

    UJT?AJ,TUSJ,Q M(()'"(' M!("!&"& %M&" +M+++ M%%!"!%* !!!M'+%

    TABLE 10. TOBIT REGRESSION: COST OF THE CRISIS

    T;B38 /.1/.993;4 JC2B./ ;6 ;B9 K (!

    \G *I '"H K #M++ F/;B P \ K +M++%*

    Q;1 E9.CSSF?A,TU=? V,JWX L!M('#M%*% )M("#M*'( L"M+" +M+%) L#&+M(#* LM!*&*(#(

    V,JW >SJ>?JTA,TUSJ L!M()(M%"( )M()&M*(# L"M+# +M+%' L#M&%#M(!) LM#!!#'"'

    >A?YUT Y?FSXUT A,TUSJ (M*""M!#% "M)"#M&'* "M)! +M++( "M"((M)** !M#&'M'#(

    FAU=,T? A?XTAU>TUSJ L"M!'!M"+' M)(&)'+& L"M%( +M+!' L#M*!"M+"' LM%!+#)'"

    V,JW Z X>SA? LM"*&("(% M!%*(% L!M*( +M+ LM&*&+)+" M++#'"&&

    V,JW AS, #M%!+M&+& !M!*'M')! "M)& +M++' !M+!)M#(% &M)+"M'#&

    >,FAUS >,FUT :?,J LM&!)*+"" M#)#"#!# L!M#& +M!)! L!M")%M*(! M"%(!''#

    >,FAUS X[F?A :?,J !+%M*)# M#))&'&" "M(+ +M++* M"(#+**! !M)"'M&'!

    UJT?AJ,TUSJ,Q !M#&"M(+% %M")*M)!' #M!& +M++" %*&M!)" "M"!+M""'>SJXT,JT ##( )#' ) !+' "%# + %" + '() L! ")" &(* ! *&) "&!