17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

9
8 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE REVISITING MARKET EFFICIENCY: THE STOCK MARKET AS A COMPLEX ADAPTIVE SYSTEM by Michael J. Mauboussin, Credit Suisse First Boston t is time to shift the emphasis of the debate about market efficiency. Most academics and practitioners agree that markets are efficient by a reasonable Take, for example, the earnings expectations game. 1 In a complex adaptive system, the sum is greater than the parts. So it is not possible to understand the stock market by paying attention to individual analysts. Managers who place a dispro- portionate focus on the perceived desires of these analysts may be managing to the wrong metrics— and ultimately destroying shareholder value. A bet- ter appreciation for how markets work will shift management attention away from individual ana- lysts to the market itself, thus capturing the aggrega- tion of many diverse views. Standard capital markets theory still has a lot to recommend it. 2 The theory maintains that a company’s stock price represents an unbiased estimate of its intrinsic value, and that investors cannot develop trading rules that earn “excess” returns over time. From a practical standpoint, these predictions closely mirror the realities of today’s markets. Year after year, the vast majority of professional money managers underperform the broad market averages. So few are the inves- tors who consistently outperform the averages that people like Warren Buffett have assumed near-legendary status. I 1. See “Just Say No to Wall Street: Putting A Stop to the Earnings Game” by Joseph Fuller and Michael C. Jensen in this issue. 2. For an excellent survey of the accomplishments of market efficiency theory, see Ray Ball, “The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency: Accomplishments and Limitations,” in The New Corporate Finance: Where Theory Meets Practice, 3 rd edition, edited by Donald H. Chew (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2001), pp. 20-33. operational criterion: there is no systematic way to exploit opportunities for superior gains. But we need to reorient the discussion to how this operational efficiency arises. The crux of the debate boils down to whether we should consider investors to be rational, well informed, and homogeneous—the backbone of standard capital markets theory—or potentially irrational, operating with incomplete information, and relying on varying decision rules. The latter characteristics are part and parcel of a relatively newly articulated phenomenon that re- searchers at the Santa Fe Institute and elsewhere call complex adaptive systems. Why should corporate managers care about how market efficiency arises? In truth, executives can make many corporate finance decisions inde- pendent of the means of market efficiency. But if complex adaptive systems do a better job explain- ing how markets work, there are critical implica- tions for areas such as risk management and investor communications.

description

Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

Transcript of 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

Page 1: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

8JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

REVISITING MARKETEFFICIENCY: THE STOCKMARKET AS A COMPLEXADAPTIVE SYSTEM

by Michael J. Mauboussin,Credit Suisse First Boston

t is time to shift the emphasis of thedebate about market efficiency. Mostacademics and practitioners agree thatmarkets are efficient by a reasonable

Take, for example, the earnings expectationsgame.1 In a complex adaptive system, the sum isgreater than the parts. So it is not possible tounderstand the stock market by paying attention toindividual analysts. Managers who place a dispro-portionate focus on the perceived desires of theseanalysts may be managing to the wrong metrics—and ultimately destroying shareholder value. A bet-ter appreciation for how markets work will shiftmanagement attention away from individual ana-lysts to the market itself, thus capturing the aggrega-tion of many diverse views.

Standard capital markets theory still has a lotto recommend it.2 The theory maintains that acompany’s stock price represents an unbiasedestimate of its intrinsic value, and that investorscannot develop trading rules that earn “excess”returns over time. From a practical standpoint,these predictions closely mirror the realities oftoday’s markets. Year after year, the vast majorityof professional money managers underperformthe broad market averages. So few are the inves-tors who consistently outperform the averagesthat people like Warren Buffett have assumednear-legendary status.

I

1. See “Just Say No to Wall Street: Putting A Stop to the Earnings Game” byJoseph Fuller and Michael C. Jensen in this issue.

2. For an excellent survey of the accomplishments of market efficiency theory,see Ray Ball, “The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency: Accomplishments andLimitations,” in The New Corporate Finance: Where Theory Meets Practice, 3rdedition, edited by Donald H. Chew (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2001), pp. 20-33.

operational criterion: there is no systematic way toexploit opportunities for superior gains. But we needto reorient the discussion to how this operationalefficiency arises. The crux of the debate boils downto whether we should consider investors to berational, well informed, and homogeneous—thebackbone of standard capital markets theory—orpotentially irrational, operating with incompleteinformation, and relying on varying decision rules.The latter characteristics are part and parcel of arelatively newly articulated phenomenon that re-searchers at the Santa Fe Institute and elsewhere callcomplex adaptive systems.

Why should corporate managers care abouthow market efficiency arises? In truth, executivescan make many corporate finance decisions inde-pendent of the means of market efficiency. But ifcomplex adaptive systems do a better job explain-ing how markets work, there are critical implica-tions for areas such as risk management andinvestor communications.

Page 2: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

9VOLUME 14 NUMBER 4 WINTER 2002

The efficient markets hypothesis and its closecounterpart the random walk theory have beenfixtures on the financial economics scene for wellover 30 years. But the theories make predictions thatdo not match the empirical data.3 Financial research-ers have documented several anomalies that runcounter to market efficiency. The theory also rests onthe assumption of rational, well-informed inves-tors—an assumption that is shaky at best. And whileprice changes are roughly consistent with a randomwalk, price fluctuations come in greater size than thetheory predicts. The obvious case in point is thestock market crash of October 19, 1987, a day the S&P500 plummeted 22.6%. Such return outliers arecrucial for executives trying to manage risk.

The goal of this paper is to explore whethermarkets are, in fact, better understood as complexadaptive systems. I follow roughly the approachoutlined by Thomas Kuhn in his seminal book, TheStructure of Scientific Revolutions, which attempts toexplain “paradigm shifts.” A paradigm shift is anevolution in a model or theory. Kuhn’s processallows us to break down the evolution of ideas intofour parts. First, a theory is laid out to explain aphenomenon. In our case, the starting point isstandard capital markets theory and the efficientmarkets hypothesis, which together seek to explainmarket behavior. Second, researchers test the theoryby collecting empirical data, and eventually find factsthat are inconsistent with the prevailing theory. Thethird phase involves “stretching” the old theory—especially important for those who have a personalstake in the prevailing theory—to accommodate thenew findings. I will describe some of these anoma-lous findings and provide some evidence of theorystretching. Finally, a new theory emerges that over-takes the old, offering greater fidelity to the facts andgreater predictive power. Complex adaptive systemsmay provide such a theory. The new model offers aricher understanding of how markets work, andshows how the market shares properties and charac-teristics with other complex adaptive systems. At theclose of this article, I discuss the practical implicationsof this new theory for managers and investors.

STANDARD CAPITAL MARKETS THEORY

The bulk of economics is based on equilibriumsystems—a balance between supply and demand,risk and reward, price and quantity. Articulated byAlfred Marshall in the 1890s, this view stems from theidea that economics is a science akin to Newtonianphysics, with an identifiable link between cause andeffect and implied predictability. When an equilib-rium system is hit by an “exogenous shock,” such asnews of a major default or a surprise interest rate cut(or hike) by the Fed, the system absorbs the shockand quickly returns to an equilibrium state.

The irony of this equilibrium perspective is thatthe convenient, predictable science that economiststacitly hold as an ideal—namely, 19th-century phys-ics—has been subsumed by advances such as quan-tum theory, where “indeterminacy” is commonplace.Most systems, in nature and in business, are not inequilibrium but rather in constant flux. Classical phys-ics offers a good first approximation of reality, butquantum physics is more broadly applicable, while stillaccommodating what is already “known.” The equilib-rium science that economists have mimicked hasevolved; economics, by and large, has not.4

Capital markets theory, largely developed overthe past 50 years, still rests on a few key assumptions,primarily efficient markets and investor rationality.We consider both in turn.

Stock market efficiency suggests that stock pricesincorporate all relevant information when that infor-mation is readily available and widely disseminated(a reasonable description of the U.S. stock market),which implies that there is no systematic way toexploit trading opportunities and achieve superiorresults. As such, purchasing stocks is a zero netpresent value proposition; you will be compensatedfor the risk that you assume but no more, over time.5

Market efficiency does not say that stock prices arealways “correct,” but it does say that stock prices arenot mispriced in any kind of “systematic” or predict-able way. The random walk theory, which is relatedto the efficient markets hypothesis, holds that secu-rity price changes are independent of one another.

3. For a recent summary of the empirical features that economic theory hasdifficulty explaining, see John Y. Campbell, “Asset Pricing at the Millennium,” TheJournal of Finance, Vol. 55 (2000), pp. 1515-1567.

4. For a particularly forceful elaboration of this point, see Philip Mirowski,More Heat than Light (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).

5. Sandy Grossman and Joe Stiglitz noted the following paradox about efficientmarkets: they pointed out that if markets were completely efficient, there could beno return earned by information gathering, and hence no one would trade. Thus,in practice, there must be “sufficient profit opportunities, i.e., inefficiencies, tocompensate investors for the cost of trading and information-gathering.” SeeSanford J. Grossman and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “On the Impossibility of InformationallyEfficient Markets,” American Economic Review, Vol. 70 (1980), pp. 393-408.

Page 3: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

10JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

Accordingly, changes in prices come only as a resultof the arrival of unexpected information that is, bydefinition, random.

One predicted outcome of the efficient marketshypothesis is modest trading activity and limitedprice fluctuations.6 As investors receive informationand agree on its meaning, prices can adjust withoutsubstantial trading activity. Another assumption isthat investors can treat expected stock price returnsas independent, identically distributed variables—unleashing probability calculus. Often, model build-ers assume that stock price changes are normally, orlog normally, distributed.

Rational investors are people who can quickly andaccurately assess and optimize risk/reward out-comes. They are constantly seeking profit opportu-nities, and it is the very efforts of such investors tomake money that lead to market efficiency. Thisframework of investor behavior is reflected in theCapital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), which suggestsa linear relationship between risk and return. Inother words, rational investors seek the highestreturn for a given level of risk.

Do we need all investors to be rational profit-seekers? Not necessarily. Joel Stern has used themetaphor of the “lead steer” to explain why themarket appears to follow an economic model evenif very few investors do so. To paraphrase Stern, “Ifyou want to know where a herd of cattle is heading,you need not interview every steer in the herd, justthe lead steer.” The basic idea is that there is arelatively small group of super-smart investors whodo understand the economic model (as opposed tothe conventional accounting model) of the firm, inwhich value is driven by expected changes inoperating cash flow (as opposed to EPS). And it isthese lead steers who are setting prices at the margin.Hence, companies need not worry about the typicalinvestor because the investors at the margin—the leadsteers—ensure that prices, on average, are set correctly.

The lead steer metaphor represents a central-ized mindset: all you need are a few smart investorsto ensure that markets are efficient. As we will see,however, there is no need to assume the presenceof “leaders” to arrive at market efficiency.

Classical Capital Markets Theory Tested

Testing began on the efficient markets hypoth-esis as soon as the ink dried on the original research.However, there is an inherent difficulty in testingeconomic theory. Economists, unlike some otherscientists, have no laboratory; their theories can beevaluated only on their ability to “explain” pastevents and predict future ones. Another potentialproblem is the availability of quality data. Research-ers in finance have the Center for Research inSecurity Prices database—the primary source ofdetailed information on stocks and the stock market—which has comprehensive data going back 80 years.

In general, there are four areas where the classictheory significantly falls short:

Stock market returns are not normal, as capitalmarkets theory suggests. Rather, return distributionsexhibit high kurtosis; that is, the “tails” of thedistribution are “fatter” and the mean is higher thanpredicted by a normal distribution. In ordinarylanguage, this means that periods of relatively mod-est change are interspersed with higher-than-pre-dicted changes—namely, booms and crashes.7 Fig-ures 1 and 2 illustrate the point graphically.

The observation that stock price returns do notfollow normal distributions is not new. As EugeneFama, one of the fathers of efficient markets theory,wrote back in 1965:

If the population of price changes is strictlynormal, on average for any stock…an observationmore than five standard deviations from the meanshould be observed about once every 7,000 years. Infact such observations seem to occur about onceevery three to four years.8

The 22.6% stock market decline of October 19,1987 was one of these fat-tailed observations. In aworld of normal distributions, the probability of a moveas large as the crash was so remote as to be effectivelyimpossible.9 The academic reaction to the crash wasrevealing. When asked about the 1987 crash in a recentinterview, Fama responded: “I think the crash in ’87was a mistake.” Merton Miller offered an explanation

6. See Fischer Black’s famous article, “Noise,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 41(1986). In that article, Black said that trading is the result of people with differentbeliefs that ultimately derive from different information.

7. Biologists will see a parallel between these observations and the theory ofpunctuated equilibrium. Stephen Jay Gould and Niles Eldredge articulated thetheory of punctuated equilibrium in 1972. The basic case is that evolutionary

changes are jerky rather than gradual. Long periods of stasis are interrupted byabrupt and dramatic periods of change.

8. Eugene Fama, “The Behavior of Stock Prices,” Journal of Business, January1965.

9. See Jens Carsten Jackwerth and Mark Rubinstein, “Recovering ProbabilityDistributions from Option Prices,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. 51 (1996), p. 1612.

Page 4: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

11VOLUME 14 NUMBER 4 WINTER 2002

for the crash consistent with investor rationality—butthen rather tellingly went on to cite the research ofBenoit Mandelbrot, a mathematician who as early asthe 1960s pointed out that stock price volatility was toogreat to justify use of a normal distribution.10

That the academic community and investmentcommunity so frequently talk about events five ormore standard deviations from the mean should bea sufficient indication that the widely used statisticalmeasures are inappropriate for these types of distri-butions. Yet the assumption of normal distributionspersists.

The random walk assertion is not supported by thedata. John Campbell, Andrew Lo, and Craig

MacKinlay, after applying a battery of empirical tests,concluded, “financial asset returns are predictable tosome degree.”11 Furthermore, other finance research-ers—building on the work of Mandelbrot—havesuggested that there is a long-term memory compo-nent in capital markets. That is, return series are oftenboth persistent and trend-reinforced.

Risk and reward are not linearly related. In theirmuch-cited 1992 survey of the empirical tests ofthe CAPM (which included their own analysis forthe period 1963-1990) that appeared in the Jour-nal of Finance, Eugene Fama and Kenneth Frenchconcluded that the “tests do not support the mostbasic prediction of the SLB [Sharpe-Lintner-Black]

FIGURE 1FREQUENCYDISTRIBUTION OF S&P 500FIVE-DAY RETURNS:NORMAL VERSUS ACTUAL(JANUARY 1968–FEBRUARY2002)

FIGURE 2FREQUENCY DIFFERENCE:NORMAL VERSUS ACTUALFIVE-DAY RETURNS(JANUARY 1968–FEBRUARY2002)

10. See Merton H. Miller, Financial Innovations and Market Volatility(Cambridge, MA: Blackwell Publishers, 1991), pp. 100-103. Miller refers to BenoitB. Mandelbrot, “The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices,” in The Random

Character of Stock Market Prices, edited by Paul Cootner (Cambridge, MA: MITPress, 1964). Mandelbrot’s paper was originally published in 1963.

11. Campbell, J.Y., Lo, A.W., MacKinlay, A.C., The Econometrics of FinancialMarkets (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997), p. 80.

Fre

qu

ency

100

9

80

60

40

20

0–9 –8 –7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Standard Deviation

Dif

fere

nce

in

Fre

qu

ency

35

0

–35Standard Deviation

–8 –7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Page 5: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

12JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

model, that average returns are positively relatedto the market’s.”

Fama and French also reported that two othernon-CAPM factors—firm size and market-to-bookvalue—were systematically correlated with stockreturns during the measured period. However, Famaand French maintained a “rational asset-pricingframework,” which means they identified factorsassociated with various returns and assumed thatthose returns were attributable to risk.

Investors are not rational. The case here rests onseveral points. The first is the growing body ofevidence from decision theorists showing that peoplemake systematic judgment errors.12 One of the best-documented illustrations is “prospect theory,” whichshows that individual risk preferences are pro-foundly influenced by how information is presentedor “packaged.”13 For example, investors act in a risk-averse way when making choices between riskyoutcomes, conflicting with the “rational” behaviorpredicted by expected utility theory.

Second, investors trade more than the theorypredicts. In order to explain the real-life tradingactivity, Fischer Black developed the theory of“noise” and “noise traders.” Black describes noisetrading as “trading on noise as if it were information”even though “from an objective point they [noisetraders] would be better off not trading.” Moststriking is Black’s introductory comment that “[noisetheories] were all derived originally as part of a broadeffort to apply the logic behind the capital assetpricing model to…behavior that does not fit conven-tional notions of optimization.”14

The final point is that people generally oper-ate using inductive, not deductive, processes tomake economic decisions. Since no individual hasaccess to all information, investors must base theirjudgments not only on what they “know,” but onwhat they think others believe. The fact thatinvestors make such decisions using rules ofthumb suggests a fundamental indeterminacy ineconomics.15 Asset prices are a good proxy foraggregate expectations. However, if enough agentsadopt decision rules based on price activity—

generated either consciously or randomly—theresulting price trend can be self-reinforcing.

Despite its apparent shortcomings, the estab-lished theory has significantly advanced our under-standing of capital markets. But is it approaching thelimit of its usefulness? The introduction of a newtheory, along with the requisite computational powerto model it, may usher in a new era of understandingof capital market behavior. But a new theory mustnot only explain why the old theory worked, it mustadd predictive power.

THE STOCK MARKET AS A COMPLEXADAPTIVE SYSTEM

Now we lay out the challenging theory: capitalmarkets as complex adaptive systems. This model ismore consistent with what is known in other sciences,such as physics and biology, and appears to be moredescriptive of actual capital markets activity. First, weprovide a description of complex adaptive systems,identifying their key properties and attributes. Next, wecompare the new theory’s predictions to actual marketbehavior. Finally, we check to see if the theory adds toour understanding of markets, while preserving thepower of classic markets theory.

A New Model of Investor Interaction

Put two people in a room and ask them to tradea commodity, and not much happens. Add a fewmore people to the room and the activity may pickup, but the interactions remain relatively uninterest-ing. The system is too static, too lifeless, to reflectwhat we see in the capital markets. But, as we addmore agents to the system, something remarkablehappens: it turns into a so-called “complex adaptivesystem,” replete with new, lifelike characteristics. Ina tangible way, the system becomes more complexthan the pieces that it comprises. Importantly, thistransition—often called “self-organized criticality”—occurs without design or help from any outsideagent. Rather, it is a direct function of the dynamicinteractions among the agents in the system.16

12. See Max H. Bazerman, Judgment in Managerial Decision Making (NewYork: John Wiley & Sons, 1986); also Richard H. Thaler, The Winner’s Curse:Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Life (New York: Free Press, 1992).

13. See Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, “Prospect Theory: An Analysisof Decision Under Risk,” Econometrica, Vol. 47 (1979), pp. 263-291.

14. See Black (1986), cited earlier.

15. W. Brian Arthur, “Complexity in Economics and Financial Markets,”Complexity, Vol. 1 (1995), pp. 20-25.

16. For a discussion of self-organized criticality, see Per Bak, How NatureWorks (New York: Springer-Verlag New York, 1996). In fact, theoretical biologistStuart Kauffman has theorized that a similar process explains the beginning of life.See Stuart Kauffman, At Home in the Universe: The Search for Laws of Self-Organization and Complexity (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995).

Page 6: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

13VOLUME 14 NUMBER 4 WINTER 2002

Physicist Per Bak uses a sand pile to illustrateself-organized criticality. Start to sprinkle sand on aflat surface and the grains settle pretty much wherethey fall; the process can be modeled with classicalphysics. After a modest pile is created, the actionpicks up, with small sand slides. Once the pile is ofsufficient size, the system becomes “out of balance,”and little disturbances can cause full-fledged ava-lanches. We cannot understand these large changesby studying the individual grains. Rather, the systemitself gains properties that we must consider sepa-rately from the individual pieces.

A central characteristic of a complex adaptivesystem is “critical points.” That is, large changesoccur as the result of the accumulation of smallstimuli—just as the accumulated weight of manysand grains precipitates large avalanches. This im-plies that large fluctuations are endogenous to sucha system. Critical points are a formal way to expressthe concept of “the straw that broke the camel’sback.” Seeking specific causes for even big-scaleeffects is often an exercise in futility.

A complex adaptive system exhibits a numberof essential properties and mechanisms.17

Aggregation. Aggregation is the emergenceof complex, large-scale behaviors from the collec-tive interactions of many less-complex agents. Anexample of this phenomenon is an ant colony. Ifyou were to “interview” any single ant about whatit does, you would hear a narrowly defined taskor set of tasks. However, because of the interac-tion of all the ants, a functional and adaptivecolony emerges. In capital markets language, thebehavior of the market “emerges” from the inter-actions of investors.18 This is what Adam Smithcalled the “invisible hand.”

Adaptive decision rules. Agents within a com-plex adaptive system take information from theenvironment, combine it with their own interactionwith the environment, and derive decision rules.19 Inturn, various decision rules compete with one an-other based on their “fitness,” with the most effectiverules surviving. This process allows for adaptation,which explains the “adaptive” within the phrase“complex adaptive system.” We can consider indi-vidual trading rules and investment rules of thumb

as decision rules in the capital markets. Notably, theconcept of adaptive decision rules is consistent withthe disappearance of “anomalies.” Given that inves-tors seek such profit opportunities and refine theirdecision rules to compete them away, anomalies“carry with them the seeds of their own decay.”20

Nonlinearity. In a linear model, the value of thewhole equals the sum of the parts. In nonlinearsystems, the aggregate behavior is more complicatedthan would be predicted by totaling the parts. Thispoint can be illustrated with a basic prey/predatormodel. Given some basic variables—predators andprey in a given area, the rate of interaction betweenthe two, and a predator “efficiency” measure—thepredator/prey model produces the nonlinear out-come of feasts and famines. This is because there isan interaction effect—the variables ebb and flowtogether and create booms and busts. For the capitalmarkets, this means that cause and effect may not besimplistically linked but may instead interact toproduce exaggerated outcomes.

Feedback loops. A feedback system is one inwhich the output of one iteration becomes the inputof the next iteration. Feedback loops can amplify(positive feedback) or dampen (negative feedback)an effect. One example of positive feedback is themultiplier effect, taught in basic economics. Here,additional resources gained by one agent are typi-cally passed on in some way to other agents,magnifying the impact of the original stimulus. In thecapital markets, an example of a feedback loopwould be the practice of “momentum” investors,who use security price changes as a buy/sell cue,allowing for self-reinforcing behavior.

Does the Theory Conform to Reality?

We now have a framework that, while relativelynew, is both consistent with advances made in othersciences and promising in its descriptive potential.But it must face the real test: explaining the facts. Wehave established both the basics of traditional capitalmarkets theory as well as some inconsistenciesbetween that theory and reality. Now we can see ifthe new framework helps bridge the gap betweenthe two.

17. The rest of this section relies on the work of John H. Holland, HiddenOrder: How Adaptation Builds Complexity (Reading, MA: Helix Books, 1995).

18. This property is called “emergence” and is a defining characteristic of acomplex adaptive system. The inability to fully explain emergent properties stemsfrom the large number of nonlinear interactions.

19. For a more detailed discussion of evolving decisions rules, see Murray Gell-Mann, The Quark and the Jaguar (New York: W.H. Freeman and Company, 1994).

20. Merton Miller, “The History of Finance: An Eyewitness Account,” Journalof Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 13 (Summer 2000).

Page 7: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

14JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

Non-normal distributions. Understanding thecapital markets as complex adaptive systems wouldaccount for the high kurtosis (“fat tails”) seen inreturn distributions. In particular, periods of stabilitypunctuated by rapid change, attributable to criticallevels, is a characteristic of many complex systems,including tectonic plate activity, beehives, and evo-lution. Hence, the observed return distributions,booms and crashes, and “high” levels of tradingactivity would all be consistent—even predicted—by the new model.

Random walk—almost. Trend persistence isfound throughout nature, and it should be no greatsurprise that it appears to some degree in capitalmarkets. New statistical models may help analyzesuch trends. The main point, however, is that theprice activity of the market, assuming it is a complexadaptive system, would be similar to a classicrandom walk. The new model, however, wouldappear to do a better job of explaining persistencein returns to the extent that such persistence exists.

Homogeneous versus heterogeneous expec-tations. The ability to relax the assumption ofrational investors—and the associated assumption ofrisk/reward efficiency—also argues for the complexadaptive system model. Shifting from the mindset ofeconomic agents as deductive decision-makers,viewed either singly or collectively, to inductivedecision makers is crucial. Under most circum-stances, it is reasonable to assume that the collective,inductive judgments of agents will yield an assetprice similar to “intrinsic value” when their errors areunrelated to each other. However, if certain decisionrules are able to gain footing, the resulting non-independence of errors can lead to self-reinforcingtrends.21 This reduction in decision-rule diversityoffers important insight into stock market instability.The key here is that complex adaptive systems canexplain the dynamics of the market without assum-ing that investors have homogeneous expectations.

Portfolio manager performance. A complexadaptive system may offer a better descriptive modelof the market, but offers little in the way of predict-ability beyond structural generalizations. The poorperformance of active portfolio managers is consis-

tent with the new model as well as with marketefficiency. That point made, it remains possibleunder either theory that certain investors—WarrenBuffett and Legg Mason’s Bill Miller, for example—may be “hard-wired” to be successful investors. Inthis sense, “hard-wired” suggests innate mentalprocesses, fortified with practice, that allow forsystematically superior security selection.

Artificial models simulate market action. Re-searchers at the Santa Fe Institute have created anartificial stock market that mimics actual marketbehavior.22 Their model provides agents with mul-tiple “expectational models,” allows the agents todiscard poorly performing rules in favor of better-performing rules, and provides for a discernible“intrinsic value.” Agents are assumed to have hetero-geneous expectations. The model shows that whenthe agents replace their expectational models at alow rate, the classical capital markets theory prevails.However, when new models are adopted moreactively, the market turns into a complex adaptivesystem and exhibits the features of real markets(trading activity, booms and crashes). The Santa FeInstitute model, while admittedly simple, illuminatesa path for understanding actual capital marketsbehavior.23

The decentralized approach inherent in com-plex adaptive systems can feel very unsettling.Consider, for example, computer scientist MitchResnick’s observations about the behavior of flocksof birds:

Most people assume that birds play a game offollow-the-leader: the bird at the front of the flockleads, and the others follow. But that’s not so. Infact, most bird flocks don’t have leaders at all.There is no special “leader bird.” Rather, the flockis an example of what some people call “self-organization.” Each bird in the flock follows a setof simple rules, reacting to the birds nearby it.Orderly flock patterns arise from these simple,local interactions. The bird in the front is not aleader in any meaningful sense—it just happensto end up there. The flock is organized without anorganizer, coordinated without a coordinator. 24

21. See Jack L. Treynor, “Market Efficiency and the Bean Jar Experiment,”Financial Analysts Journal, May-June 1987.

22. W. Brian Arthur, et al., “Asset Pricing Under Endogenous Expectations inan Artificial Stock Market,” in The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II,edited by W.B. Arthur, S.N. Durlaf, and D.A. Lane (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley,1997).

23. For a more recent discussion, see Blake LeBaron, “Volatility Magnificationand Persistence in an Agent Based Financial Market,” Working Paper, BrandeisUniversity, March 2001.

24. Mitchel Resnick, Turtles, Termites and Traffic Jams (Cambridge, MA: MITPress, 1994), p. 3.

Page 8: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

15VOLUME 14 NUMBER 4 WINTER 2002

Order, then, is not always the result of leader-ship, but can arise from the dynamic interaction ofagents employing relatively simple decision rules. Ina 1993 study, Dan Gode and Shyam Sunder testedthis possibility by creating markets in which tradersused simple, and not necessarily realistic, decisionrules to submit their bids and offers. The study foundthat markets were still remarkably efficient; in otherwords, even dumb agents achieve smart results. Intheir own words:

Allocative efficiency of a double auction marketderives largely from its structure, independent oftraders’ motivation, intelligence, or learning. AdamSmith’s invisible hand may be more powerful thansome may have thought; it can generate aggregaterationality not only from individual rationality butalso from individual irrationality.

These findings stand in stark contrast to the leadsteer metaphor. Most people feel more comfortablewith the notion that prices are set by smart investors.But there is growing evidence that the aggregationof many investors is sufficient to create a well-functioning market.

While the theory of the market as a complexadaptive system arguably does a better job ofexplaining reality (crashes, trading activity) than theold model, it does so at the expense of a difficulttrade-off: by incorporating more realistic—albeit stillsimple—assumptions we lose the crispness of cur-rent economic models. This paradigm shift requiresletting go of the determinate and accepting indetermi-nacy; substituting equations with unique equilibriumsolutions for models with multiple equilibria; lookingto other fields of science for relevant metaphors.

PRACTICAL CONSIDERATIONS

But even if capital markets have a lot in commonwith other natural systems, what does this newparadigm mean for investors and corporate practitio-ners? How should they change their behavior, if atall, to accommodate the complex adaptive systemframework? Can old tools be applied to the newreality? Here are some thoughts.

The risk and reward link may not be clear.Traditional finance theory assumes a linear relation

between risk and reward, with the debate surround-ing how to correctly measure risk. In a complexadaptive system, however, risk and reward may notbe so simplistically linked.25 The fact that the tails ofempirical distributions are fatter than predicted bymost models is essential to consider in risk manage-ment, where extreme outcomes can undermine themost brilliant economic models (witness the case ofLong-Term Capital Management).

What are the practical implications? For mostcorporate investment decisions, the Capital AssetPricing Model is still probably the best availableestimate of investment risk. But managers must beaware that their stock price may be subject tovolatility swings beyond what the standard theorysuggests.

Don’t listen to agents, listen to the market.Most managers try to allocate capital so as to createshareholder value. However, when faced with sig-nificant decisions they often trust the counsel ofselect individuals (i.e., investment bankers and ana-lysts) in favor of reviewing empirical market studies.Complex adaptive systems show us that the marketis smarter than the individual. Most studies infinancial economics are at the market level, andhence capture the benefit of aggregation. Managersthat weight the advice of experts over the evidenceof the market can make poor decisions.

Look for diversity breakdowns. Many corpo-rate managers view the stock market with somemisgiving. On balance, this skepticism is unfounded—markets appear to function well when there is adiversity of decision rules and agent errors areindependent.26 However, if too many investorseither mimic one another or don’t participate, thenmarkets can become fragile, leading to substantialvolatility. Managers should look for opinion ex-tremes—times when investors are all acting thesame. Potentially armed with better information,managers may be able to take action by buying orselling securities in order to enhance value. At aminimum, these occasions require a sharp focus oninvestor communication.

Cause and effect thinking is futile if notdangerous. People like to link effects with causes,and capital market activities are no different. Forexample, politicians created numerous panelsafter the 1987 market crash in a futile effort to

25. Tonis Vaga, Profiting From Chaos (New York: McGraw Hill, 1994). 26. Norman L. Johnson, “Diversity in Decentralized Systems: Enabling Self-Organizing Solutions, LANL, LA-UR-99-6281, 1999.

Page 9: 17-Revisiting Market Efficiency_The Stock Market as a Complex Adaptive System

16JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

identify its “cause.”27 A nonlinear approach, how-ever, suggests that large-scale changes can comefrom small-scale inputs. As a result, cause-and-effect thinking can be both simplistic and counter-productive, particularly when a “quick fix” endsup doing more harm than good. To the extent thatthe complex adaptive system theory reinforcesthe notion that a random disturbance can some-times have an enormous effect, and restrains thenatural inclination to impose a solution, it may bea positive step forward.

Traditional discounted cash flow analysis re-mains the key to value. This is true for three reasons.First, discounted cash flow (DCF) spells out firstprinciples: the value of a financial asset is the presentvalue of future cash flows discounted appropriately.Second, a DCF model remains an excellent frame-work for sorting out key investment issues. Finally,there is arguably no better available quantitativemodel than DCF for crystallizing expectations im-pounded in stock prices.28

CONCLUSIONS

In a widely cited 1953 paper, Milton Friedmanpointed out that the plausibility of a model’s assump-tions is not as important as the accuracy of its

predictions.29 We argue that standard capital marketstheory provides good predictions for the most part.But there are some important exceptions. For ex-ample, asset price changes do not conform to normaldistributions, the evidence in support of CAPM isambiguous, and trading activity is much greater thanthe theory predicts.

Over the past few decades, researchers havedefined some of the prime properties and character-istics of complex adaptive systems. These systemsare present throughout nature, and their generalfeatures appear to be a good description of howcapital markets work. Importantly, complex adap-tive systems predict stock price change distributionssimilar to what we see empirically, while showingwhy it is that markets are so hard for investors to beat.Further, the underlying assumptions behind com-plex adaptive systems are at once simple yet do notrequire restrictive assumptions about investor ratio-nality or lead steers.

From a practical standpoint, managers whosubscribe to standard capital markets theory andoperate on the premise of stock market efficiencywill probably not go too far astray. However, com-plex adaptive systems may provide a useful perspec-tive in areas like risk management and investorcommunication.

MICHAEL MAUBOUSSIN

is a Managing Director and Chief U.S. Investment Strategist atCredit Suisse First Boston in New York City.

27. See Miller (1991), cited earlier.28. For extensive discussion of this argument, see Alfred Rappaport and

Michael J. Mauboussin, Expectations Investing (Boston: Harvard Business SchoolPress, 2001).

29. Milton Friedman, Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: The Universityof Chicago Press, 1953).