1. SSRN-id1497205 -- corporate social responsibility

download 1. SSRN-id1497205 -- corporate social responsibility

of 80

description

corporate social responsibility

Transcript of 1. SSRN-id1497205 -- corporate social responsibility

  • Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1497205Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1497205

    Deviations from Expected Stakeholder Management, Firm

    Value, and Corporate Governance

    Bradley W. Benson* Department of Economics and Finance

    Louisiana Tech University Ruston, LA 71270

    318-257-2389 [email protected]

    Wallace N. Davidson III

    Finance Department Mailcode 4626 Southern Illinois University

    Carbondale, IL 62901 618-453-1429

    [email protected]

    Hongxia Wang Institute for Contemporary Financial Studies

    College of Business and Economics Ashland University Ashland, OH 44805

    419-289-5222 [email protected]

    Dan L. Worrell

    Dean and Sam Walton Leadership Chair Sam Walton College of Business

    University of Arkansas Fayetteville, AR 72701-1201

    479-575-5949 [email protected]

    August 12, 2010 * Corresponding Author

    The authors would like to thank seminar participants at the University of Mississippi for many helpful and insightful comments. All errors remain the responsibility of the authors.

  • Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1497205Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1497205

    1

    Deviations from Expected Stakeholder Management, Firm

    Value, and Corporate Governance

    Abstract

    In this paper, we examine the relation between deviations from expected investment in stakeholder management and corporate governance. Building good relations with various stakeholders may help create firm value, but investment in stakeholder management beyond what is necessary to create shareholder value may be an agency cost. We propose that high quality corporate governance may mitigate value-destroying investments in stakeholder management. Using an unbalanced panel of 9,051firm-year observations for 1,631 firms, we find that deviations from expected SM are increasing in CEO portfolio delta. We find, however, that deviations from expected stakeholder management are negatively related to proxies for effective board monitoring. More independent boards effectively control deviations from expected investment in stakeholder management. These results are consistent with both the CEO perquisite and the board monitoring hypotheses. We also document that the effect of governance mechanisms varies by industry (consumer or industrial orientation) and SM dimension; their influence is similar in dimensions expected to provide similar benefits across industry orientation, but differs when the benefits are expected to benefit one industry more than the other. Consistent with Jensens Enlightened Value Maximization theory, the results show that corporations with good governance pursue shareholder value maximization while constraining unnecessary investment in stakeholders. JEL classification: G34; J33; L21; M14; M52 Keywords: Corporate Governance; Corporate Social Responsibility; Enlightened Value Maximization; Institutional Ownership; Firm Value; Managerial Ownership Incentives; Stakeholder Theory

  • 2

    Deviations from Expected Stakeholder Management, Firm Value, and Corporate Governance

    1. Introduction

    Proponents of stakeholder management argue that a firm should manage the relations with

    all of its stakeholders rather than focus on shareholder wealth. Researchers in a wide range of

    fields have examined the implications of stakeholder management (e.g. strategic management,

    organizational behavior, business ethics, and sustainable development) (Laplume, Sonpar, and

    Litz, 2008). The corporate scandals of the early 2000s have brought corporate social performance

    and stakeholder management to the forefront (Neubaum and Zahra, 2006)1. Furthermore,

    constituency statutes have been enacted in over half of US states in recent years that either require

    or permit directors to consider the interests of non-shareholders when conducting their duties

    (Keay, 2009).2

    The principal argument of stakeholder management (SM) is that organizations should be

    operated and managed in the interests of all their constituents who can affect or be affected by the

    achievement of the organizations objectives (Freeman, 1984; Donaldson and Preston, 1995).

    Stakeholder management captures various firm-stakeholder relationships. Proponents maintain

    that stakeholder management is strategically important, and firms can benefit from properly

    managing the relationship with these important groups (Fong, 2009; Bhattacharya, Korschun, and

    1 Stakeholder management and social performance are similar in their construct such that firms which manage stakeholder relations may be seen as socially responsible. 2 The legal duty of directors to consider the interest of additional stakeholders has also taken hold in the UK. For example, section 172 of the Companies Act 2006 states that directors have a duty to promote the success of the company by considering such factors as: (a) the likely consequences of any long term decision, (b) the interests of the companys employees, (c) the need to foster the business relationships of the company with suppliers, customers and other organizations, (d) the impact of the companys operations on the community and the environment, (e) the desirability of the company maintaining a reputation for high standards of business conduct, and (f) the need to act fairly between members of the company.

  • 3

    Sen, 2009). Empirical studies, however, have documented that only some stakeholders are critical

    to firm value creation (such as Galbreath, 2006; Hillman and Keim, 2001).

    One of the downsides to investing in stakeholder management is that it consumes a firms

    limited resources. Directing excess resources from shareholders to other stakeholders may hurt

    firm value. Some shareholders view stakeholder management as being at odds with profit making

    and value maximization. For example, two shareholders at Goldman Sachs protested the

    companys donation of land for a nature preserve. The shareholders based their protest on the

    idea that while the donation would have benefitted one of the firms stakeholders (the world

    environment), it would be costly to shareholders because the land could have been put to

    profitable use (Kelly and Davis, 2007).

    Stakeholder theory seems to be at odds with value maximization. Jensen (2001; 2002)

    addresses this problem and proposes enlightened value maximization. He argues that a firms goal

    is to increase firm value, but a firm cannot maximize its value unless it takes care of its

    stakeholders. Jensens theory implies that there is an optimal level of stakeholder management

    that maximizes shareholder wealth. Similarly, Brickley, Smith, and Zimmerman (2002) argue

    that creating shareholder wealth involves allocating resources to all constituencies that affect the

    process of shareholder value creation, but only to the point at which the benefits from such

    expenditures do not exceed their additional costs (p.113). That is, when the marginal cost of

    stakeholder management exceeds the marginal benefit to shareholders, it would not be optimal to

    pursue stakeholder management any further. Excess stakeholder management would be

    investments in stakeholders beyond this optimal level. Benson and Davidson (2009) find that

    while stakeholder management is positively related to firm value, firms do not compensate

    managers for stakeholder management; instead, firms compensate their CEOs for achieving the

  • 4

    firms ultimate goalvalue maximization. Their results indicate that effective managers optimize

    relations with stakeholders to accomplish value maximization.

    When firms allocate excess resources to stakeholders, this can be considered an agency

    cost and shareholder wealth would suffer. As with other agency conflicts, there are various

    governance mechanisms that should protect shareholders, and therefore, the quality of corporate

    governance may affect a firms stakeholder management policy.

    In this paper, we examine how various corporate governance mechanisms affect the

    amount of resources diverted toward stakeholders. We propose that firms will invest in

    stakeholder management (SM) until the marginal cost of doing so exceeds the marginal benefit to

    shareholders. This level of investment in stakeholder management is each firms expected

    investment in stakeholder management (ESM). Good corporate governance, proxied by

    managerial ownership incentives, board monitoring, and monitoring from institutional investors,

    should control deviations from this expected level of stakeholder management.

    Using an unbalanced panel of 9,051 firm-year observations for 1,631 firms, we find that

    deviations from expected SM are increasing in CEO portfolio delta (scaled wealth-performance

    sensitivity), but they are negatively related to proxies for effective board monitoring. More

    independent boards effectively control deviations from expected investment in stakeholder

    management. These results are consistent with both the CEO perquisite and the board monitoring

    hypotheses. We also document that the effect of governance mechanisms varies by industry

    (consumer or industrial orientation) and SM dimension; their influence is similar in dimensions

    expected to provide similar benefits across industries, but differs when the benefits are expected

    to benefit one industry more than the other.

  • 5

    This study is unique. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to introduce the

    concept of deviation from expected investment in stakeholder management and empirically test

    how various governance mechanisms are related to unexpected investment in stakeholder

    management. We organize the remainder of this paper as follows. In Sections 2 and 3, we

    motivate our research, review the literature, and develop our hypotheses. We discuss our data and

    sample in Section 4. In Section 5, we test our hypotheses on the effect of internal governance

    mechanisms on excess stakeholder management. We provide concluding remarks in Section 6.

    2. Background and motivation

    2.1. Stakeholder theory

    Under stakeholder theory, the firm is a collection of groups and individuals with a stake in

    the firm. The purpose of the firm is to manage the interests of these various stakeholders.

    Stakeholder theory has diverged into at least two approaches. The first is the strategic approach

    in which firms manage stakeholder relations in the pursuit of value maximization. Here, value

    maximization is the fundamental purpose of the firm with stakeholder management as a means to

    an end (Freeman et al., 2004). The second approach is the moral approach where firms manage

    stakeholder relations for ethical or moral reasons (Freeman, 1984; Evan and Freeman, 1988).3

    One issue in stakeholder theory is the identification of stakeholders. Freeman (1984, p. 46)

    is credited with the classic definition in which a stakeholder is "any group or individual who can

    affect or is affected by the achievement of the organization's objectives". In a literature review,

    Friedman and Miles (2006) find 55 definitions of what constitutes a stakeholder. Stakeholder

    3 Donaldson and Preston (1995) define these approaches as instrumental and normative stakeholder theories. Instrumental stakeholder theory is concerned with how managers act if they are to further goals of the organization, such as long-run profit maximization or shareholder value. On the other hand, normative stakeholder theory is used to explain how managers should behave and arrive at the purpose of the organization based on ethical principles. Freeman (1994; 1999) maintains that business and ethical decisions cannot be separated.

  • 6

    definitions range from those who have a vested interest in the firm (Carroll, 1993) to any entity

    that affects or is affected by the firm (Starik, 1993).

    Another issue in stakeholder theory/management is the allocation of resources between

    stakeholders. Clarkson (1995) argues that all stakeholders have intrinsic value and no stakeholder

    is more important than another. However, if managers treat all stakeholders with the same

    priority, it would be difficult to manage a firm because various stakeholders have different

    interests. For example, suppliers would want to receive high prices, and customers would want

    low prices; accomplishing these goals would be unlikely to produce value for another stakeholder

    group, shareholders (Sundaram and Inkpen, 2004).

    2.2. Value Maximization

    Milton Friedman stated that the social responsibility of business is to increase its profits

    (Friedman, 1970)4. Brickley et al. (2002) argue that a company must focus its attention on

    shareholder wealth to survive in a competitive and technology-oriented business world.

    Shareholder wealth maximization has been taught in colleges as a basic concept in finance

    courses for decades and is a dominating view of many if not most financial scholars. One of the

    major differences between shareholder wealth maximization and stakeholder theories is the role

    of managers in the resolution of a firms internal conflicts (Laurent, 2007). Shareholder value

    theory emphasizes that the role of managers is to make decisions that enhance shareholder value;

    this differs from normative stakeholder theory which maintains that managers should focus on the

    welfare of all stakeholders (Laurent, 2007). Proponents of value maximization believe that other

    constituencies can become better off if companies pursue shareholders interests. Jensen (2001;

    4 Hillman and Keim (2001) argue that social responsibility and stakeholder management are closely related and that social responsibility is a measure of how well a firm manages the relations with its stakeholders. Graves and Waddock (2000) state that social performance can be defined as stakeholder relations. The groups identified in social responsibility discussions are often the same groups identified as stakeholders. As such, corporate social responsibility and stakeholder theory may be directly linked and are at a minimum based on a similar foundation.

  • 7

    2002) argues that a business cannot maximize wealth simply by stating this as its goal; it requires

    working with stakeholders to achieve this objective. So, simply focusing on shareholder value

    maximization may be like putting blinders on a horse, and it may not be applicable in todays

    business world.5

    3. Enlightened value maximization and development of hypotheses

    Jensen (2001; 2002) argues that while the goal of the corporation is to maximize

    shareholder wealth, this goal cannot be met by treating stakeholders poorly. Companies should

    not try to maximize the welfare of all stakeholders, but work with stakeholders to produce

    shareholder wealth. More specifically, companies should improve stakeholder welfare until the

    marginal cost of doing so exceeds the marginal benefit to shareholders. Thus, Jensens approach

    is somewhat consistent with the management of stakeholders as a means to an end where the end

    is shareholder value maximization6.

    There are at least two questions raised by this logic. The first question is: how would

    actions aimed at improving the welfare of stakeholders contribute to shareholder wealth; and the

    second is: does stakeholder management actually improve company financial performance and

    increase shareholder wealth.

    To address the first question, we must realize that the effect of stakeholder management

    on shareholder wealth could be bi-directional. There may be rewards for positive actions, as well

    as penalties for irresponsible ones. Companies that build better relations with primary

    5 In the recent business downturn and stock market drop, the press has increasingly focused on business social responsibility and the relations between business and stakeholders. Value maximization, as the sole firm goal, is viewed very negatively in the popular press and even in the financial press. 6 Instrumental stakeholder theory posits that stakeholder management will lead to better financial performance. Jensens (2001; 2002) enlightened value maximization does differ from instrumental stakeholder theory. Jensen argues that stakeholder theory fails to provide a mechanism for making the tradeoffs between competing stakeholder claims. Enlightened value maximization implies that managers will make tradeoffs between stakeholders using the effect on firm value as the decision criteria.

  • 8

    stakeholders such as employees, customers, suppliers, and communities may be able to increase

    their financial gains (Freeman, 1984). Prior research has documented these rewards (Turban and

    Greening, 1996; Greening and Turban, 2000; De Luque, Washburn, Waldman, and House, 2008).

    Godfrey (2005) argues that corporate social responsibility and philanthropic activities can

    generate positive moral capital among stakeholders which may provide an insurance-like effect

    for firm reputation if social problems occur. Companies that mistreat stakeholders may face

    penalties. Researchers have documented these penalties (Davidson and Worrell, 1988; Karpoff

    and Lott, 1993; Cohen, Fenn, and Naiman, 1995; Davidson, Worrell, and El-Jelly, 1995; Hart and

    Ahuja, 1996; Karpoff, Lott, and Rankine, 1998; Karpoff, Lee and Vendrzyk, 1999; Klassen and

    Whybark, 1999; Konar and Cohen, 2001; Davidson, Worrell, and El Jelly, 2000).

    While stakeholder theory posits that stakeholder management may generate increases in

    income or shareholder wealth, companies that spend resources directed at stakeholder welfare, in

    excess of the marginal benefits, may find that income and/or shareholder wealth decreases

    (Hillman and Keim, 2001). Therefore, whether companies actually increase or decrease

    shareholder wealth by managing stakeholder relations is an empirical question.7

    Jensens theory of enlightened value maximization suggests that value maximization

    cannot be achieved if companies ignore or mistreat their stakeholders. Others have made similar

    propositions (Graves and Waddock, 2000; Davis, 2005). Jensens model differs from traditional

    instrumental stakeholder theory because his model provides a basis for making tradeoffs between

    stakeholder groups. The companys relations with its stakeholders must be rooted in the

    7 Numerous researchers have addressed this question with equivocal findings. Many have found a positive relation between stakeholder management and financial performance (Berrone, Surroca, and Trib, 2007; Barbara, Myron, and Bruce, 2006; Hillman and Keim, 2001; Moore, 2001; Ogden and Watson, 1999; Ruf, Muralidhar, Brown, Janney, and Paul, 2001; Waddock and Graves, 1997; Moneva, Rivera-Lirio, and Munoz-Torres, 2007) while others have found a negative or a mixed relation (Meznar, Nigh and Kwok, 1994; Berman et al., 1999; Omran, Atrill, and Pointon, 2002; Brammer, Brooks, and Pavelin , 2006; and Bird, D. Hall, Moment, and Reggiani, 2007).

  • 9

    companys strategies and must be a means to an endvalue maximization. Accordingly,

    managers optimize relations with stakeholders to maximize firm value. Managing stakeholder

    welfare may be a partial determinant of firm value. However, deviations from expected

    investment in stakeholder management may be detrimental to a firms value.

    3.1. Deviations from expected stakeholder management as an agency cost

    Once an owner-manager owns less than 100 percent of the corporation, the costs of

    providing the manager with pecuniary and non-pecuniary benefits are borne, in part, by

    shareholders (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). These costs are called agency costs. If management

    spends resources on managing stakeholder relations and the expenditures do not lead to increased

    firm value, then these expenditures would be an agency cost. What incentive would management

    have to spend excess resources on stakeholders?

    Cespa and Cestone (2007) argue that stakeholder management can become a powerful

    entrenchment strategy for incumbent CEOs because inefficient managers may commit themselves

    to socially responsible behavior to gain stakeholders support against shareholders. Firms have

    limited resources, and there are conflicts between shareholders and other constituents over these

    resources. Managers must solve these conflicts. Diverting resources from shareholders may either

    hurt shareholders or benefit shareholders in the long run. Proponents of the strict shareholder

    value maximization philosophy argue that philanthropic activities and maintaining stakeholder

    welfare would waste company resources that would be better spent to produce value for

    shareholders. However, diverting some resources in the management of stakeholder welfare may

    produce long-run value maximization (Jensen, 2001, 2002; Brickley et al., 2002). The question

    may not be whether a firm should invest in stakeholder management, but how much should be

    invested in the pursuit of shareholder wealth maximization. Finding the optimal level of

  • 10

    investment likely challenges all firms, but may be easier when there is high quality corporate

    governance.

    3.2. Internal governance mechanisms and agency costs

    3.2.1. Managerial ownership incentives and agency costs

    From a theoretical standpoint, higher pay-performance sensitivity should result in a

    convexity payoff that encourages managers to work hard and take on value enhancing risky

    projects (Jensen and Meckling, 1996; Myers 1977; Haugen and Senbet, 1981). Accordingly,

    increasing the sensitivity of CEO wealth to stock price should better align managerial behavior

    with shareholder interests. An unintended effect of high managerial ownership is that it may

    expose managers to more risk relative to diversified shareholders. Here, the concavity of the

    managers utility function may overcome the convexity of the payoff making managers more risk

    adverse (Guay, 1999; Ross, 2004). High managerial ownership may also increase the risk of

    managerial perquisite consumption (Baker and Hall, 2004; Edmans, Gabaix, and Landier, 2009).

    Despite significant research on this issue, there is substantial debate over the theoretical and

    empirical effect of higher pay-performance sensitivity on financial performance and its effect in

    deterring various agency-related issues.8,9

    8 For example, studies find a positive relation between managerial ownership and firm performance (Mehran, 1995; Core and Larker, 2002), or a positive but decreasing relation between managerial ownership and firm performance (Morck, Schleifer, and Vishney, 1988; McConnell and Servaes 1990, 1995; Hermalin and Weisbach, 1991; Hubbard and Palia, 1995; Holderness, Krosner, and Sheehan, 1999; Anderson and Reeb, 2003; Tian, 2004; Davies, Hillier, and McColgan, 2005; Adams and Santos, 2006; Pukthuanthong, and Roll, Walker, 2007; McConnell, Servaes, and Lins, 2008; Tong, 2008; Benson and Davidson, 2009). Others find no relation between managerial ownership and firm performance (Demsetz, 1983; Demsetz and Lehn, 1985; Agrawal and Knoeber, 1996; Lorderer and Martin, 1997; Cho, 1998; Demsetz and Villalonga, 2001; Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Palia, 1999; Palia, 2001; Coles, Lemmon, and Meschke, 2003; Brick, Palia, and Wang, 2005; and Cheung and Wei, 2006). 9 The remainder of this section focuses on the effects of increased sensitivity of wealth to stock price, delta. However, it is important to note that increasing the sensitivity of CEO wealth to stock return volatility, vega, is seen as one potential mechanism to offset managerial risk aversion. Coles, Daniel, and Naveen (2006) provide evidence that managers with greater convexity in their contracts engage in riskier investment. However, theoretical and empirical studies suggest that increasing convexity does not necessarily increase managerial risk taking (Lambert, Larker, and

  • 11

    At the heart of the debate is the empirical puzzle of a negative and significant relation

    between the CEOs effective ownership percentage (dollar-dollar incentives), b, and firm size

    (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985; Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Gibbons and Murphy, 1992; Garen, 1994;

    Hadlock and Lumer 1997; Hall and Liebman, 1998; Schaefer 1998; Murphy, 1999; Jin, 2002;

    Baker and Hall, 2004; Cichello, 2005; Benson and Davidson, 2009; and Edmans et al. 2009).

    Nonetheless, the concept that CEOs of large companies have trivial incentives relative to those of

    small companies seems inconsistent with the observation of the very large wealth swings induced

    by substantial stock and option holdings of large-company CEOs (Hall and Liebman, 1998; Baker

    and Hall, 2004; Core and Guay, 2010). Baker and Hall (2004), however, note that a key

    assumption made by researchers examining this puzzle is the marginal product of CEO action on

    firm value, . Viewed from two polar extremes, if total incentives (i.e. the marginal return to effort) are equal to b*, this suggests that either = 0 and is independent of firm size or = 1 and scales proportionally with firm size. The former assumption is best modeled using dollar-dollar

    incentives, b. Dollar-dollar incentives, consequently, are most effective at deterring agency costs

    that have a dollar effect on firm value (i.e. perquisite consumption). The later assumption,

    however, is best modeled using dollar-percent incentives. This implies that dollar-percent

    incentives are most effective at deterring agency costs that scale with firm size (i.e. corporate

    strategy) and their model predicts that for tasks whose marginal products scale with firm size,

    optimally low b in large firms should not incur significant agency costs. However, given the

    infeasibility of high b in large firms, optimally low b will also induce significant agency costs for

    those tasks whose marginal products do not scale with firm size. Therefore, some agency costs are

    Verrecchia, 1991; Guay, 1999; Carpenter, 2000; Ju, Leland, and Senbet, 2002; Ross, 2004; Tian, 2005; Parrino, Poteshman, and Weisbach, 2005; Lewellen, 2006; and Hayes, Lemmon, and Qiu, 2010). Furthermore, it is not entirely clear how increasing managerial sensitivity to risk would influence deviations from expected SM.

  • 12

    best deterred by active board monitoring and bureaucratic control systems rather than managerial

    incentives.

    Edmans et al. (2009) propose a multiplicative specification for the CEOs utility and

    production function. Their model predicts that the dollar increase in firm value has size elasticity

    of 1, or is proportional to firm size. They measure CEO incentives using percent-percent

    incentives, the dollar change in wealth for a one-percent change in firm value, divided by total

    annual pay (i.e. scaled wealth-performance sensitivity).10 Dollar-dollar incentives equal percent-

    percent incentives multiplied by CEO wage and divided by firm value. Even a small b can induce

    high levels of CEO effort since firm value is substantially greater than the CEOs wage, making

    the dollar gains from effort larger than the dollar costs. A key implication of the Edmans et al.

    (2009) model, however, is that equity based incentives are only effective at addressing agency

    costs that have a multiplicative effect on firm value, or actions that are proportional to firm value,

    such as corporate strategy. In contrast, CEO incentives cannot solve additive value-destructive

    actions, such as perquisite consumption, as these actions have a minimal effect on stock price and

    consequently, CEO wealth. Perks, instead, are best controlled by corporate governance. As the

    authors suggest, active monitoring [via corporate governance] and incentives should be used in

    tandem; the former to deter additive value-destructive actions, and the latter to encourage

    multiplicative value-enhancing efforts (p. 4902).

    Our testable hypotheses, therefore, assume that firms will choose CEO equity-based

    ownership incentives, delta, to implement value-maximizing decisions. If CEO incentives are in

    alignment with shareholder interests, deviations from expected investment in stakeholder

    10 Edmans et al. (2009) also demonstrate that this measure has several empirical advantages over previous measures, including size and firm risk insensitivity.

  • 13

    management should be negatively related to CEO portfolio delta. As a result, the managerial

    ownership incentive hypothesis states:

    H1: Deviation from expected stakeholder management is negatively related to CEO

    portfolio delta. The empirical implication is that higher delta deters agency costs related to activities that

    scale firm size, such as corporate strategy. If investment in stakeholder management is necessary

    for maximizing firm value from a strategic standpoint, then we would then expect that deviations

    from expected stakeholder management are negatively related to CEO portfolio delta.

    However, it is also possible that managers may undertake some investment in stakeholder

    management for personal interests. For example, non-strategic investments in stakeholder

    management may benefit the CEO by increasing job security (Cespa and Cestone, 2007) or

    support moral or personal beliefs incongruent with those of the firm. As a result, deviations from

    expected investment in stakeholder management may also represent perquisite consumption by

    the CEO. As a result, the managerial perquisite hypothesis states:

    H2: Deviation from expected stakeholder management is positively related to CEO portfolio delta.

    The empirical implication of this hypothesis is that while a higher delta may induce

    greater alignment between CEO incentives and investment in stakeholder management related to

    corporate strategy, CEOs may invest in superfluous stakeholder management for personal reasons

    as a form of perquisite consumption. These investment are likely to be more additive in nature,

    and will have a minimal effect on stock price. While they will be costly in dollar terms to the

    firm, they will not appreciably affect CEO wealth. We therefore expect that deviations from

    expected stakeholder management may also be increasing in CEO portfolio delta.

  • 14

    3.2.2. Board monitoring and agency costs

    Executive perquisites have attracted a lot of attention and criticism from the public and

    regulators, especially in the current financial crisis11,12. There are two competing views on

    executive perquisites: the outcome of an optimal employment contract, designed to motivate

    executives to work harder and enhance productivity (Fama, 1980), and an agency problem leading

    to reduced firm value either directly or indirectly (Jensen and Meckling 1976). Empirical studies

    have documented mixed evidence. For example, Yermack (2006) find that firms which disclose

    the private use of corporate jets witness negative market reactions, and they tend to underperform

    their peers with no private jet use disclosures. Similarly, Chen, Chen, and Hui (2009) find that

    family ownership reduces managerial perquisite consumption and stock prices drop around the

    disclosure of a descendent CEOs perk consumption and Andrews, Linn, and Yi (2009) find that

    firms that hid large amounts of CEO perquisites experienced a negative market reaction after their

    proxy statements were released. On the other hand, Rajan and Wulf (2006) provide evidence that

    executive perks can increase managerial productivity.

    Both theories, however, are consistent on one point; weak corporate governance and

    executive personal tastes affect perquisite awards and consumption. Yermack (2006) documents

    that variables related to CEO characteristics have significant explanatory power for executives

    personal use of corporate jets. Andrews, Linn, and Yi (2009) find that firms with weak corporate

    governance are more likely to award perquisites to executives. These results imply that

    11 For example, there are a lot of negative reports criticizing the CEOs of the big three auto makers who flew to Washington in their luxury corporate jets to request 25-billion-dollar taxpayer bailout money on November 19, 2008, and the 1.22 million dollar office refurbishing expenses of the Merrill Lynch CEO in early 2008 while the securities firm was cutting thousands of jobs, and etc. 12 To improve the transparency of disclosure of executive perquisite consumption to investors, the SEC tightened up its disclosure requirements. The new rule not only lowers the minimum threshold amount for reporting from $50,000 to $10,000, but also provides interpretive guidelines on the classification of perquisite. There is loophole in this rule because it does not specify clearly between an expense and a perquisite. We cannot completely rule out the possibility that executives report some perks, for instance, investment in stakeholder management because of their own personal interests, as normal business expenses.

  • 15

    executives personal tastes may play a significant role in stakeholder management; executives

    may tend to invest in stakeholder management unrelated to firm value; and ineffective governance

    may not be able to deter but encourage this kind of stakeholder management behavior. As

    indicated earlier, this kind of behavior may become more additive. The rationale is simple. If

    CEOs can spend corporate resources for their personal use (e.g. luxury office, traveling), we can

    reasonably argue that they may invest in stakeholder management based on their personal

    interests. This investment would simply be another form of perquisite. This type of investment

    may be more harmful to a firm because of the hidden nature of this type of perquisites.

    A boards attitude towards various stakeholders is likely to become an important

    determinant of its stakeholder policy. In addition, many state statutes have challenged the

    traditional view of the shareholder-only fiduciary duty of the board and specified that boards have

    the right to take the interests of all stakeholders into account (McDonnell, 2004). Under this

    pressure, boards may be more likely to apply enlightened stakeholder management in dealing

    with stakeholders while maximizing shareholder wealth. So, effective monitoring by boards may

    mitigate agency problems related to the amount of resources diverted to other stakeholders.

    Board composition may affect the boards management policy. Regulators and academics

    believe that outside directors are generally more effective monitors than inside directors. The

    Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the exchange rules in 2002 require that the majority of the board be

    independent. Numerous studies link the proportion of outside directors to financial performance

    and shareholder wealth (e.g. Rosenstein and Wyatt, 1990; Byrd and Hickman, 1992; Brickley,

    Coles, and Terry, 1994; Cotter, Shivdasani, and Zenner, 1997). Outside dominated boards may

    be less likely to provide other stakeholders with excess resources, and they would be more likely

  • 16

    to optimize the level of stakeholder management. In other words, outside dominated boards

    should be in a better position to control unwarranted investment in stakeholder management.13

    Board size is another major characteristic of corporate boards (Lipton and Lorsch, 1992;

    Jensen, 1993; Yermack, 1996). Even though there is debate regarding the effect of board size on

    its decisions, the commonly accepted idea is that small boards are better than large ones because

    large boards place a greater emphasis on politeness and courtesy, making it easier for CEOs to

    control. Empirical studies support this idea (e.g. Yermack, 1996; Eisenberg, Sundgren, and Wells,

    1998). If small boards are more effective in monitoring management, small boards may be more

    likely to control superfluous resources diverted to stakeholder management.

    Thus, more effective monitoring by the board is expected to reduce agency costs between

    managers and shareholders by preventing managers from making unnecessary investment in

    stakeholder management as a potential means of perquisite consumption. Therefore, the board

    monitoring hypothesis is as follows:

    H3: Deviation from expected stakeholder management is negatively related to proxies for effective board monitoring (i.e. smaller board size and more independent directors).

    The empirical implication of this hypothesis is that higher delta may increase agency costs

    between managers and shareholders related to investment in stakeholder management as a form of

    perquisite consumption. This type of additive value-destructive investment is best deterred by

    active monitoring by the board of directors. We therefore expect that deviations from expected

    stakeholder management may be decreasing in proxies for effective board monitoring.

    13 Other research has related board composition to stakeholder management. Johnson and Greening (1999) find that outside director dominated boards tend to pursue greater stakeholder management. Similarly, Kassinis and Vafeas (2002) find that the likelihood of becoming an environmental lawsuit defendant decreases with the number of outside directors.

  • 17

    3.2.3. The Equivocal Effect of Duality

    When the CEO also holds the title of board chair, CEO duality, power may concentrate in

    the CEOs position. Duality may allow the CEO to control information available to other directors

    impeding effective monitoring (Jensen, 1993). However, empirical work has not supported the

    concept that duality can lead to agency costs. For example, Brickley, Coles, and Jarrell (1997)

    show that CEOs are awarded the chair position as a normal part of the succession process;

    successful CEOs later become CEO/Chair. While duality may have an impact on deviations from

    expected stakeholder management, we do not have strong priors with respect to empirical

    outcomes. It is possible that duality proxies for the CEOs power over the board of directors, thus

    impeding effective monitoring by the board. It is also possible that duality is endogenously

    determined, such that CEOs that are less likely to engage in unnecessary investment in

    stakeholder management are awarded the chair position. We therefore treat the expected impact of

    duality as an open empirical issue.

    3.2.4. Institutional and blockholder ownership and agency costs

    Given their large financial stake, institutional investors and blockholders have incentives,

    resources, and the ability to mitigate agency problems (Edwards and Hubbard, 2000) and monitor

    a firms stakeholder policy. Empirical research supports this idea (Brickley, Lease, and Smith,

    1988; Hartzell and Starks, 2003; Holderness, 2003; Jiambalvo, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam,

    2002; McConnell and Servaes, 1990). Empirical studies have also explored the role of

    blockholders in the conflict between stakeholder management and financial performance. For

    example, institutional ownership plays an important role in monitoring and influencing CEOs

    attention to corporate social performance (Graves and Waddock, 1994; Wright et al., 2002;

  • 18

    Wright, Ferris, Sarin, and Awasthi, 1996; Johnson and Greening, 1999; Neubaum and Zahra,

    2006).

    Our focus, however, is on the role of institutional investors in preventing needless

    investment in stakeholder management. A higher concentration of institutional investor ownership

    should also lead to lower levels of unnecessary investment in stakeholder management.

    Consequently, the institutional ownership hypothesis is as follows:

    H4: Deviation from expected stakeholder management is negatively related to the percentage of shares held by institutional investors.

    3.2.5. Operationalizing expected stakeholder management

    Our theoretical arguments allude to a value maximizing, or optimal, level of stakeholder

    management. Our measurement of optimal stakeholder management is limited, however, by a

    lack of empirical literature on this concept. Consequently, as a starting point we assume that

    management has an incentive to invest in stakeholder management to increase firm value either

    voluntarily or due to pressure from regulators, investors, the board of directors, the media, or the

    product market. And like other financial decisions, management has a target level of investment

    in stakeholder management which is believed to maximize shareholder wealth. Given the

    difficulty in accurately assessing the optimal level of stakeholder management, empirical

    evidence and corporate practice suggest that industry average provides a useful starting point for

    arriving at this value. Masulis (1983), for example, finds that when firms issuing debt move

    toward the industry average from below, the market reacts more positively than when the firm

    moves away from the industry average, indicating that industry average provides a proper

    benchmark for optimal capital structure. Similarly, Frank and Goyal (2009) find that the median

    industry leverage is one of most reliable factors in the capital structure decisions of publicly

  • 19

    traded American firms. Extending this logic from the capital structure literature, an optimal level

    of stakeholder management exists, but not every firm achieves this value-maximizing level.

    Industry average provides an approximate estimate for the optimal level of stakeholder

    management 14

    However, given the difficulty in measuring actual investment in stakeholder management

    and the unique characteristics of each firm, a simple industry average is likely to be a noisy proxy.

    Specifically, in addition to industry, the optimal level of stakeholder management may be

    explained by firm value and other observable firm specific characteristics, such as firm size,

    financial constraints, and growth opportunities. Such an interpretation is also more consistent with

    Jensens (2001, 2002) argument that value is the criterion to stakeholder management. A more

    detailed discussion of the operationalization of our measures used for deviation from expected

    stakeholder management is provided in section 4.2.1.

    Finally, given our operationalization of optimal stakeholder management, our conclusions

    depend on a key assumption. Namely, that the sample mean, conditional upon industry and other

    observable firm specific factors, is a reasonable proxy for optimal stakeholder management. To

    the extent that this assumption is violated, our measures of deviation from expected stakeholder

    management may be biased.

    4. Sample selection and data

    4.1. Sample selection

    We obtain our initial sample from the KLD Statistical Tool for the Analysis of Trends in

    Social and Environmental Performance (KLD) database, an annual statistical database of over 90

    14 The use of industry average as a proxy for the optimal level is also validated by common practice in financial statement analysis, in which greater deviations from the industry average are a potential indicator of financial problems within the firm.

  • 20

    social and environmental indicators provided by KLD Research and Analytics, Inc. The database

    reports social, environmental, and governance performance indicators for S&P 500, Domini 400

    Social, and Russell 1000 (starting in 2001) and Russell 3000 (starting in 2003) companies

    between the years of 1991 to 2008. We use the KLD database because it is a measure of social

    performance (relations with stakeholders) that has been developed independently of this studys

    researchers, and therefore, does not suffer from potential researcher bias that might occur if we

    use our own definition of stakeholder management and corporate social performance.

    Furthermore, the KLD database is a well-established measure of both stakeholder

    management and corporate social performance. Researchers have certified its quality and it has

    been widely used in empirical studies.15 16

    Our initial KLD sample has 26,575 firm years from 1991 to 2008. We match the KLD

    data with COMPUSTAT accounting data, resulting in a sample composed of an unbalanced panel

    of 24,813 firm year observations for 4,552 firms.17 We match this set of firms to Standard and

    Poors EXECUCOMP database, which includes annual compensation data from proxy statements

    for the five highest paid executives for firms in the S&P 500, the S&P MidCap 400, and the S&P

    SmallCap 600. We lose one year of data because the EXECUCOMP data begins in 1992. This

    results in an unbalanced panel of 15,761 firm year observations for 2,297 firms from 1992 to

    2008. To account for the influence of internal governance mechanisms, we obtain board of

    15 For example, Chatterji, Levine, and Toffel (2009) conclude that while the KLD database does not reflect all available information on stakeholder management and corporate social performance, it is a good predictor of more narrow measures such as compliance with environmental regulations. 16 See Agle, Mitchell, and Sonnenfeld (1999), Berman, Wicks, Kotha, and Jones (1999), Graves and Waddock (1994), Hillman and Keim (2001), Johnson and Greening (1999), Turban and Greening (1996), Waddock and Graves (1997), and Coombs and Gilley (2005). 17 A primary problem with the KLD data is that the data lacks a numeric unique identifier (i.e. CUSIP) for years prior to 1995 in which to merge with COMPUSTAT. We try several methods to obtain a COMPUSTAT unique identifier (GVKEY) for the initial sample. First, we backfill early years of data (prior to 1995) with CUSIPs from the same firm if it appears in the database in a later year. Next, we attempt to merge companies with COMPUSTAT using CUSIP, ticker, and the first 15 letters in the company name. Lastly, we hand verify our merge results from the steps above and hand match firms with COMPUSTAT for any remaining firms not captured in previous steps.

  • 21

    director characteristics from the RiskMetrics IRRC (IRRC) database and institutional ownership

    data from the Thomson 13F (13F) database. Due to data limitations in IRRC, board characteristics

    are only available from fiscal year 1995 onward.18 We obtain stock return volatility, volume, and

    shares outstanding data from the Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) database. We

    omit regulated utilities (SIC codes 4910-4949), depository institutions (SIC codes 6000-6099) and

    holding or investment companies (SIC codes 6700-6799) from our sample. The final matched

    sample, after combining KLD, COMPUSTAT, EXECUCOMP, IRRC, 13F, and CRSP data,

    contains an unbalanced panel of 9,051 firm year observations for 1,631 firms from 1995 to 2008.

    4.2. Variable descriptions

    We rely on the KLD database for stakeholder management and social issue performance

    data, COMPUSTAT for accounting data, EXECUCOMP for managerial ownership,

    compensation data, and CEO data, IRRC for board and CEO data, 13F for institutional ownership

    data, and CRSP for volume traded and shares outstanding data. We winsorize all variables at the

    upper and lower 1% to reduce any possible impact from outliers.

    4.2.1. Deviation from expected stakeholder management

    Enlightened value maximization posits that firms will invest in stakeholder management

    (SM) until the marginal cost of doing so exceeds the marginal benefit to shareholders, and we call

    this the expected investment in stakeholder management (ESM). While we can observe the effect

    of a firms actual investment in stakeholder management, SM, ESM is unobservable. Therefore,

    we use two proxies for ESM to measure the deviation of each firm from expected SM.

    18 The Risk Metrics IRRC proxy database reports the year using the meeting date. We assume that the proxy date is approximately 3 months after fiscal year end and the meeting date follows by 1 month. So, firms with fiscal years ending in December 1995 will be matched with IRRC observations with meeting dates in April 1996 or earlier.

  • 22

    To begin with, we create a measure of the deviation of each firm from expected

    stakeholder management (DESM), which is the residual from a cross-sectional regression of SM

    on size, financing constraints, performance, and growth opportunities estimated at time t for all

    firms in the same 4-digit Global Industry Classification System (GICS) industry19:

    1

    where SM is the firms stakeholder management score, size is LNSALES, financing constraints

    are measured by CASH/TA and TD/TA, performance is measured by ROA and TRS, growth

    opportunities is measured by Q and DESM = . The definitions of variables in regression equation (1) are described below. The residuals are a proxy of deviations from expected

    investment in SM given industry, year, and observable firm specific factors. To construct

    measures for SM, we follow the procedure used in prior research in the area (Waddock and

    Graves, 1997; Hillman and Keim, 2001; Coombs and Gilley, 2005), and construct a measure of

    the firms stakeholder management (SM) performance using the KLD categories of employee

    relations (EMP), diversity issues (DIV), product issues (PRO), community relations (COM), and

    environmental issues (ENV). These five categories parallel the primary stakeholder groups with

    regard to employees (including diversity initiatives), customers (product safety/quality), the

    19 Following Benson and Davidson (2009), we use 4-digit GICS industry group rather than the more common 2-digit SIC code or Fama-French (FF) industry classification for several reasons. First, GICS categorization is based on both a firms operational characteristics and information on investors perceptions as to what constitutes the firms main line of business. Second, Chan, Lakonishok, and Swaminathan (2007) demonstrate that a 4-digit GICS code classification using 24 categories achieves the same level of discrimination as the FF procedure using 48 categories. Finally, the ability to effectively discriminate between industries using a smaller number of categories results in more industry peers each year than the FF procedure, resulting in potentially more accurate industry averages. A breakdown of 4-digit GICS and FF industry classifications by year for the KLD database is provided in Appendix C (available from the authors upon request).

  • 23

    natural environment, the community, and suppliers (to the extent that certain diversity initiatives

    are directed toward suppliers). We detail the calculation of the SM variables in Appendix A.

    As a second proxy for the deviation from expected SM, we assume that ESM is close to

    the industry average for each firm in each year. Therefore, we use industry adjusted SM (IASM)

    as an additional measure of the deviation of each firm from expected stakeholder management:

    SM 2 where industry adjusted SM (IASM) is equal to the difference between each firms actual

    investment in SM at time t and the industry average SM (IAVGSM), the average value of peer

    firms within each companys 4-digit GICS industry group at time t.

    4.2.2. Managerial ownership incentives

    We use delta as a proxy for CEO equity-based compensation and ownership incentives.

    As in Edmans et al. (2009), delta is the dollar change in CEO portfolio wealth for a 1% change in

    firm value scaled by total annual compensation. We estimate each CEOs portfolio of stock and

    options using data from the EXECUCOMP database as in Core and Guay (2002). We detail the

    calculation of the CEO portfolio delta in Appendix B. We use log of delta (LNDELTA) in our

    analysis to account for the high skewness and kurtosis in the variable.

    4.2.3. Board monitoring

    We proxy for effective monitoring by the board of directors using four measures: board

    size, the percentage of independent directors on the board, board independence, and CEO duality.

    First, we measure board size (BRDSIZE) as the number of directors serving on the board during

    the year. Next, we classify directors as insiders (employed by the firm), affiliated (e.g. former

    employees, family members of employees, or those with business relations with the firm) and

  • 24

    independent (Baysinger and Butler, 1985). We then create a variable for the percentage of outside

    directors serving on the board (PIND) calculated as the percentage of outside directors relative to

    total directors on the board. We also create a composite measure of board independence

    (BRDIND), calculated as the ratio of independent directors to insider and affiliated directors

    multiplied by the inverse of board size. Higher values of this measure indicate more effective

    board structure (i.e. higher ratio of independent directors and/or smaller board size). Finally, we

    determine whether the CEO holds the title of CEO and COB (DUALITY) and create a dummy

    variable equal to one in such cases, and zero otherwise.

    4.2.4. Institutional and blockholder ownership

    We develop a measure of institutional investor ownership percentage (INSTOWN), which

    is the percentage of shares held by institutions during the year.

    4.2.5. Controls

    We include several additional control variables to proxy for various firm specific factors

    which have been shown to be determinants of stakeholder management, internal governance

    structure, and firm value.

    Cash. High cash balances may exacerbate agency problems (Jensen, 1986) leading to

    inefficient investment. We control for cash using the ratio of cash to total assets (CASH).

    Capital structure (Leverage). Theoretical and empirical research has found that leverage is

    positively related to firm value. However, Titman (1984) and Maksimovic and Titman (1991)

    argue that some firms also consider the costs imposed on non-financial stakeholders in

    undertaking relationship-specific investments when making capital structure decisions. For

    example, research has shown that firms selling unique products (Titman and Wessels, 1988), or

  • 25

    firms entering into bilateral relationships (Banerjee et al., 2008) or strategic alliances (Kale and

    Shahrur, 2007) maintain or lower leverage. We proxy for the firms capital structure using the

    debt ratio (TD/TA); we calculate it as book value of total debt to book value of total assets.

    Firm size. Research has shown that firm size is positively related to board size and CEO

    compensation, but negatively related to firm value. We control for firm size using the log of sales

    (LNSALES).

    Firm Performance. We measure accounting performance using return on assets (ROA),

    calculated as earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets. As an additional measure

    of financial performance, we use the 1-year total return to shareholders (TRS), including the

    monthly reinvestment of dividends. We obtain this measure from the COMPUSTAT database.

    4.2.6. Instruments

    We use several instruments to proxy for various firm specific factors which have been

    shown to be determinants of internal governance structure.

    Growth opportunities and information asymmetry. Jensen (1993) argues that monitoring

    high growth firms is costly, and Fama and Jensen (1983) suggest that firms with higher stock

    return volatility have higher levels of information asymmetry. Prior research has suggested that

    the monitoring costs associated with higher levels of information asymmetry are inversely related

    to board size and independence (Linck et al., 2008; Adams and Ferreira, 2007; Raheja, 2005;

    Maug, 1997). Similarly, Demsetz and Lehn (1985) note that higher levels of information

    asymmetry (as proxied by higher volatility) are associated with more managerial discretion,

    necessitating higher levels of variable compensation. Following Linck, et al. (2008) we proxy for

    growth opportunities and information asymmetry using Tobins Q, the level of R&D

    expenditures, and total firm risk. As in Smith and Watts (1992), we calculate Tobins Q (Q) as the

  • 26

    market value of equity minus the book value of equity plus the book value of assets all divided by

    the book value of assets.20 R&D expenditures (R&D/TA) are the dollar value of R&D

    expenditures scaled by total assets. Many firms in the COMPUSTAT database have missing

    values for R&D. We set R&D expenditures equal to zero when the value is missing. Total equity

    risk is measured using volatility (VOLATILITY), which is the annualized standard deviation of

    monthly stock returns calculated over 36 months.

    Capital intensity. Previous research has found that managerial ownership and

    compensation are related to the capital intensity of the firm. We include a variable for capital

    intensity (CAP), measured as the net property, plant, and equipment to total assets.

    CEO characteristics. Hermalin and Weisbach (1998) suggest that firms will add insiders

    to the board of directors as the CEO approaches retirement as part of the succession process. We

    use CEO age (AGE) as a proxy for the length of time to retirement of the CEO.

    Risk aversion. Following Coles, Naveen, and Naveen (2006), we include CEO tenure

    (TENURE), measured as the time the CEO has been in the current position, and CEO cash

    compensation (TCC), measured as salary plus bonus, as proxies for the CEOs level of risk

    aversion. CEOs with longer tenures may be entrenched, making them more likely to avoid risk

    (Berger et al., 1997). However, Guay (1999) argues that higher levels of cash compensation

    reduces manager risk aversion because cash compensation is unrelated to performance and

    permits their personal diversification.

    Turnover. As in Hartzell and Starks (2003), we use turnover (TURNOVER), the log of

    one plus the ratio of monthly volume to number of shares outstanding in the month prior to the

    institutional ownership observation, as an instrument for institutional investor ownership.

    20 We use Q rather than MKBK as in Linck, et al. (2008) to account for the problem of many firms having negative or small values of book value of equity in the denominator. This leads to negative values of MKBK or abnormally large values of MKBK that are driven by small book values of equity rather than large market values of equity.

  • 27

    4.3. Descriptive statistics

    Table 1, Panel A, presents descriptive statistics. The mean (median) deviation from

    expected stakeholder management score (DESM) is 0.02 (0.02). The measure ranges from a

    minimum score of 0.88 to a maximum score of 0.93. The mean (median) industry adjusted stakeholder management score (IASM) is 0.04 (0.05). The measure ranges from a minimum score

    of 1.01 to a maximum score of 1.14. The mean (median) stakeholder management score (SM) is 0.05 (0.00). The measure ranges from a minimum score of 1.12 to a maximum score of 1.16.

    -----Insert Table 1 About Here-----

    The mean (median) value for DELTA is 446.49 (85.41). Our sample boards average 9.66

    directors (BRDSIZE). Approximately 29.82% of directors are independent (PIND), and the CEO

    is also Chair (DUALITY) approximately 66% of the time. Institutional ownership (INSTOWN)

    averages 75.41% of shares outstanding. Finally, our sample consists of large industrial firms. The

    mean (median) value of total sales is $6.669 ($2.142) billion. However, the sample includes a

    broad range of firms with total sales ranging from $94.06 million to $81.303 billion.

    Table 1, Panel B, presents correlations of key variables for our sample. The correlations

    between the two measures of deviation from expected stakeholder management (DESM and

    IASM) and SM are significant. However, the correlations between DESM and IASM or SM are

    less than 90%, suggesting that they may capture different dimensions of overall deviation from

    expected stakeholder management. Lastly, we find that less financially constrained firms (higher

    CASH/TA and lower TD/TA) and firms with higher ROA are associated with higher deviations

    from expected SM (IASM and SM).21 This finding may also reflect that firms with slack financial

    resources are associated with higher levels of SM (Waddock and Graves, 1997).

    21 Note that we control for CASH/TA and TD/TA in equation 1 when calculating DESM. So, it is not surprising that DESM does not exhibit a similar significant correlation with these measures.

  • 28

    The correlations between LNDELTA and two of three measures of deviation from

    expected and actual SM are positive and significant. Interestingly, we also find that dollar/dollar,

    or effective percentage owned, incentives, (Jensen and Murphy, 1990) have a negative and

    significant correlation with both measures of deviation from expected SM and actual SM (un-

    tabulated). This finding is consistent with the predictions of Hall and Baker (2004) who note that

    dollar/dollar incentives are more effective at deterring tasks that do not scale with firm size.

    Deviations from expected SM, therefore, may be additive value destructive and reflect a form of

    perquisite consumption by the CEO. Combined, these findings provide initial support for the CEO

    perquisite consumption hypothesis (H2). Conversely, more effective corporate governance is

    associated with lower deviations from expected SM; it has positive and significant correlations

    with BRDSIZE, negative and significant correlations (DESM and IASM) with PIND, and

    negative and significant correlation (SM) with INSTOWN. Furthermore, higher LNDELTA is

    associated with more effective board governance (smaller BRDSIZE, higher PIND, separation of

    CEO and COB title) and lower levels of institutional ownership (INSTOWN). Overall, this initial

    evidence supports the board monitoring hypothesis (H3). As noted by Edmans et al. (2009), more

    effective corporate governance is associated with higher managerial incentives, the latter being an

    effective means of addressing agency costs that are proportionate with firm value. However,

    incentive pay is ineffective at deterring perquisite consumption, which is largely independent of

    firm value; additive value destructive actions are best controlled by direct monitoring, rather than

    incentive pay.22 Our initial observations suggest that firms recognize this tradeoff and adjust

    accordingly.

    22 As a final note, we find that percent/percent incentives (LNDELTA) are independent of firm size (LNSALES), whereas the dollar/dollar (Jensen and Murphy, 1990) and dollar/percent (Baker and Hall, 2004) measures have negative and significant correlations with firm size (un-tabulated). This makes the percent/percent measure an empirically desirable measure of managerial incentives (Edmans et al., 2009).

  • 29

    5. Analysis of the effect of internal governance mechanisms on the deviation from expected stakeholder management

    We begin by examining whether internal governance mechanisms are related to deviations

    from expected stakeholder management. Previous research has explored the relation between SM

    and firm performance using pooled ordinary least squares regressions, which assumes that a

    firms level of SM is exogenous to the firm (Hillman and Keim, 2001). Modeling the relation in

    this manner fails to control for unobserved firm heterogeneity, or omitted variable bias. As a

    result, it is possible that these results are biased due to multiple occurrences of the omitted

    variable across time periods. We, therefore, use firm fixed effects (FE) regression as the

    estimation method to control for the presence of unobserved firm effects.

    Specifically, we test whether changes in internal governance mechanisms affect deviations

    from expected stakeholder management or are endogenously determined by the firm specific

    factors. The model we test is as follows:

    DESM

    /

    3

    where deviation from expected stakeholder management (DESM) is a function of managerial

    ownership incentives (LNDELTA), board monitoring (BRDSIZE, PIND, DUALITY),

    institutional ownership (INSTOWN), controls (CASH/TA, TD/TA, LNSALES, ROA, TRS), and

    dummy variables for year. The definition of variables in regression equation (3) is as described in

    section 4.2. The sign beneath each variable indicates the expected relation between the dependent

    variable and relevant independent variables.

  • 30

    Table 2, column 1 reports results of fixed-effects (FE) estimates of regression equation

    (3).23 Here and throughout the table we compute the t (z)-statistics using robust standard errors

    clustered at the firm level (see Rogers, 1993; Wooldridge, 2002). The estimated coefficient for

    LNDELTA is positive and significant at the 5% level (t = 2.18). Higher managerial incentives are

    associated with larger deviations from expected stakeholder management. This result supports the

    CEO perquisite hypothesis (H2). While the signs on BRDSIZE and PIND are as predicted, only

    the estimated coefficient for BRDSIZE is significant at the 1% level (t = 3.01). Larger boards are

    associated with larger deviations from expected stakeholder management. This provides partial

    support for the board monitoring hypothesis (H3). The estimated coefficients for DUALITY and

    INSTOWN are insignificant. Column 2 includes our composite measure for BRDIND rather than

    BRDSIZE and PIND. While the sign on BRDIND is as predicted, the estimated coefficient for

    this variable is not significant. The significance and direction of the estimated coefficients for

    LNDELTA, DUALITY, and INSTOWN are similar to those in column 1.

    -----Insert Table 2 About Here-----

    While our initial finding provides some evidence that higher levels of managerial

    incentives are associated with greater deviations from expected SM and that more effective

    internal governance mechanisms work to lessen the deviations from expected SM, these

    deviations may also reflect either an under- or over-investment from expected SM. While a

    negative value of DESM (a negative residual) suggests an under-investment in SM, a positive

    value of DESM (a positive residual) suggests an over-investment. Internal governance

    mechanisms may influence under-investment and positive deviations from expected SM

    23 Pooling tests for firm fixed effects and year fixed effects are significant at the 1% level, supporting the inclusion of firm and time effects in the model. The conclusion of subject specific parameters in the model is also supported by a modified Wald statistic for group-wise heteroskedasticity in the residuals of a fixed effect regression model, following Greene (2003, p. 598). This statistic is consistent at the 1% level. Finally, a Hausman test for random effects is significant at the 1% level, supporting the use of the fixed effects model over the random effects model.

  • 31

    differently. To test this directly, we first sort DESM into quintiles. Firm observations in the

    bottom two quintiles, those with the most negative values, are classified as under-investing in SM.

    Firm observations in the top two quintiles, those with the most positive values, are classified as

    over-investing in SM. We classify firms in the middle quintile as near expected SM and treat

    them as a benchmark. We then estimate a multinomial logit model that predicts the likelihood that

    a firm will be in one of the two extreme quintile groups as opposed to the middle quintile.24

    Columns 3 and 4 contain results for a multinomial logit regression of equation (3).

    Column 3 contains estimated results for the under-investment in SM firms. The estimated

    coefficient for BRDSIZE is negative and significant at the 1% level (z = 3.77). Larger boards are associated with a lower relative risk of under-investment in SM. Column 4 contains estimated

    results for the over-investment in SM firms relative to the normal investment in SM firms. The

    estimated coefficient for BRDSIZE is now positive and significant at the 5% level (z = 2.25),

    while the estimated coefficient for PIND is negative and significant at the 5% level (z = 2.40). More effective board monitoring (i.e. smaller boards and more independent directors) are

    associated with a lower relative risk of over-investment in SM. Columns 5 and 6 report results

    using BRDIND rather than BRDSIZE and PIND. Column 5 contains estimated results for the

    under-investment in SM firms relative to the normal investment in SM firms. The estimated

    coefficient for BRDIND is positive and significant at the 10% level (z = 1.90). Column 6 contains

    estimated results for the over-investment in SM firms relative to the normal investment in SM

    firms. The estimated coefficient on BRDIND is now negative and significant at the 1% level (z =

    2.68). More independent boards are associated with a higher relative risk of under-investment in 24 We use a multinomial logit model rather than an ordered logit model because we are uncertain of the ordinality of the ESM measure. As noted by Long (1997), using a nominal model when the dependent variable is ordinal results in a loss of efficiency since information is ignored. However, applying an ordinal model to a nominal dependent variable may result in biased estimates. In cases where there is a question about the ordinality of the dependent variable, the loss of efficiency of using a nominal model is outweighed by the potential bias of ordinal model.

  • 32

    SM and lower relative risk of over-investment in SM. Overall, these results suggest that more

    effective board monitoring (i.e. smaller boards and more independent directors) may be effective

    at constraining over-investment, or positive deviations from expected SM. Our results continue to

    provide support for the board monitoring hypothesis (H3).

    Columns 7 and 8 contain estimated results for regression equation (3) replacing DESM

    with IASM as a proxy for the deviation from expected investment in SM. The significance and

    direction of the estimated coefficients for LNDELTA, BRDSIZE, PIND, BRDIND, and

    INSTOWN are similar to those in columns 1 and 2. The estimated coefficients for DUALITY,

    however, are now significant. This finding is consistent with prior research; successful CEOs,

    such as those better at maximizing shareholder wealth, become COB (Brickley et al., 1997).

    Lastly, the deviation of observed SM from the expected level of SM may be conditional

    upon the financing constraints faced by each firm. Under this assumption, SM is more likely to

    deviate from expected SM when managers are less financially constrained and agency problems

    are more likely to exist. We use cash and leverage as proxies for financial constraints. Large cash

    balances may exacerbate agency problems (Jensen, 1986). As such, managers of firms with large

    cash balances may have a tendency to overinvest in SM. Conversely, firms with low leverage may

    be less financially constrained, which may cause managers to over-invest in SM. We follow the

    procedure used in Biddle et al. (2009) to proxy for the financial constraints faced by each firm.

    We rank firms into deciles based on cash and leverage (we first multiply leverage by minus one

    so that it is decreasing in the level of financial constraint). We then create a composite measure

    for the propensity to over-invest in stakeholder management (OVER), which is the average of the

    ranked values of cash and negative leverage re-scaled so that the values range between zero and

    one. Higher values for OVER reflect less financially constrained firms, which may increase the

  • 33

    likelihood that observed SM deviates from expected SM; managers of these firms may have a

    greater propensity to over-invest in SM. We test this by creating interaction terms between each

    of our internal governance mechanism variables (LNDELTA, BRDSIZE, PIND, DUALITY, and

    INSTOWN) and OVER.

    Specifically, we test whether changes in internal governance mechanisms, conditional on

    whether the firm is financially constrained and more likely to over-invest in SM, affect observed

    SM or are endogenously determined by the firm specific factors. The model we test is as follows:

    SM

    4

    where stakeholder management (SM) is a function of managerial ownership incentives

    (LNDELTA), board monitoring (BRDSIZE, PIND, DUALITY), institutional ownership

    (INSTOWN), interactions between internal governance mechanisms and OVER, controls

    (LNSALES, ROA, TRS), and dummy variables for year. The definition of variables in regression

    equation (4) is as mentioned in section 4.2. We exclude CASH and TD/TA from our list of

    controls because they are used to calculate OVER. The estimated coefficients (1, 2, 3, 4, and 5) measure the relation between internal governance mechanisms and SM for the most financially

    constrained firms. The sum of the coefficients (1 + 6, 2 + 7, 3 + 8, 4 + 9, 5 + 10) measure the relation between internal governance mechanisms and SM for the least financially

    constrained firms. The sign beneath each variable indicates the expected relation between the

    dependent variable and relevant independent variables.

  • 34

    Column 9 contains results of fixed-effects (FE) estimates for regression equation (4). With

    the exception of the estimated coefficient for DUALITY, which is positive and significant at the

    10% level (t = 1.66), none of the estimated coefficients on the main effects (i.e. the most

    financially constrained firms) for LNDELTA, BRDSIZE, PIND, and INSTOWN are significant.

    However, as predicted, the estimated coefficients for the interaction between OVER and

    BRDSIZE is positive and significant at the 1% level, while the estimated coefficients for the

    interaction between OVER and DUALITY is negative and significant at the 1% level. This

    suggests that the relation between internal governance and investment in SM is conditional upon

    whether a firm is more likely to over-invest, and suggests that these mechanisms may be more

    effective at constraining excess SM. Furthermore, the overall relation between internal

    governance and SM for the least financially constrained firms (measured by the sum of the

    coefficients for the internal governance mechanism variables and the interaction terms between

    internal governance mechanisms and OVER) for LNDELTA and BRDSIZE are positive and

    significant at the 5% and 1% levels, respectively, while the sum of coefficients for DUALITY is

    negative and significant at the 5% level. While we find that the relation between INSTOWN and

    SM is significantly higher for less financially constrained firms, the overall relation is not

    significant. Our conclusion using BRDIND in column 10 is similar to that in column 9.

    5.1.1. Robustness tests

    In the presence of unobserved firm effects, firm fixed effects (FE) regression is commonly

    suggested. However, FE estimation may be unsuitable in our unbalanced panel for several

    reasons. First, several of our primary variables of interest, such as BRDSIZE and PIND, are

    relatively time invariant and cannot be estimated with FE regression as they would be absorbed in

    the within transformation of the variable. Second, FE estimation requires significant within panel

  • 35

    variation for important right-hand side variables to produce consistent and efficient estimates

    (Wooldridge, 2002, p. 286). For example, the within standard deviations for BRDSIZE (1.04) and

    PIND (9.13) are substantially smaller than the between standard deviations (2.21) and (12.55),

    respectively. Furthermore, while our sample spans 13 years, on average firms remain in our

    sample for approximately half of this period. Consequently, for robustness we also run random-

    effects (RE) GLS regression on the unbalanced panel, and we use FE estimation on a balanced

    panel of firms (153 firms and 1,989 firm-year observations) that remain in our sample for all 13

    years of our sample (reported in Appendix C and available from the authors upon request).25 Our

    results are similar to those using the FE model on the unbalanced panel, except that the estimated

    coefficients for PIND and BRDIND remain negative, but are generally significant.

    5.2. Exploring causality

    The estimated coefficients in Table 2 may be biased as the various internal governance

    mechanisms are endogenously formed (e.g. Hermalin and Weisbach, 2003). We address

    endogeneity concerns in two ways. First, to ensure that causality runs from internal governance to

    deviation from expected stakeholder management, we re-estimate regression equations (3) and (4)

    replacing contemporaneous internal governance variables with their lagged values and also using

    contemporaneous internal governance variables while including a lagged dependent variable in

    25 In cases where researchers are interested in the inferring significance of key variables in the model, Wooldridge (2002, pg. 290) suggests a t-statistic Hausman test computed as (FE/ RE)/{[se(FE)]2-[se(RE)]2}1/2 to determine whether a random effects estimator is appropriate. While the overall Hausman (1978) test is significant at the 1% level, the t-statistic Hausman tests are insignificant on all of the variables of interest, supporting the use of the random-effects model in our analysis. Consequently, we use random-effects (RE) GLS regression as the estimation method for our unbalanced panel. However, as noted by Mundlak (1978), one assumes that the researcher is making the assumption that the omitted variable, ci, is uncorrelated with xit when using a random-effects model. If this assumption is violated, the random-effects estimators are inconsistent. To minimize this issue, we include dummy variables for industry and year in our models to control for part of the ci correlated with xit. Still, a limitation of using the random effects model in our context is that we can only infer the significance of the relations for key variables (i.e. governance), rather than all variables in our model.

  • 36

    our regression equation. Our results are similar to those reported in Table 2 (un-tabulated and

    available from the authors upon request).

    While lagging the measurement of the dependent and/or independent variables partially

    controls for simultaneity, it does not provide a complete remedy. Our analysis to this point has

    treated the internal governance variables as exogenous, but if any one of these variables is

    determined simultaneously with deviation from expected stakeholder management, it violates the

    least squares regression assumption that the regressors are uncorrelated with the error term. To

    eliminate the endogeneity problem from simultaneity bias, we endogenize LNDELTA, BRDIND,

    and INSTOWN given the existing literature on managerial ownership incentives (Coles et al,

    2006), board structure determinants (Linck et al., 2008), and institutional ownership (Hartzell and

    Starks, 2003) by developing the following four regression equations:26

    5

    / 6

    / 7

    26 While DUALITY may also be endogenously formed, we treat it as exogenous because it is a binary variable. We also use the composite measure of effective board monitoring (BRDIND), rather than BRDSIZE and PIND separately to simplify interpretation of our results and due to difficulties identifying a set of instruments that is sufficiently correlated with PIND. The set of instruments is strongly correlated with BRDIND.

  • 37

    8 where the definition of variables is as mentioned in section 4.2 and the list of controls remains the

    same as in regression equation (3). The four equations, regression equations (5) (8) are solved

    using system of simultaneous equations using first-difference three-stage least squares (FD3SLS)

    to control for unobserved firm heterogeneity, or omitted variable bias.27

    Table 3 reports results of FD3SLS estimates of the system of four equations.28 Column 1

    contains FD3SLS results for regression equation (5). The estimated coefficient for BRDIND

    remains negative and significant at the 1% level (z = 6.26). More effective monitoring by the board of directors (smaller boards with more independent directors) leads to lower deviations

    from expected SM. This continues to support the board monitoring hypothesis (H3). The

    estimated coefficient for DUALITY also remains negative and significant at the 5% level (z =

    2.73). However, the estimated coefficient for LNDELTA, while positive, is no longer significant. Furthermore, the estimated coefficient for INSTOWN is now negative but not

    significant.

    -----Insert Table 3 About Here-----

    The results in columns 2 and 3 for regression equations (6) and (7), respectively, also

    provide some additional useful information. For example, the negative and significant estimated

    27 In the absence of specification problems, the use of a systems procedure, such as 3SLS, is asymptotically more efficient than a single-equation procedure such as 2SLS. But single-equation methods are more robust to misspecification (Wooldridge, 2002 p. 222). Our conclusions are unchanged using 2SLS (un-tabulated and available from the authors upon request). 28 A DavidsonMacKinnon (1993) test for endogeneity is significant at the 1% level supporting the use of the 3SLS model in Table 4. However, when conducting 2SLS/3SLS the set of instruments, z, must also be highly correlated with the endogenous regressors, xk, but uncorrelated with the disturbance process, u. The first condition, that the set of instruments is sufficiently correlated with the endogenous regressors, is supported by estimated coefficients and F statistics for the set of instruments that are significant at the 1% level, high Shea (1997) partial R2 values, and a Kleibergen-Papp (2006) LM statistic that is significant at the 1% level. The latter condition, that the set of instruments is uncorrelated with (orthogonal to) the disturbance process is supported by a non-significant Hansen-Sargan J-statistic.

  • 38

    coefficients for DESM in columns 2 and 3 suggest that there is an inverse relation between

    deviations from expected SM and the level of CEO incentives and board independence. Firms

    with lower deviations from expected SM have CEOs with higher incentives. Higher levels of

    managerial incentives potentially expose the firm to perquisite consumption in the form of

    unnecessary investment in SM. However, board independence also increases in tandem with the

    level of CEO incentives. The negative and significant estimated coefficient for BRDIND and

    positive but not significant estimated coefficient for LNDELTA in the main equation suggest that

    greater monitoring by the board effectively constrains this perquisite consumption by the CEO in

    the form of unwarranted investment in SM.

    5.2.1. Industry level analysis of the effect of internal governance mechanisms on deviations from expected investment in stakeholder management and components

    Although we find some support for a relation between various internal governance

    mechanisms and deviations from expected SM, industry likely plays an important role in

    determining the nature of the firm-level stakeholder environment, and as a result, influences the

    relative importance and allocation of resources to various competing stakeholder groups. For

    example, investment in diversity, community, and environment related stakeholder management

    may play a role in differentiating ones product for consumer oriented firms. As a result, some

    consumers may be willing to pay a premium for such products, leading to better financial

    performance. Higher investment in these dimensions of SM for industrial oriented firms,

    however, may provide limited financial benefits. Conversely, strong relations with employee,

    supplier, and product related stakeholder groups are likely to benefit both consumer and industrial