1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

38
1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition
  • date post

    20-Dec-2015
  • Category

    Documents

  • view

    223
  • download

    0

Transcript of 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

Page 1: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

1

Chapter 9

Static Games and Cournot Competition

Page 2: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

2

Introduction• In the majority of markets firms interact with few

competitors• In determining strategy each firm has to consider rival’s

reactions– strategic interaction in prices, outputs, advertising …

• This kind of interaction is analyzed using game theory– assumes that “players” are rational

• Distinguish cooperative and noncooperative games– focus on noncooperative games

• Also consider timing– simultaneous versus sequential games

Page 3: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

3

Oligopoly Theory• No single theory

– employ game theoretic tools that are appropriate– outcome depends upon information available

• Need a concept of equilibrium– players (firms?) choose strategies, one for each

player– combination of strategies determines outcome– outcome determines pay-offs (profits?)

• Equilibrium first formalized by Nash: No firm wants to change its current strategy given that no other firm changes its current strategy

Page 4: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

4

Nash Equilibrium• Equilibrium need not be “nice”

– firms might do better by coordinating but such coordination may not be possible (or legal)

• Some strategies can be eliminated on occasions– they are never good strategies no matter what the rivals do

• These are dominated strategies– they are never employed and so can be eliminated

– elimination of a dominated strategy may result in another being dominated: it also can be eliminated

• One strategy might always be chosen no matter what the rivals do: dominant strategy

Page 5: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

5

An Example

• Two airlines• Prices set: compete in departure times• 70% of consumers prefer evening departure, 30%

prefer morning departure• If the airlines choose the same departure times

they share the market equally• Pay-offs to the airlines are determined by market

shares• Represent the pay-offs in a pay-off matrix

Page 6: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

6

The example (cont.)The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

Morning

Morning

Evening

Evening

(15, 15)

The left-handnumber is the

pay-off toDelta

The right-handnumber is the

pay-off toAmerican

(30, 70)

(70, 30) (35, 35)

What is theequilibrium for this

game?

Page 7: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

7

1, If American chooses a morning departure, Delta will choose evening

2, If American chooses an evening departure, Delta will still choose evening

3, The morning departure is a dominated strategy for Delta and so can be eliminated.

4, The morning departure is also a dominated strategy for American and again can be eliminated

5, The Nash Equilibrium must therefore be one in whichboth airlines choose an evening departure

Page 8: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

8

The example (cont.)The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

Morning

Morning

Evening

Evening

(15, 15) (30, 70)

(70, 30) (35, 35)(35, 35)

Page 9: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

9

• Now suppose that Delta has a frequent flier program; When both airline choose the same departure times Delta gets 60% of the travelers

• This changes the pay-off matrix

If Delta chooses a morning departure, American will choose evening

But if Delta chooses an evening departure, American will choose morning

American has no dominated strategy.However, a morning departure is still a dominated strategy for

Delta. So, evening is still a dominant strategy.American knows this and so chooses a morning departure.

Page 10: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

10

The example (cont.)

The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

Morning

Morning

Evening

Evening

(18, 12) (30, 70)

(70, 30) (42, 28)(70, 30)

Page 11: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

11

Nash Equilibrium Again• What if there are no dominated or dominant strategies?• The Nash equilibrium concept can still help us in

eliminating at least some outcomes• Change the airline game to a pricing game:

– 60 potential passengers with a reservation price of $500– 120 additional passengers with a reservation price of $220– price discrimination is not possible (perhaps for regulatory

reasons or because the airlines don’t know the passenger types)– costs are $200 per passenger no matter when the plane leaves– the airlines must choose between a price of $500 and a price of

$220– if equal prices are charged the passengers are evenly shared– Otherwise the low-price airline gets all the passengers

• The pay-off matrix is now:

Page 12: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

12

See example in next page

1, If both price high then both get 30 passengers. Profit per passenger is $300.

2, If Delta prices high and American low then American gets all 180 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20.

3, Delta prices low and American high then Delta gets all 180 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20.

4, If both price low they each get 90 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20.

Page 13: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

13

The example (cont.)The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

PH = $500

$9000,$9000) ($0, $3600)

($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

PH = $500

PL = $220

PL = $220

Page 14: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

14

1, (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices low then Delta should also price low.

2, (PL, PH) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices high then Delta should also price high.

3, (PH, PH) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing high then neither wants to change.

4, (PL, PL) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing low then neither wants to change.

5, There are two Nash equilibria to this version of the game.

6,There is no simple way to choose between these equilibria. But even so, the Nash concept has eliminated half of the outcomes as equilibria.

7, Custom and familiarity might lead both to price high.8, Regret” might cause both to price low.

Page 15: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

15

Nash Equilibrium (cont.)The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

PH = $500

($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600)

($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

PH = $500

PL = $220

PL = $220

($0, $3600)

($3600, $0)

($9000, $9000)

($1800, $1800)

Page 16: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

16

1, (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices low then Delta would want to price low, too.

2, (PL, PH) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices high then Delta should also price high.

3, (PH, PH) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing high then neither wants to change.

4, (PL, PL) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing low then neither wants to change.

5, There are two Nash equilibria to this version of the game.6, There is no simple way to choose between these equilibria, but

at least we have eliminated half of the outcomes as possible equilibria.

Page 17: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

17

Nash Equilibrium (cont.)The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

PH = $500

($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600)

($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

PH = $500

PL = $220

PL = $220

($0, $3600)

($3600, $0)

($9000, $9000)

($1800, $1800)

Page 18: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

18

See next page1, Sometimes, consideration of the timing of moves can

help us find the equilibrium.2, Suppose that Delta can set its price first.3, Delta can see that if it sets a high price, then American

will do best by also pricing high. Delta earns $9000.4, This means that PH, PL cannot be an equilibrium

outcome5, Delta can also see that if it sets a low price, American

will do best by pricing low. Delta will then earn $1800.6, This means that PL,PH cannot be an equilibrium.7, The only sensible choice for Delta is PH knowing that

American will follow with PH and each will earn $9000. So, the Nash equilibria now is (PH, PH).

Page 19: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

19

Nash Equilibrium (cont.)The Pay-Off Matrix

American

Delta

PH = $500

($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600)

($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

PH = $500

PL = $220

PL = $220

($0, $3600)

($3600, $0)

($3,000, $3,000)

($1800, $1800)($1800, $1800)

Page 20: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

20

Oligopoly Models

• There are three dominant oligopoly models– Cournot

– Bertrand

– Stackelberg

• They are distinguished by– the decision variable that firms choose

– the timing of the underlying game

• But each embodies the Nash equilibrium concept

Page 21: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

21

The Cournot Model• Start with a duopoly• Two firms making an identical product (Cournot

supposed this was spring water)• Demand for this product is

P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2)

where q1 is output of firm 1 and q2 is output of firm 2

• Marginal cost for each firm is constant at c per unit

• To get the demand curve for one of the firms we treat the output of the other firm as constant

• So for firm 2, demand is P = (A - Bq1) - Bq2

Page 22: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

22

The Cournot model (cont.)P = (A - Bq1) - Bq2

$

Quantity

A - Bq1

If the output offirm 1 is increasedthe demand curvefor firm 2 moves

to the left

A - Bq’1

The profit-maximizing choice of output by firm 2 depends upon the output of firm 1

DemandMarginal revenue for firm 2 is

MR2 = (A - Bq1) - 2Bq2MR2

MR2 = MC

A - Bq1 - 2Bq2 = c

Solve thisfor output

q2

q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2

c MC

q*2

Page 23: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

23

The Cournot model (cont.)q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2

This is the best response function( or reaction function) for firm 2It gives firm 2’s profit-maximizing choice of output for any choice of output by firm 1

There is also a best response function for firm 1

By exactly the same argument it can be written:

q*1 = (A - c)/2B - q2/2

Cournot-Nash equilibrium requires that both firms be on their best response functions.

Page 24: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

24

See next page1, The best response function for firm 1 is q*1 = (A-c)/2B

- q2/2.2, If firm 2 produces nothing then firm 1 will produce the

monopoly output (A-c)/2B3, If firm 2 produces (A-c)/B then firm 1 will choose to

produce no output4, The best response function for firm 2 is q*2 = (A-c)/2B

- q1/25, The Cournot-Nash equilibrium is at Point C at the

intersection of the best response functions

Page 25: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

25

Cournot-Nash Equilibriumq2

q1

(A-c)/B

(A-c)/2B

Firm 1’s best response function

(A-c)/2B

(A-c)/B

Firm 2’s best response function

C

qC1

qC2

Page 26: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

26

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium

q2

q1

(A-c)/B

(A-c)/2B

Firm 1’s best response function

(A-c)/2B

(A-c)/B

Firm 2’s best response function

C

q*1 = (A - c)/2B - q*2/2

q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q*1/2

q*2 = (A - c)/2B - (A - c)/4B + q*2/4

3q*2/4 = (A - c)/4B

q*2 = (A - c)/3B(A-c)/3B

q*1 = (A - c)/3B

(A-c)/3B

Page 27: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

27

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.)• In equilibrium each firm produces qC

1 = qC2 = (A - c)/3B

• Total output is, therefore, Q* = 2(A - c)/3B• Recall that demand is P = A - BQ• So the equilibrium price is P* = A - 2(A - c)/3 = (A + 2c)/3• Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c)qC

1 = (A - c)2/9• Profit of firm 2 is the same• A monopolist would produce QM = (A - c)/2B• Competition between the firms causes their total output

to exceed the monopoly output. Price is therefore lower than the monopoly price but exceeds MC.

• But output is less than the competitive output (A - c)/B where price equals marginal cost

Page 28: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

28

Numerical Example of Cournot Duopoly• Demand: P = 100 - 2Q = 100 - 2(q1 + q2); A = 100; B = 2• Unit cost: c = 10• Equilibrium total output: Q = 2(A – c)/3B = 30;• Individual Firm output: q1 = q2 = 15• Equilibrium price is P* = (A + 2c)/3 = $40• Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c)qC

1 = (A - c)2/9B = $450• Competition: Q* = (A – c)/B = 45; P = c = $10• Monopoly: QM = (A - c)/2B = 22.5; P = $55• Total output exceeds the monopoly output, but is less

than the competitive output• Price exceeds marginal cost but is less than the

monopoly price

Page 29: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

29

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.)• What if there are more than two firms?• Much the same approach. • Say that there are N identical firms

producing identical products

• Total output Q = q1 + q2 + … + qN

• Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2 + … + qN)

• Consider firm 1. It’s demand curve can be written:P = A - B(q2 + … + qN) - Bq1

• Use a simplifying notation: Q-1= q2 + q3 + … + qN. This denotes output of every firm other than firm 1

So demand for firm 1 is P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1

Page 30: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

30

The Cournot model (cont.)

P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1$

Quantity

A - BQ-1

If the output ofthe other firms

is increasedthe demand curvefor firm 1 moves

to the leftA - BQ’-1

The profit-maximizing choice of output by firm 1 depends upon the output of the other firms

DemandMarginal revenue for firm 1 is

MR1 = (A - BQ-1) - 2Bq1MR1

MR1 = MC

A - BQ-1 - 2Bq1 = c q*1 = (A - c)/2B - Q-1/2

c MC

q*1

Page 31: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

31

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium q*1 = (A - c)/2B - Q-1/2

How do we solve thisfor q*1?

Q*-1 = (N - 1)q*1

q*1 = (A - c)/2B - (N - 1)q*1/2

(1 + (N - 1)/2)q*1 = (A - c)/2B

q*1(N + 1)/2 = (A - c)/2B

q*1 = (A - c)/(N + 1)B

Q* = N(A - c)/(N + 1)B

P* = A - BQ* = (A + Nc)/(N + 1)

Profit of firm 1 is P*1 = (P* - c)q*1= (A - c)2/(N + 1)2B

The firms are identical, So in equilibrium they will have identical outputs

Page 32: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

32

Related with previous page1, From q*1 , we know as the number of firms

increases output of each firm falls2, From Q*, we know as the number of firms

increases aggregate output increases3, As the number of firms increases price tends to

marginal cost4, As the number of firms increases profit of each

firm falls.

Page 33: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

33

Cournot-Nash equilibrium (cont.)• What if the firms do not have identical costs?• Once again, much the same analysis can be used

• Assume that marginal costs of firm 1 are c1 and of firm 2 are c2.

• Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2)

• We have marginal revenue for firm 1 as before

• MR1 = (A - Bq2) - 2Bq1

• Equate to marginal cost: (A - Bq2) - 2Bq1 = c1

Solve thisfor output

q1

q*1 = (A - c1)/2B - q2/2 A symmetric resultholds for output of

firm 2 q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - q1/2

Page 34: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

34

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium

q2

q1

(A-c1)/B

(A-c1)/2B

R1

(A-c2)/2B

(A-c2)/B

R2C

q*1 = (A - c1)/2B - q*2/2

q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - q*1/2

q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - (A - c1)/4B + q*2/4

3q*2/4 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/4B

q*2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B

q*1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B

1, What happens to thisequilibrium when

costs change?

2, As the marginalcost of firm 2

falls its best responsecurve shifts to

the right

3, The equilibriumoutput of firm 2increases and of

firm 1 falls

Page 35: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

35

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.)

• In equilibrium the firms produce qC

1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B; qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B

• Total output is, therefore, Q* = (2A - c1 - c2)/3B

• Recall that demand is P = A - BQ

• So price is P* = A - (2A - c1 - c2)/3 = (A + c1 +c2)/3

• Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c1)qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)2/9B

• Profit of firm 2 is (P* - c2)qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)2/9B

• Equilibrium output is less than the competitive level• Output is produced inefficiently: the low-cost firm

should produce all the output

Page 36: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

36

A Numerical Example with Different Costs

• Let demand be given by: P = 100 – 2Q; A = 100, B =2• Let c1 = 5 and c2 = 15• Total output is, Q* = (2A - c1 - c2)/3B = (200 – 5 – 15)/6

= 30• qC

1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B = (100 – 10 + 15)/6 = 17.5• qC

2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B = (100 – 30 + 5)/3B = 12.5• Price is P* = (A + c1 +c2)/3 = (100 + 5 + 15)/3 = 40• Profit of firm 1 is (A - 2c1 + c2)2/9B =(100 – 10 +5)2/18 =

$612.5• Profit of firm 2 is (A - 2c2 + c1)2/9B = $312.5• Producers would be better off and consumers no worse

off if firm 2’s 12.5 units were instead produced by firm 1

Page 37: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

37

Concentration and Profitability

• Assume that we have N firms with different marginal costs

• We can use the N-firm analysis with a simple change

• Recall that demand for firm 1 is P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1

• But then demand for firm i is P = (A - BQ-i) - Bqi

• Equate this to marginal cost ci

A - BQ-i - 2Bqi = ci

This can be reorganized to give the equilibrium condition:

A - B(Q*-i + q*i) - Bq*i - ci = 0But Q*-i + q*i = Q*and A - BQ* = P* P* - Bq*i - ci = 0 P* - ci = Bq*i

Page 38: 1 Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition.

38

Concentration and profitability (cont.)P* - ci = Bq*i

Divide by P* and multiply the right-hand

side by Q*/Q*

P* - ci

P*=

BQ*

P*

q*i

Q*

But BQ*/P* = 1/ and q*i/Q* = si

so: P* - ci

P*=

si

1, The price-cost marginfor each firm is

determined by its ownmarket share and overallmarket demand elasticity

Extending this we have

P* - cP*

= H

2, The verage price-cost margin is determined by industry

concentration as measured by the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index