00131043.pdf

download 00131043.pdf

of 7

Transcript of 00131043.pdf

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    1/7

    IEEE

    Transactions on Power

    Systems, Vo1.6,

    No.1,

    February

    1991

    23

    REAL-TIME

    PRICING OF REACTIVE POWER: THEORY AND CASE STUDY RESULTS

    by

    Martin L. Baughman

    Senior Member Student Member

    Professor Graduate Research Assistant

    Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering

    The University of Texas at Austin

    Austin, Texas 78712

    ShamsN Siddiqi

    ABSTRACT

    An analysis is made of real-time pricing policies of reactive

    power using a modification of the OPF model. The theory of real-

    time pricing of reactive power is presented, followed by a case study

    illustrating the magnitudes and ranges that real-time prices of

    reactive power might take

    on

    under different circumstances. The

    efficiency implications of real-time pricing of reactive power are

    compared with traditional power factor penalties. It is concluded

    that real-time pricing of reactive power should develop

    simultaneously with that of active power for maximum economic

    efficiency and smooth operation of the electricity marketplace.

    KEY

    WORDS

    ;

    Reactive Power, Real-Time Pricing, Optimal Power

    Flow

    I

    NTRODUCTIO

    N

    Real-time pricing of electrical energy is an area of intense

    research at present. Real-time pricing of reactive power is closely

    related to that of active

    or

    eal) power.

    The development of spot pricing theory and the analysis of

    the practice of spot pricing for real power have been carried out by

    Caramanis, Bohn and Schweppe [1],[2], among others. Schweppe,

    et. al. [3]

    see

    spot pricing becoming more attractive n a competitive

    electricity market, especially at the generation stage where

    independent power producers would adjust their generation levels

    according to the spot prices paid to the producers for their power

    production.

    An extensive discussion

    on

    the implementation and

    functioning of a spot price based energy marketplace is made in [4].

    It includes topics ranging from spot price based rates and revenue

    reconciliation to optimal investment conditions. a summary

    of

    existing rates that are related to real-time prices and load

    management schemes that reflect real-time pricing policies is

    provided in [5].

    A

    utility perspective on spot pricing is given in [6].

    Most discussions on spot pricing of real power are equally relevant

    to real-time pricing of reactive power.

    Unfortunately, the pricing of reactive power has received

    very little attention. A reason for this negligence is the inherent

    difficulty in understanding the concept, especially by economists.

    Berg, et. al. [7] point out the inconsistency and inadequacy of the

    present pricing policies based

    on

    power factor penalties. They

    suggest that, given the present high cost of additional investments

    by electric utilities, prices should be derived from economic

    principles, which support a pricing approach that has price equal

    marginal costs, that would also reflect today's technological

    constraints.

    As power system margins

    are

    reduced because of emphasis

    on the greater use of generation and transmission, power systems

    dispatchers must operate their systems much closer to their technical

    limits. Real-time prices for react ive power provide information to

    both users and dispatchers of electricity about the cost and value of

    reactive power usage, flows, and sources.

    90 SM

    466-3

    PWRS

    A

    paper recommended

    and

    approved

    by the IEEE Power System Engineering Committee of the

    IEEE Power Engineering Society for p re se n ta t i on a t t h e

    IEEE/PES 1990 Summer Meet ing, Minn eapol is, Min nesot a,

    July

    15-19, 1990.

    1990; made available

    f o r

    p r in t i n g A p r i l

    24

    1990.

    Manuscript submitted February 1,

    Ray and Alvarado [8] use a modification of the Optimal

    Power Flow

    (OPF)

    model which allows for the price

    responsiveness of real power demand to analyze the effects of spot

    pricing policies. A similar model, but one which also allows for the

    price responsiveness of reactive power demand, will be used here

    to

    analyze the impact of real-time pricing of real

    In this paper, an analysis is made of real-time pricing of

    reactive power using a modification of the OPF model. In the next

    section the theory of real-time pricing of reactive power is presented.

    In Section 111, a case study illustrating he magnitudes and ranges

    that real-time prices of reactive power might take on under different

    circumstances is presented. The next section then discusses the

    efficiency implications of real-time pricing of reactive power when

    compared with traditional power factor penalties. The last section

    concludes that real-time pricing of reactive power should develop

    simultaneously with that of active power for maximum economic

    efficiency and smooth operation of the electricity marketplace.

    II

    THEORY OF REAL-TIME PRIC NG

    OF

    REAC'I?VE POWER

    A theory of real-time pricing of reactive power that

    accurately reflects the underlying physical and engineering

    properties of electricity is presented below.

    The following notationwll be used in the derivation:

    C = total system operating cost

    Ci(.)= cost function of generating plant at Bus i

    Pgi

    =

    active power generation at Bus i

    Qgi

    =

    reactive power generation at Bus

    i

    Pdi

    =

    active power demand at Bus

    i

    Qdi

    =

    reactive power demand at Bus i

    Vi

    = voltage at Bus i

    6i =

    voltage angle at Bus i

    YBUS= Yij] = admittance matrix of the transmission network.

    8ij = phase angle of Yij

    Pi, = active power flow from Bus

    i

    to Bus j

    N

    = set of all buses in the system

    G = set of all buses having generating capacity

    MCpi= Lagrange multiplier on the active power equation at Bus i

    M Q =

    Lagrange multiplier on the reactive power equation at Bus i

    , i n =

    Lagrange multiplier on the minimum active power

    hi,m=

    =

    Lagrange multiplier

    on

    the maximum active power

    pi,min= Lagrange multiplier on the minimum reactive power

    pi, =Lagrange multiplier

    on

    the maximum reactive power

    qi,

    =

    Lagrange multiplier

    on

    the active power flow limit from Bus i

    reactive power.

    generation limit at Bus

    i

    generation limit at Bus i

    generation at Bus

    i

    generation at Bus

    i

    to Bus j

    Vimh=

    Lagrange multiplier on the minimum voltage level at Bus i

    Vim==

    Lagrange multiplier

    on

    the

    maximum

    voltage level at Bus

    i

    Epi

    =

    price elasticity of demand of active power at Bus i

    Q =

    price elasticity of demand of reactive power at Bus

    i

    Epqi = cross-price elasticity of demand for active power with

    respect to a change in price of reactive power at Bus i

    Espi

    =

    cross-price elasticity of demand for reactive power with

    respect to a change in price of active power at Bus i

    Dpi

    =

    demand for active power at Bus

    i

    for active power and

    reactive power prices equal to unity

    Dqj =

    demand for reactive power at

    Bus

    i for active power

    and reactive power prices equal to unity.

    0885-8950/91/0200-0023$01.00

    1991

    EEE

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    2/7

    24

    It is assumed that a single welfare-maximizingpublic utility

    owns and operates the generating plants and transmission network

    of the electric power system under consideration and it sells active

    and reactive power to independent customers. The utility is assumed

    to be able to set and communicate prices instantly, and can set a

    different price for each customer location at each moment. The

    customer responses to these prices are assumed to be known and

    are

    given by the demand functions. It is also assumed that demands are

    independent of past and future prices and, correspondingly, for

    generating costs. Therefore, the model can be solved as a single

    period model.

    Objective:

    The objective of the pricing policy is to maximize social

    welfare, that is, to maximize consumers' plus producers' surplus,

    subject to the operational constraints. This is accomplished by

    setting prices of real and reactive power at each bus at a particular

    time equal to the marginal costs of supplying real and reactive

    power, respectively, at that bus and that time, where the marginal

    costs are determined on the basis of an optimal load dispatch, that is,

    real and reactive power dispatch so

    as

    to minimize total operating

    costs of the utility, subject to the operational constraints. The pattern

    of

    optimal load dispatch is dependent on the real and reactive power

    demands, and, on the other hand, real and reactive power demands

    are dependent on the prices, that is, marginal costs determined from

    the optimal load dispatch. Thus, this is a bi-level problem consisting

    of an upper and a lower part. The upper level problem is that of

    satisfying the demand functions, where the prices are implicitly

    determined by the lower level problem, which is that of minimizing

    total operating costs subject

    to

    he operational constraints.

    Demand Functions:

    The demand functions are assumed to be of log-linear form

    exhibiting constant price elasticity and cross-price elasticity.The

    demand functions may be mathematically expressed in the following

    equation forms:

    Pd;= Dpi MCp;)Epi MCqi)Ep9'

    wi

    %i (MQi)E4ph(MCqi)'1 2)

    (1)

    which give the demand of real and reactive power at Bus i as a

    function of prices of real and reactive power at that bus, for all i E N.

    The parameters of the equations, which are Dpi, Dqi, Epi,

    Eqi,. Epqi, and Ew i, vary with customer classes, time under

    consideration, and other exogenous factors. For example, they may

    differ for residential and commercial customers, the time of day, the

    season, weather conditions, etc.

    The prices of real and reactive power, which are equal to

    marginal costs MCpi and MCqi, respectively, when load is

    dispatched optimally, are implicitly defined by the following lower

    level problem.

    Lower-level Objective Function:

    The lower level problem is basically the optimal power flow

    problem which has the objective of minimizing the total cost of

    operating the spatially separated generating units subject

    to

    he set of

    equations that characterize the flow of power throughout the system

    and all operational constraints. Since the operating cost of producing

    reactive power is much less than that of real power where the

    capacity exists, the operating cost of generating reactive power is

    assumed to be negligible compared to that of real power in the

    analysis to follow. Thus, the objective function may be expressed in

    the following form:

    Minimize

    C

    =

    Ci ( Pgi)

    (3)

    i e G

    where

    Ci

    Pgi ) is the operating cost of producing Pgi units of real

    power at the generating plant atBus i.

    There are several constraints to the lower level problem.

    Load Flow Equations:

    The set of equations, determined by Kirchoffs laws, that

    characterize the flow of power throughout the system are given

    below:

    (4)

    gi

    -

    Pdi

    - c

    Vi IVj 1YijI COS( iJ+6j-6i ) = 0

    j E N

    Qg; - Qdi

    +

    c Vi IV,

    j e N

    which are the active and

    respectively, for all i E

    N.

    lYij

    eaci

    Sin( Bij+6,-6i

    ) =

    0

    ( 5 )

    ve power flow equations,

    The Lagrange multipliers of the above constraints, MQi and

    MCqi respectively, give the marginal costs of supplying real and

    reactive power a t Bus i and thus determine the prices of real and

    reactive power, respectively, at that bus.

    Generation Limits:

    The generating plants of the utility have a maximum

    generating capacity, above which it is not feasible to generate due to

    technical or economic reasons. Generation limits are important in

    determining the operating points and marginal costs of generation.

    Generating limits are usually expressed as maximum and minimum

    active power and reactive power outputs,

    Pgi,min Pgi Pgi,max

    6)

    Qgi,max Qgi Qgi,max

    (7)

    where Pgi,min and Pgi,max are the minimum and maximum active

    power output and Qgi,min and Qgi,max

    are

    the minimum and

    maximum reactive power output, respectively, of the generating

    plant at

    Bus

    i, for all i

    E

    G

    If the plant at Bus

    i

    has only reactive power generating

    capability, for example, capacitor banks or synchronous

    condensers, then Pgi

    min

    = 0, Pgi,max = 0, Qgi,min = 0, nd the set

    of constraints effectivkly reduce to

    0

    2

    Qgi Qgi,max (8)

    Transmission Limits:

    Transmission limits refer to the maximum power or current

    that a given transmission line is capable of transmitting under given

    conditions. These limits can be based on thermal considerations or

    on stability considerations. Thermal limits usually dominate for

    shorter lines. Dynamic stabilitylimitsdominate longer line behavior.

    These limits affect the marginal costs of operation. Transmission

    limits

    are

    expressed here in terms of the maximum active power

    flow through the lines,

    9)

    where Pij = IVi I IVj IYi, COS(8ij+6,-6i ) - IVi l2 IYij I Coseij,

    assuming that shunt admittance is negligible, where Pij,min and

    Pij,max are the minimum and maximum active power flow,

    respectlvely, through the line connecting Bus i to Bus j , or i j,

    and all i, j EN .

    Voltage Limits:

    Voltage limits refer to the requirement for the system bus

    voltages to remain within a narrow range of levels. Since voltages

    are affected primarily by reactive power flows, the marginal cost of

    supplying reactive power to a bus is directly dependent in the

    voltage level requirement at that bus. The voltage limits can be

    expressed by the following constraints,

    10)

    where Vi,min and Vi, are the minimum and maximum voltage

    levels, respectively, hat are acceptable atBus i, for all i E

    N.

    Model Solution:

    A method of solution for the bi-level nonlinear programming

    problem is presented below.

    The Lagrangian to be minimized over all active power

    generation levels Pg, reactive power generation levelsQg, voltage

    levels V, and voltage angles 6, is:

    Pij,min Pij Pij,max

    Vi,min IViI I ViDa

    L

    Pg, Qg, V, 6 )

    =

    c

    Ci(Pgi)

    [

    operating costs

    I

    E G

    - ( M Q i ) [ P gi

    -

    Pdi

    -

    N~INjITY~~ICos(8i 6J-6i)]

    i

    E N j e N

    [

    active power flow equations ]

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    3/7

    25

    -

    M C ~ ~

    i

    wi

    I V ~w j wi j Sin(

    eij+6j--6i

    i EN

    j E N

    [

    reactive power flow equations

    ]

    -

    C hi,min(pgi-Pgi,min)

    i e G

    [

    min. active power generation limit

    ]

    [ max. active power generation limit ]

    [min. reactive power generation limit ]

    [max.reactive power generation limit]

    C hi,max Pg i- Pgi,max)

    i E G

    -

    C

    Fi,min Qgi - Qi,min)

    i E G

    C Wi,max Qi - Qi,max)

    i E G

    + c 'f qij lpijl Pij,max)

    i E N J E N

    I ransmission line constraints 1

    - C Vi,min

    -

    Vi,min)

    [ minimum voltage levels ]

    [ maximum voltage levels ]

    i E N

    + C Vi ,max

    I - Vi,max)

    (1 1)

    with the additional condition that the demand functions must be

    satisfied, that is,

    (12)

    i E N

    Pdi= Dpi MC P~ )~ ( Cqi)ER'

    Qdi=

    mi

    (MCPi)Egp'(MCqi)'g' (13)

    for all i E

    N.

    The Kuhn-Tucker conditions for the minimization problem

    along with the demand functions can be solved simultaneously to

    obtain the real-time prices of active and reactive power at each bus

    that maximizes overall social welfare along with the generation,

    demand, voltage magnitude and angle at each bus and the power

    flow in each line.

    Definition of Real-time Prices:

    Bus i and at a particular time is given by,

    pi

    =

    total cost of providing electricity to

    l

    customers subject

    to the operational constraints ]

    The real-time price of real power based on marginal cost at

    6

    6Pd

    6L

    6Pd

    -

    -

    = MCpi

    Similarly, the real-time price of reactive power based on

    6

    marginal cost at Bus i and at a particular time is given by:

    q , = total cost of providing electricity to

    all

    customers subject

    to the operational constraints ]

    SQdi

    6L

    -

    -

    6Qdi

    =

    MCqi

    111. CASE STUDY

    A simple, four-bus test power system, shown in Fig.1, is

    used to gain insights into the effects of real-time pricing.The buses

    are interconnected by high voltage transmission lines. At buses 1

    and

    2,

    there are util ity-controlled generating plants. The two

    generating units each have a unique operating cost function derived

    from data on fuel costs of the generating units. A controllable

    reactive power source is available at Bus 3. Customer loads exist at

    every bus and each load is assumed to be price sensitive and

    expressible by demand functions for active power and reactive

    power that have constant price elasticity and cross-price elasticity.

    The units of all quantities

    are

    given in per unit on a basis of 100

    MVA and 138 kV. Voltage angles are in radians.

    W

    eneratingUnit e m

    Figure 1 The Four-bus Test Power System

    Model Formulation:

    The modified OPF model used to solve the bi-level problem

    can be formulated as the optimization problem of minimizing the

    total cost of operating the spatially separated generating units subject

    to the load flow equations that characterize the flow of real and

    reactive power throughout the system, the operational constraints

    such as generation limits, transmission limits and voltage limits, and

    the demand functions for real and reactive power at every bus.

    Objective Function:

    Minimize C = C1( Pgl ) C2 Pg2 )

    Load Flow Equations:

    The formulation of the model is described below.

    =

    33251+1622 Pg1+169.5 Pg12+ 2098.9 Pg2+ 441.9 Pg22

    4

    Pgi

    -

    Pdi - ~ N i I N j I N i , i C ~ ~ 8 i j + 6 j - 6 i )

    a i

    a i

    C N , I N ~ I N ~ ~ I S ~ ~ ( ~ ~ , +

      o

    for i

    =

    1,2,3,4.

    0.0

    Pgl 6.3

    0.0 5 Pg2

    I

    2.0

    j = l

    4

    j = 1

    Generation Limits:

    -1.0

    Qgl 3.5

    -0.8 I

    Qg2 S 3.0

    0.05

    Qg3 2 0.2

    Transmission Limits:

    Pij 1.8

    for all i

    =

    1,2,3,4, j = 1,2,3,4 and i

    j.

    Voltage Limits:

    v1

    =

    1.0

    v2 = 1.0

    0.95 I V3 1.05

    0.95

    I

    V41 2 1.05

    Pd,

    =

    Dpl MCpl)-0'2(MCql)o'a

    Pd2

    =

    Dp2 M Q J ~ ) - ~MCq2)O.O

    Demand Functions:

    -0.0001

    Pd3 = DP3 MCP3 MCq3

    1

    Pd4

    =

    Dp4 MCp4)-'.05 MCq4 )-0 04

    Qd, = Dql MCpl )-o.2(MCql

    Q d 2 = D q 2 MCp2

    Qd3

    =

    Dq3 MCp3

    ) - 0 0 5

    MCq3

    Qd4 = Dq4 MCp4 )-0.02 MCq4 - O l

    where Dpi and Dqi vary with time of use and are determined

    from load curves. The values at the time of system peak are:

    Dpl

    =

    5.677 Dql = 2.962

    Dp2

    =

    1.444 Dq2 = 0.667

    Dp3

    =

    1.889

    Dq3 =

    0.8175

    Dp4 = 1.184 Dq4 = 0.6434

    MCq2 )O

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    4/7

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    5/7

    27

    Figures

    6

    and 7 show the effects of decreasing the reactive

    generating capacity of the generating unit at Bus

    3

    on the real-time

    prices of active and reactive power. Figures

    8.9,

    and 10 show the

    effects on active power de,mand. reactive power demand, and the

    revenue, costs and profits of the utility, respectively. Figure

    11

    shows that the revenue, and hence profit, of the reactive power

    generating plant alone initially increases due to increasing prices but

    then falls as the quantity produced is reduced more than the

    corresponding rise in prices.

    (b) Transmission Limits:

    Transmission limits affect real-time prices of reactive power

    much

    in

    the same way as it does real power prices. When the power

    flow constraint

    on

    a line ismade increasingly tight, the prices of real

    and reactive power on the receiving end of the line also increase.

    This is because the line flow constraint forces the use of a higher

    loss path to satisfy the demand requirements of the bus at the

    receiving end of the line, and may also require the reallocation of

    generation which would increase

    total

    operating costs.

    (c) Voltage limit:

    The greatest impact on the real-time prices of reactive power

    as well as the generation and consumption pattem of reactive power

    by the utility and customers is due to vol tage constraints. This is

    because voltages are affected mainly by reactive power flows and

    voltage constraints are usually relieved by adding sources of reactive

    power.

    b

    Busl

    Bus2

    9 Bus3

    Bus4

    z 321 ----

    3 1 :

    .

    I .

    . 1

    0 10 20 30

    40

    ReactivePowerGenerationat

    Bus 3

    Fig.6 Real-time Price of Active Power vs.Reactive Power

    Generation at Bus

    3

    1

    f

    z

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    P,

    Bus3

    Bus4

    Bus3

    Bus4

    0.2

    +

    0

    1 0 2 0 30 4 0

    ReactivePower Oeneration

    t

    Bus 3

    MVAR)

    Fig.7 Real-time Price of Reactive Power vs. Reactive Power

    Generation at Bus 3

    s

    -0.0

    -0.2

    -0.4

    -0.6

    4

    Busl

    B us 2

    Bus3

    Bus4

    -0.8

    0

    1 0 20

    30

    4 0

    ReactivePowerGenerationatBus

    3 (MVAR)

    Fig.8 Change in Active Power Demand vs. Reactive Power

    Generation

    at

    Bus

    3

    -

    t

    Busl

    +-

    Bus2

    9 Bus3

    Bus4

    -5

    10 20 30

    4 0

    ReactivePowerGenerationat

    Bus

    3 (MVAR)

    Fig9 Change in Reactive Power Demand vs. Reactive Power

    Generation at Bus

    3

    + Profit

    cost

    Rev.

    - l o

    I

    .

    I

    * 1 i

    0 10 20 30 4 0

    ReactivePower eneration t Bus 3 MVAR)

    Fig.

    10

    Change

    in

    Revenue, Cost, and Profit vs. Reactive Power

    Generation at Bus

    3

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    6/7

    28

    The effect of tightening the voltage constraint atBus 4 under

    real-time pricing of active and reactive power are shown in Figures

    12and 13. Figure 12 shows that the real-time price of active power

    rises at Bus 4 and changes very little at other buses with the

    increasingly tight constraint on Bus

    4

    voltage. On the other hand,

    the real-time price of reactive power at Bus 4 r ises very rapidly with

    the tightening of the constraint, as shown in Figure 13. Without

    real-time pricing of reactive power and the corresponding price

    responsiveness of reactive power demand, the tightening of the

    voltage constraint at Bus 4 could lead to skyrocketing costs of

    supplying reactive power

    to

    Bus

    4

    and consequent load intemption

    in order to maintain the

    desired

    voltage level.

    IV. COMPARISON

    WITH

    POWER F A O R PENALTIES

    Reactive power pricing based on power factor penalties is

    unable to provide accurate

    price

    signals to customers under voltage

    constraints. In the case in question, the marginal cost of reactive

    power at

    Bus

    4 is 693.52 per MVARHr when the voltage limit is

    0.966 PA., but the price of reactive power would be zero under

    power factor penalties since the power factor of the customer atBus

    4 is greater than 85 percent. Under real-time pricing of reactive

    power, the price of reactive power at Bus

    4

    would be

    693.52

    per

    MVARHr, equal to the marginal cost. Such a high price would

    provide a strong incentive for the customer to reduce eactive power

    demand.Thus, power factor penalties are unable to give accurate

    price signals to customers, while real-time prices provide such

    signals.

    Consider the case of two customers connected

    to

    Bus 4, one

    large customer having a demand of 200 MW and 113 MVAR and

    another smaller customer having a demand of

    20

    MW and

    19

    MVAR at the time of system peak, when the marginal cost of

    reactive power

    is

    0.56 per

    MV RHr

    t Bus 4. In order to calculate

    the bill for reactive power consumption under power factor penalty,

    the following billing algorithm is used for customers having power

    factors below 85 percent: The totalKWh for the month is multiplied

    by 85 percent and divided by the average power factor for that

    month for adjustment purpose. Under this penalty policy, the larger

    customer who demands 113 MVAR of reactive power will not be

    penalized, that is. his monthly bill for real power consumption-will

    not increase due to his reactive power consumption since the

    cugtomer's power factor is greater than 85 percent, namely 87

    percent. On the other hand, the smaller customer would be penalized

    for his demand of

    19

    MVAR and,

    if

    a load factor of one is assumed,

    the customer's monthly bill would be

    1.1724

    times his bill for real

    power consumption alone. This represents an increase in the

    monthly bill of 17.24percent for the smaller customer, while the

    larger customer's bill does not increase. The smaller customer

    effectively pays 7.26per MVARHrwhile the larger customer pays

    $0.00 per MVARHr, even though the larger customer is the major

    consumer of reactive power. Thus, the cost burden is inequitably

    shared by the customers under reactive power pricing based on

    power factor penalties.

    Under real-time pricing of reactive power, both customers

    would pay the same real-time price of 0.56 per MVARHr. Thus,

    each customer would pay

    in

    the exact proportion

    as

    the amount of

    reactive power consumed by each, which results in an equitable

    sharing of the cost burden. The cost imposed on a utility due to the

    reactive power demand at a bus depends on the amount of reactive

    power consumed and not on the power factors of the individual

    customers. Hence, reactive power pricing based on power factor

    penalties does not result in equitable sharing of the cost burdens

    while real-time pricing of reactive power based on marginal costs

    does result in equitable sharing of cost burdens.

    V.

    CONCLUSION

    The importance of an efficient reactive power pricing policy

    is beginning to

    be

    recognized by the utility industry. Accurate price

    signalsare essential for proper investment planning by the utility and

    the customerssoas to

    maximize

    overallsocialwelfare.

    Real-time pricing of active and reactive power are necessary

    ingredients for a successful marketplace of electricity. Such a market

    would treat VARs like other market mc di ti es , thus providing a

    market mechanism for buving and selling VARs. This would

    facilitate marketplace transactions of reactive power including

    buying and selling of VARs to neighboring utilities, large industries

    and independent power producers as well as to cletermine wheeling

    charges for VARs.

    5 1

    -15

    0

    10

    2 0

    30

    40

    Reactive owa

    GenerationatBus3

    MVAR)

    Fig.

    11

    Change in Revenue from VAR Sales atBus 3 vs. Reactive

    Power Generation at

    Bus 3

    3oo 1

    100

    0 1

    0.90 0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98

    Voltage

    at

    Bus

    4

    @er

    unit)

    Fig.12 Real-time Price of Active.Power vs. Voltage at Bus 4

    M O 1

    P

    a

    f

    -200

    0.90 0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98

    Voltage

    at

    Bus4 @er unit)

    Fig.13Real-time Price of Reactive Power at Bus

    4

    vs. Voltage

    at

    Bus

    4

  • 8/17/2019 00131043.pdf

    7/7

    29

    APPENDIX: TRANSMISSION

    LINE

    IMPEDGNCE DATA

    Line, Length

    bus to R X R X Charging

    bus km

    mi

    R R perunit perunit MVAR

    1-2 64.4

    40

    8

    32 0.042

    0.168 4.1

    1-4 48.3 30

    6

    24

    0.031

    0.126 3.1

    2-3 48.3 30

    6

    24 

    0.031

    0.126 3.1

    2-4 128.7

    80

    16 64

    0.084 0.336

    8.2

    3-4

    80.5

    50

    10 40

    0.053

    0.210 5.1

    REFERENCES

    1 )

    Caramanis, M. C., R. E. Bohn, and F. C. Schweppe, Spot

    Pricing of Electricity: Practice and Theory , IEEE

    Transactions

    on

    Power Apparatus and Systems

    Vol.

    PAS-101,

    No.

    9,

    September

    1982,

    pp.

    3234 - 3245.

    2)

    Bohn, R. E., M. C. Caramanis, and F.

    C.

    Schweppe, Optimal

    Pricing in Electrical Networks Over Space and Time ,The

    Rand

    Journal of Economics

    Vol.

    15,

    No.

    3

    (Autumn

    1984),

    pp.

    360

    3)

    Schweppe,

    F.,

    et al, Homeostatic Control for Electric Power

    Usage ,

    IEEE Spectrum

    July

    1982,

    pp.

    44

    -

    48.

    4) Schweppe, F. C., Caramanis, M. C., Tabors, R.

    D.,

    and Bohn,

    R. E.,

    Spot Pricing

    of

    Electricity

    Kluwer Academic Publishers,

    Boston, MA,

    1988.

    5)

    Tabors, R.

    D.,

    F. C. Schweppe, and M. C. Caramanis, Utility

    Experience with Real Time Rates , IEEE Summer Power

    Meeting,

    1988.6)

    Garcia, E. V., and J. E. Runnels, The Utility Perspective of

    Spot Pricing , IEEE

    1984

    Summer Power Meeting, Seattle,

    Washington, July

    15 - 20, 1984.

    Paper

    84-SM-:54-2.

    7)

    Berg, Sanford V., J. Adams and B. Niekum, Power Factors

    and the Efficient Pricing and Production of Reactive Power ,

    The Energy Journal Vol. 4, Special Electricity Issue, pp. 93

    -

    102.

    8)

    Ray,

    D.,

    and F. Alvarado, Use of an Engineering Model for

    Economic Analyses in the Electric Utility Industry , Department

    of Electrical and Computer Engineering, University of

    Wisconsin-Madison,

    1988,

    presented at the Advanced

    Workshop on Regulation and Public Utility Economics, Rutgers

    University, May

    25-27, 1988.

    9)

    Lasdon, L.S. and Waren, A.D., Generalized Reduced Gradient

    Software for Linearly and Nonlinearly Constrained Problems ,

    in

    Design and Implementation

    of

    Optimization Software

    H.

    Greenberg, ed., Sijthoff and Noordhoff, pubs.,

    1979.

    - 376.

    Martin L. Baughman

    (S,

    72)

    was

    bom

    on February

    18,1946

    in

    Paulding,

    Ohio.

    He received

    his

    BS

    in Electrical Engineering from Ohio

    Northem University in

    1968

    and his

    MSEE ndPhD degrees in electrical

    engineering at

    MIT

    in

    1970

    and

    1972,

    respectively.

    Dr.

    Baughman was

    a

    Research

    Associate at Massachusetts Institute of

    Technology from

    1972

    to

    1975,

    at

    which time he joined the University

    of Texas at Austin as a Senior

    Research Associate. In

    1976

    he

    joined the faculty of the Department of Electrical and Computer

    Engineering as an Assistant Professor. In

    1979

    he coauthored a

    book with Paul Joskow on electricity supply planning entitled

    Electricitv in the U n i w s : Models and Policv Analv&. From

    1984

    to

    1986

    he chaired the National Research Council Committee

    on Electricity

    in

    Economic Growth. He

    has

    served

    as a consultant

    to several agencies, including Edison Electric Institute, the MIT

    Energy Laboratory, the Economic Councilof Canada, and the

    Ministry of Planning in Saudi Arabia, and the Electric Power

    Research Institute.

    Dr.

    Baughman is a member of the Intemational Association

    of Economists and registered ProfessionalEngineer in the state of

    Texas.

    N. Siddiai was bom in

    Chittagong, Bangladesh on

    September

    1,1964.

    He received a

    B.Sc. (Engineering) from Bangladesh

    University of Engineering and

    Technology in 1988. He received a

    Masterdegree n Electrical

    Engineeringfrom he University

    of

    Texas at Austin in

    1989.

    He has been

    a Graduate Research Assistant with

    the Center for Energy Studies at the

    University of Texas at Austin since September,1988, where he is

    pursuing a PhD in the Departmentof Electrical and Computer

    Engineering.

    economics, electricity pricing, and optimal power dispatch.

    His esearch interests are in the areas of power systems