© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department...

45
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Transcript of © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department...

Page 1: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Page 2: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Page 3: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

What is the essential difference between:

A city police department and Brinks security

Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and fish in a fish farm

A live concert and a concert on television

These and all goods and services can be classified according to whether they are excludable or nonexcludable and rival or nonrival.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 4: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Excludable

A good is excludable if only the people who pay for it are able to enjoy its benefits.

Brinks’s security services, East Point Seafood’s fish, and a Coldplay concert are examples.

Nonexcludable

A good is nonexcludable if everyone benefits from it regardless of whether they pay for it.

The services of the LAPD, fish in the Pacific Ocean, and a concert on network television are examples.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 5: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Rival

A good is rival if one person’s use of it decreases the quantity available for someone else.

A Brinks’s truck can’t deliver cash to two banks at the same time. A fish can be consumed only once.

Nonrival

A good is nonrival if one person’s use of it does not decrease the quantity available for someone else.

The services of the LAPD and a concert on network television are nonrival.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 6: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

A Four-Fold Classification

Private Goods

A private good is both rival and excludable.

A can of Coke and a fish on East Point Seafood’s farm are examples of private goods.

Public goods

A public good is both nonrival and nonexcludable. A public good can be consumed simultaneously by everyone, and no one can be excluded from its benefits.

National defense is the best example of a public good.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 7: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Common Resources

A common resource is rival and nonexcludable.

A unit of a common resource can be used only once, but no one can be prevented from using what is available. Ocean fish are a common resource.

They are rival because a fish taken by one person isn’t available for anyone else.

They are nonexcludable because it is difficult to prevent people from catching them.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 8: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Natural Monopolies

In a natural monopoly, economies of scale exist over the entire range of output for which there is a demand.

A special case of natural monopoly arises when the good or service can be produced at zero marginal cost. Such a good is nonrival. If it is also excludable, it is produced by a natural monopoly.

The Internet and cable television are examples.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 9: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.1 shows this four-fold classification of goods and services.

Classifying Goods and Resources

Page 10: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

The Free-Rider Problem

A free rider enjoys the benefits of a good or service without paying for it.

Because no one can be excluded from the benefits is a public good, everyone has an incentive to free rise.

Public goods create a free-rider problem—the absence of an incentive for people to pay for what they consume.

Public Goods

Page 11: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

The value of a private good is the maximum amount that a person is willing to pay for one more unit of it.

The value of a public good is the maximum amount that all the people are willing to pay for one more unit of it.

To calculate the value placed on a public good, we use the concepts of total benefit and marginal benefit.

Public Goods

Page 12: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Marginal Social Benefit of a Public Good

Total benefit is the dollar value that a person places on a given quantity of a good.

The greater the quantity of a good, the larger is a person’s total benefit.

Marginal benefit is the increase in total benefit that results from a one-unit increase in the quantity of a good.

The marginal benefit of a public good diminishes with the quantity of the good provided.

Public Goods

Page 13: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.2 shows that the marginal social benefit of a public good is the sum of marginal benefits of everyone at each quantity of the good provided.

Part (a) shows Lisa’s marginal benefit.

Part (b) shows Max’s marginal benefit.

Public Goods

Page 14: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

The economy’s marginal social benefit of a public good is the sum of the marginal benefits of all individuals at each quantity of the good provided.

The economy’s marginal social benefit curve for a public good is the vertical sum of all individual marginal benefit curves.

Public Goods

Page 15: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

The marginal social benefit curve for a public good contrasts with the demand curve for a private good, which is the horizontal sum of the individual demand curves at each price.

Public Goods

Page 16: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

The Marginal Social Cost of a Public Good

The marginal social cost of a public good is determined in the same way as that of a private good.

The Efficient Quantity of a Public Good

The efficient quantity of a public good is the quantity that at which marginal social benefit equals marginal social cost.

Public Goods

Page 17: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.3 illustrates the efficient quantity of a public good.

With fewer than 2 satellites, MSB exceeds MSC.

Resources a can be used more efficiently by increasing the quantity.

Public Goods

Page 18: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

With more than 2 satellites, MSC exceeds MSB.

Resources can be used more efficiently if fewer satellites are provided.

So the quantity at which MSB = MSC, resources are used efficiently.

Private production would produce 0 satellites.

Public Goods

Page 19: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Inefficient Private Provision

If a private firm tried to produce and sell a public good, almost no one would buy it.

The free-rider problem results in too little of the good being produced.

Public Goods

Page 20: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Efficient Public Provision

Because the government can tax all the consumers of the public good and force everyone to pay for its provision, public provision overcomes the free-rider problem.

If two political parties compete, each is driven to propose the efficient quantity of a public good.

A party that proposes either too much or too little can be beaten by one that proposes the efficient amount because more people vote for an increase in net benefit.

Public Goods

Page 21: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.4 illustrates the efficient political outcome.

Two parties, Doves and Hawks, agree on everything except the number of satellites.

If Doves propose 1 satellites and Hawks propose 3, voters are equally unhappy and the election is too close to call.

Public Goods

Page 22: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

If Doves increase the number of satellites to 2, it will win the election if Hawks propose 3.

If Hawks decrease the number of satellites to 2, it will win the election if Doves propose 1.

Both parties propose 2 satellites and each party gets 50 percent of the votes.

Public Goods

Page 23: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Principle of Minimum Differentiation

The attempt by politicians to appeal to a majority of voters leads them to the same policies—an example of the principle of minimum differentiation.

The principle of minimum differentiation is the tendency for competitors to make themselves similar so as to appeal to the maximum number of clients (voters).

(The same principle applies to competing firms such as McDonald’s and Burger King).

Public Goods

Page 24: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Inefficient Public Overprovision

If competition between two political parties is to deliver the efficient quantity of a public good, bureaucrats must cooperate and help achieve this outcome.

Objective of Bureaucrats

Bureaucrats want to maximize their department’s budget.

A bigger budget increases their status and power.

Bureaucrats might try to persuade politicians to provide more than the efficient quantity.

Public Goods

Page 25: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Rational Ignorance

Rational ignorance is the decision by a voter not to acquire information about a policy or provision of a public good because the cost of doing so exceeds the expected benefit.

For voters who consume but don’t produce a public good, it is rational to be ignorant about the costs and benefit.

For voters who produce a public good, it is rational to be well informed.

When the rationality of uninformed voters and special interest groups is taken into account, the political equilibrium results in overprovision of a public good.

Public Goods

Page 26: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.5 shows bureaucratic overprovision.

If rationally ignorant voters enable the bureaucrats to achieve their goal of maximizing their budget,

public good might be overprovided and

and a deadweight loss created.

Public Goods

Page 27: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Two Types of Political Equilibrium

The two types of political equilibrium—efficient provision and inefficient overprovision of public goods correspond to two theories of government:

Social interest theory predicts that political equilibrium achieves efficiency because well-informed voters refuse to support inefficient policies.

Public choice theory predicts that government delivers an inefficient allocation of resources—that government failure parallels market failure.

Public Goods

Page 28: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Why Government Is Large and Grows

Two possible reasons are

Voter preferences

Inefficient overprovision

Government grows because the voters’ demand for some public goods is income elastic.

Inefficient overprovision might explain the size of government but not its growth rate.

Public Goods

Page 29: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Voters Strike Back

If government grows too large relative to the value voters place on public goods, there might be a voter backlash that leads politicians to propose smaller government.

Privatization is one way of coping with overgrown government and is based on distinguishing between public provision and public production of public goods.

Public Goods

Page 30: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Common Resources

The Tragedy of the Commons

The tragedy of the commons is the absence of incentives to prevent the overuse and depletion of a commonly owned resource.

Examples include the Atlantic Ocean cod stocks, South Pacific whales, and the quality of the earth’s atmosphere.

The traditional example from which the term derives is the common grazing land surrounding middle-age villages.

Page 31: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Sustainable Production

Sustainable production is the rate of production that can be maintained indefinitely.

This production rate depends on the existing stock of fish and the number of boats that go fishing.

For a given fish stock, as more boats go fishing, the quantity of fish caught increases.

But with too many boats fishing, the quantity of fish caught decreases.

Common Resources

Page 32: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Table 17.1 illustrates the number of boats and the quantity if fish caught.

As the number of fishing boats increases, the quantity of fish caught increases to some maximum.

Overfishing occurs when the maximum sustainable catch decreases.

Common Resources

Page 33: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Table 17.1 also shows the average and marginal catch depends on the number of boats that go fishing.

As the number of fishing boats increases:

The average quantity of fish caught decreases.

The marginal catch decreases.

Common Resources

Page 34: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.6 illustrates the sustainable production of fish.

As the number of fishing boats increases, the quantity of fish caught increases to some maximum.

Overfishing occurs when the maximum sustainable catch decreases.

Common Resources

Page 35: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

An Overfishing Equilibrium

Figure 17.7 shows why overfishing occurs.

Marginal private benefit, MB, is the average catch per boat.

Marginal private benefit decreases as the number of boats increases.

The marginal cost per boat is MC (assumed constant).

Common Resources

Page 36: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Equilibrium occurs where, MB equals MC.

In equilibrium, the resource is overused

because no one takes into account the effects of her/his actions on other users of the resources.

Common Resources

Page 37: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

The Efficient Use of the Commons

The quantity of fish caught by each boat decreases as the number of boats increases.

But no one has an incentive to take this fact into account when deciding whether to fish.

The efficient use of a common resource requires marginal social cost to equal marginal social benefit.

Common Resources

Page 38: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Marginal Social Benefit

Marginal social benefit is the increase in the total fish catch that results from an additional boat.

Marginal social benefit equals the marginal catch of a boat, not the average catch per boat.

Common Resources

Page 39: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Efficient Use

Figure 17.8 shows the marginal private benefit curve, MB, and the marginal social benefit curve, MSB.

With no external costs, the marginal social cost MSC equals marginal cost MC.

Resources are used efficiently when MSB equals MSC.

Common Resources

Page 40: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Achieving an Efficient Outcome

It is harder to achieve an efficient use of a common resource than to define the conditions under which it occurs.

Three methods that might be used are

Property rights

Production quotas

Individual transferable quotas (ITQs)

Common Resources

Page 41: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Property Rights

By assigning property rights, common property becomes private property.

When someone owns a resource, the owner is confronted with the full consequences of her/his actions in using that resources.

The social benefits become the private benefits.

But assigning property rights is not always feasible.

Common Resources

Page 42: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Production Quotas

By setting a production quota at the efficient quantity, a common resource might remain in common use but be used efficiently.

Figure 17.9 shows this situation.

It is hard to make a production quota work.

Common Resources

Page 43: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Individual Transferable Quotas

An individual transferable quota (ITQ) is a production limit that is assigned to an individual who is free to transfer (sell) the quota to someone else.

A market in ITQs emerges.

If the efficient quantity of ITQs is assigned, the market price of an ITQ confronts resource users with a marginal cost of MC + price of ITQ.

With MC + price of ITQ equal to MSB, the quantity produced is efficient.

Common Resources

Page 44: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Figure 17.10 shows the situation with an efficient number of ITQs.

The market price of an ITQ increases the marginal cost to MC0 + price of ITQ.

Users of the resource make MB equal MC0 + price of ITQ, and the outcome is efficient.

Common Resources

Page 45: © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What is the essential difference between: A city police department and Brinks security Fish in the Atlantic Ocean and.

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley

Public Choice and Political Equilibrium

It is easy for economists to agree that ITQs make it possible to achieve an efficient use of a common resource.

It is difficult to get the political marketplace to deliver that outcome.

In 1996, Congress killed an attempt to use ITQs in the Gulf of Mexico and the Northern Pacific Ocean.

Self-interest and capture of the political process sometimes beats the social interest.

Common Resources