Public Goods Lecture 11 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini.

Post on 18-Dec-2015

221 views 2 download

Tags:

Transcript of Public Goods Lecture 11 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini.

Public Goods

Lecture 11 – academic year 2014/15Introduction to Economics

Fabio Landini

What do we do today?

• Lect. 11: what happens when markets cannot provide a price for goods?

• Lect. 11: what’s the difference between private goods and public goods?

• Lect. 11: how can we come avoid opportunistic behaviour (free rider)?

3

Common resources

• What happens when natural resources finishes (e.g. fish)?

• Which countries and/or citizens have to pay for such resources?

Public goods

• Who decides how much we should spend for the public sector?

• What could happen if everyone stop paying taxes?

In our economic system (private capitalism) most goods are allocated though the market mechanism.

For these goods, the price is the reference point for consumers (how much to buy) and producers (how much to sell).

The allocative function of prices

However, there are also free goods (nice walk in Parco Ducale).

For free goods, markets are not good devices to design the allocation of the resources.

The price does not reflect the consumers’ willingness to pay.

Indeed, the price cannot equalize supply and demand.

Not everything has a price…

In this case:

Public intervention

can solve market failure & increase economic welfare.

Not everything has a price…

Market efficiency and good typology

The efficiency of markets depends on the type of goods.

The various goods available in our economy differ along two dimensions

Excludability

and

Rivalry

ExcludabilityAn individual can be prevented from using a good (e.g. laws usually recognize the private property of a good)

Typologies of economic goods

RivalryThe consumption of a good by an individual prevents the simultaneous consumption of the same good by other individuals

Typologies of economic goods

A bridge connects two shores of a river

Given a certain dimension of the bridge, if the n. of people using the bridge increases (congestion): consumption rivalry

If there is a tax for the bridge (those who don’t pay cannot use it): consumption excludability

Example of a public good: A bridge

Rival

Not rival

N. people

Many

Few

Free accessExample of the bridge

ExcludableNot

excludable

Tax

yes No

Given number of people

Example of the bridge

Excludable

Rival(PRIVATE GOODS)

Not excludable

Rival(COMMONS)

Excludabe

Not rival(NATURAL

MONOPOLY)

Not excludable

Not rival(PUBLIC GOODS)

Tax

Yes No

N. people

Many

Few

Example of the bridge: two-ways table

Four types of economic goods (1)

Private goods•Both excludable and rival

Example: ice-cream, CDs, etc.

Public goods•Neither excludable nor rival

Example: national defence, scientific knowledge, Wikipedia

Four types of economic goods (1)

Commons•Rival but not excludable

Example: sea fish.

Natural monopoly•Excludable but not rival

Example: drinkable water

Public goods and externalities

Non-excludable goods all can benefit without paying the price, p = 0

Access to the good cannot be limited; private value = 0, social value > 0

But: production costs > 0 (scarce resources)

Who is it going to produce the good, if not paid?

Therefore: positive externalities of a public good (autonomously, market produces too few).

The problem of free riding

A free rider is a person who can enjoy the benefit of a good without paying the price

The bridge is

built

The bridge is not built

I contribute(I pay 10) 90 - 10

I do not contribute(I don’t pay)

100 0

In order to build the bridge, a voluntary contribution equal to 10 is requested…..

It is convenient for me NOT to pay!!!

Free riding in public transport

The problem of free riding

Since public goods are not excludable, each individual can refuse to pay the good, hoping that other people will pay in his/her place.

If everybody reasons the same, the good is not produced.

IMPORTANT: the presence of free riding makes it impossible to rely on the market to supply public goods.

Solution of the free riding problem

If the benefits > costs (social value > 0), public authorities can produce the good by relying on taxes.

Example: fireworks by Moena’s Municipality

– 500 inhabitants; value for each inhabitant =10 €; cost of fireworks = 1000 €.

– Fireworks tax for each inhabitant = 2€, it covers the costs.

– Consumer surplus = 8€ (= 10€ - 2€).

The need for a State to produces public goods, whose cost is financed via taxes, represents the main economic justification for the existence of taxation (and thus for the fight against tax evasion): that is the “minimum State”.

Common resources

Common resources are not excludable

They are freely available for anybody to exploit

But they are rival: the consumption of the good by one individual reduces the possibility for other individual to consume

Examples of common resources

• Air and clean water• Congested streets • Fishes, whale and other wild species

The tragedy of the commons

When an individual, by using a resource, diminishes the availability of the resource for others we encounter the tragedy of the commons.

Common resources tend to be over-exploited

This generates a negative externality.

The public administration can:

• Impose a tax on usage;

• Regulate the use of the resource;

• Transform the common resource in a private good (by defining and enforcing individual property rights on the resource).

The tragedy of the commons

The importance of property rights

When the absence of property rights is the cause of market failures, public intervention can potentially solve the problem in 3 ways

1) By defining property rights, which enable the market to operate efficiently;

2) By regulating individual behaviour;

3) By producing a good that the market does not supply.

Economic goods differ in terms of excludability and rivalry.

The market can function when goods are private i.e. both excludable and rival.

Public goods are neither excludable nor rival, hence the market does not function well.

In because of free riding, it is the public sector who is responsible to supply public goods.

Conclusion

Conclusion

Collective resources are rival but not excludable.

Since individuals do not pay for the use of the resource, there is a tendency toward over-exploitation.

Public administration may limit the use of common resources via access regulation and taxes